Examination of Witnesses (Questions 75-130)
Jesse Griffiths, Peter Young, Ed Hedger
30 November 2010
Chair: Good morning, and
welcome. I see you have just introduced yourselves to each other,
which is fine, but, for the record, perhaps you could also introduce
yourselves to the Committee.
Jesse Griffiths:
I'm Jesse Griffiths, from the Bretton Woods Project.
Ed Hedger: Ed Hedger
from the Overseas Development Institute.
Peter Young: Peter
Young from Adam Smith International.
Q75 Chair: Thank
you for coming along. We are, as you know, just completing a
report into the World Bank and the UK's engagement with it. Obviously
the UK is a major contributor to the IDA of the World Bank. It
has often been said that the World Bank is very good on analysis
but not always excellent on delivery. We clearly, as a country,
under both the previous Government and the present Government,
have taken the view that the World Bank delivers a lot of our
objectives, so that in the current financial year, 37% of the
programme is going through multilaterals, and obviously the World
Bank is a major recipient; not the biggest, but the second biggest.
First of all, do you think that is right? If so, do you think
the percentage should be higher or lower? May I say that you
don't all have to answer every question, unless you feel you have
a particular comment to make? I have a suspicion, Peter, that
this might be one you would want to get started on.
Peter Young: Thank
you very much. I agree with what you said earlier, which is that
the Bank is very good on analysis, and has a lot of very capable
people working there, and it's our great pleasure to interact
with them often, but the implementation could be considerably
improved. The central point of the evidence that we submitted
is that the overall approach that is taken by the Bank of lending
money to developing countries and for the developing countries
themselves then to handle the procurement and administration is
a critical reason, in many cases, for that poor implementation.
This is because fundamentally, in many of these countries, the
capable midlevel staff in the civil services that we have,
which handle such procurement and administration effectively,
just don't exist or are very much thinner on the ground. You
have all sorts of problems that arise from that, including substantial
delays in the organisation and the start of activities, and a
lot of problems in the actual implementation due to faulty administration
and difficulties in changing what is required in the light of
circumstances. It's notable that whereas the Bank is strong in
evaluation in the form of postevaluationevaluation
of things once they've stoppedit isn't strong on evaluation
during the course of activities, which is the most valuable type
of evaluation, because then you can see what's going on, and what
you should change in the light of circumstances. Because of the
way things are structured, you have Bank supervision of ongoing
activities, as opposed to monitoring and evaluation in the sense
it would be done, say, in a DFID project. Broadly speaking, we
think that development expenditure is spent much more effectively
by DFID itself directly than through the World Bank or many of
the other multilateral agencies. There should be a focus on trying
to get to grips with these implementation problems as a priority.
Perhaps, in the interim, more should be spent directly by DFID
and less through multilaterals like the Bank.
Q76 Chair: Before
I invite the others to come in, I'm going to make a comment and
ask another question. The Minister of State last week made the
point, just picking up on your last point, that DFID did not have
the same footprint as the World Bank. Indeed, in many cases,
we could only work through the World Bank in countries in which
we didn't have an operation, or similarly with the United Nations,
where security factors made it difficult. You've made a clear
statement that, comparing like with like, I suppose, you think
DFID does it better than the World Bank, but clearly DFID cannot
be everywhere. That's the comment. Perhaps I'll ask the others
to comment on what has been said, but the question would be: what
is the comparative advantage of the World Bank compared with other
multilaterals and compared with DFID doing it itself? We've heard
what the disadvantages are, but does the Bank have any particular
advantages?
Ed Hedger: I'll
comment on that. From an ODI perspective we wouldn't have a strong
position on what the precise allocation should be under IDA16.
However, speaking to the question of the performance of the World
Bank, first of all, it is worth disaggregating the World Bank
into its constituent parts, and particularly the focus of ODI
has been on IDA, the concessional lending arm. It's interesting
to look at what some of the evidence on the performance is. There
are various indices out there, consistently scoring quite highly,
which is worth noting. Work by Bill Easterly ranks it very highly
first in a comparative sample, Knack et al did some work and ranked
it second, and the most recent analysis by CDG and Brookings puts
it in the top 10 on the four categories that it mentions. That's
not to say that it's perfect, but by various measures we have,
it is worth noting that its performance is assessed quite positively.
Speaking to the question of the comparative advantage
versus a bilateral agency in the form of DFID, there are certainly
things that the World Bank does and that the World Bank is invested
in doing on behalf of other bilateral funders that are worth noting.
These include its engagement with global public goods, which
does require that footprint across multiple countries, which DFID
doesn't have, and its capability at country level to harmonise
and to engage a large number of actors. It can form a bridgehead,
with all the questions about how effectively it performs that,
and take advantage of the economies of scale across a very large
number of countries, which bilaterals can't. As you mentioned,
there is also the depth and the richness of its expertise. From
my perspective, those would be points worth considering, which
would need to be set against a series of concerns, of course,
about how effective it is in delivering its mandate.
Q77 Chair: Obviously
Bretton Woods has some strong views about how the World Bank should
reform. The British Government have concurred with some of them,
not all of them, and have argued that they've had some success
in helping to shape the Bank's responsiveness, particularly incountry
delivery, which was one point of concern. Do you agree with DFID's
assessment of that? Do you think they have made progress in getting
the Bank to be better focused? What more do you think needs to
be done, and is it good value for the UK taxpayer compared with
what else it might do with that development funding?
Jesse Griffiths:
Before I come back to those specific points, just to put a little
bit of context into the decision that the UK Government will be
making on IDA, as you know, last time, IDA15, the UK was the largest
contributor to IDA, overtaking even the USA, even though the US
is a much
Chair: That was partly
to do with the exchange rate at the time.
Jesse Griffiths:
Exactly. But I think when we are talking about the IDA16 replenishment,
for the UK to maintain the same dollar contribution would mean
an increase of around 30% in its pound sterling contribution.
For me that frames this question of to what extent the UK should
be supporting IDA16, because I think the central question is not
so much the issues of effectiveness, though they are incredibly
important. It's also about what the role of the World Bank should
be, as you rightly highlighted, and the position it plays in the
development architecture. When the UK comes to make that decision,
if it were to increase, for example, its dollar contribution,
it would be seen as a massive boost, a vote of confidence in the
Bank, which I don't think the Bank should be getting at this time.
I think there are a number of areas of concern that
we've highlighted in our paper, but first of all, and critically
important to everything the Bank does, is the issue of governance
and ownership. As you know, and as previous reports of past Committees
have said, the ownership is central to the development of developing
countries, and I think whilst the Bank scores quite highly on
some aspects of effectiveness, it's ownership where there's a
real issue; for example, in terms of the continuing use of conditionality.
While that has reduced, it's still problematic. As people have
mentioned, procurement and other procedures sometimes make it
more complicated in countries. I think there are real issues
about the way the Bank interacts, and the governance issue, for
me, is central. 60% of the Bank's shares are still held by highincome
countries. It's interesting to read in DFID's submission that
they used the Bank's inaccurate figures, which say that the figure
is about 53%. That's only if you classify countries such as Saudi
Arabia as developing countries, which the Bank itself doesn't
do except when it comes to measuring governance.
Q78 Chair: Obviously
it is on the record. That's interesting. I take that point.
Presumably there's a published record of the actual shareholdings,
so it is possible to get the
Jesse Griffiths:
It is, and we've produced a detailed briefing that looks at it.
If you look at the highincome countries versus the middleincome
countries versus the lowincome countries, the highincome
countries have 60% of the vote, even after the last round of reforms.
There are inaccuracies in the way that has been reported by the
Bank.
Q79 Chair: Have
you given us that briefing?
Jesse Griffiths:
I believe so, but I can certainly send it again.
Chair: We have a briefing
from you, but I don't particularly recall that detail.
Jesse Griffiths:
It's mentioned in there, but there's a much more detailed one
where we break it down by different categories of country. There's
an issue there, and there's also an issue of transparency about
that.
There are also concerns in some key areas that are
essential for the Millennium Development Goals, such as health,
where the Bank has been heavily criticised by the Independent
Evaluation Group. They found that only 27% of projects in subSaharan
Africa were deemed to have had satisfactory outcomes in the health
portfolio. On gender, which is another issue that the Government
have been rightly emphasising as central to development, the Bank
tried to improve, so it had a gender action plan about five years
ago. But even now only 27% of economic sector work, which is
essentially important both from a gender perspective and also
in terms of what the Bank does, is regarded as genderinformed.
There are quite a lot of concerns about how the Bank
behaves and about the Bank's effectiveness, which are slightly
broader than just asking questions of: "If I spend £1
here, will it be the most effective use of that £1?"
but which strike to the heart of the development debate, and how
countries can develop. To my mind, that is the question. When
you are asking questions about the Bank, it's about the Bank's
central role in developing countries.
You asked about what are the comparative advantages.
One of the key roles the Bank does play is that it has a huge
role in overall policy discourse and shaping the way we all think
about development. I would suggest that it's played that role
in a highly problematic way in the past, although there have been
some improvements and I welcome President Zoellick's recent speech
on the matter. My main concern in this whole inquiry is to highlight
that the Bank's role is broader than just delivering particular
programmes on the ground. It is, I would argue, the most important
actor in development in many countries, and also in the global
development discourse.
Q80 Hugh Bayley:
We've read your evidence, and we'll come back with specific questions
on health, gender, the IEG, education and each of those specific
criticisms that you make, so you don't need to refer to them on
each occasion. My question is this: DFID is, as a result of the
Spending Review, committed to halving its administration costs.
That means a lot of DFID staff are going to be laid off, and
the ability of DFID to expand its bilateral programme whilst managing
it effectively is severely constrained. That means that more
money will go to the multilaterals. Overall the aid budget is
going to increase by 50% over the period of the next three years.
That is a massive increase; perhaps a doubling of the multilateral
spend. If you say they shouldn't spend it through the World Bank,
and we know they're likely to spend less rather than more through
Europe, where on earth is this money going to be spent if you
don't use the Bank as a vehicle?
Jesse Griffiths:
Our position is that they shouldn't increase their dollar contribution.
Q81 Hugh Bayley:
You've said that, but where is a doubling of multilateral aid
going to be spent if the Bank doesn't pick up a share of that?
Jesse Griffiths:
To maintain a dollar contribution will be a 30% increase in the
sterling contribution, so that is already quite a significant
increase.
Q82 Hugh Bayley:
But we're talking about a 100% increase. You're saying, "Avoid
the Bank," because you have criticisms, which we're going
to discuss in detail in the next hour or so. Malcolm asked you
about what was the comparative advantage of the Bank. You said
it had severe comparative disadvantages, so what are the comparative
advantages of the alternative multilaterals? Where would you
advise the Secretary of State, if he were sitting here, to put
his money? If not through the Bank, where, in terms of multilaterals?
Which multilaterals work better than the Bank?
Jesse Griffiths:
The UK Government, as you know, are conducting a Multilateral
Aid Review, and in any review like that you will find that for
different issues, different multilaterals perform better. You
mentioned, for example, the Global Fund: a lot of NGOs support
that as a tool for improving health expenditure, and I think in
many countries DFID's own bilateral programmes perform very well.
Q83 Hugh Bayley:
But if it is halving its admin costs, it would be a misuse of
aid to put more money bilaterally, wouldn't it? It would be poorly
managed.
Jesse Griffiths:
There are two issues. Should it be halving its admin costs, or
not?
Q84 Hugh Bayley:
Well, it is. It was told to, and it has committed to, so it's
not dreaming that something different is going to happen. That
is what the Spending Review has agreed to do. What I'm saying
to you is this: most of us in the development community are very
pleased that the Government's committed to meeting the 0.7% target.
It means a huge increase in British taxpayers' money that will
go to development. If you were to limit the contribution to IDA
in the way that you're suggesting, I think it's highly unlikely
that that 0.7% would be reached. Would that be preferable, to
miss 0.7% but constrain what the Bank does, or to use the Bank
as a vehicle for delivery to ensure that we meet the 0.7%. If
you had the choice between those two, which way would you jump?
Jesse Griffiths:
I don't think it is a choice. There are plenty of vehicles for
spending aid money. The approach DFID adopt in many countries
is to think: "On the ground in that country, what's the best
way to spend the money?" As you rightly highlighted, a large
proportion of DFID expenditure goes through multilaterals, but
a significant chunk of that goes through multilateral expenditure
incountry. It is not the IDA replenishments we're talking
about, or the large increases to the Global Fund and others, but
incountry, deciding which institutions operate best in this
or that country, and how do we fund those? I don't see any problem
with making a decision at that level. However, I'm a bit concerned
about some of the assumptions that lie behind some of the questions;
that, for example, it's more important to defend the line that
we should be reducing administration costs than asking, in each
country, "What is the most effective way to spend that money?"
In some countries, particularly fragile states, it may mean you
have to have higher administration costs. I take your point that
that is the Government's position, but it doesn't mean I would
necessarily support that.
Q85 Mr McCann:
Good morning, gentlemen. My question is about how the interests
of the poorest developing countries can be best served within
the World Bank Group. In particular, there's a proposal where
the presidency of the World Bank would alternate between developed
countries and developing countries. I just wondered, is that
just a fig leaf, or do you think that would be valuable?
Peter Young: The
more important things relate to the actual operations of the Bank
and reforms in the way that those are carried out. In our evidence,
we tried to give you a view from the trenches on what it's like
to interact with the Bank and work with the Bank on a practical
basis. We pointed to a lot of flaws in the procurement administration
and the implementation of activity, which I think are a lot worse
in the fragile states than in other places. Talking, after this
very kind invitation to give evidence, to some former Bank staff
who are working with us, they said that the real problem is to
do with the HR issues within the Bank, and how people are managed
and motivated, and the matrix structures that mean that people
are reporting to five different people, and so forth. If a developed
country person was to sort that out, then great; if a developing
country person was to sort that out, then great. I think it is
addressing the fundamental issues that is the important thing,
as opposed to who sits at the top, and to address those fundamental
issues within the Bank means difficult reform programmes. All
those people who work for the Bank often have strong interests
in preserving things the way they are, because they are comfortable
with that and changing things would make things difficult for
them. It is a question of who would be tough enough to push through
those reforms.
Q86 Mr McCann:
If they were pushing through those reforms, if it really is structure,
I take it that the other ideas that people have had, for example
in terms of developing countries having the same voting strength
as donor countries, is that, again, not dealing with the issue,
because of the structural issues you've referred to?
Peter Young: I
would generally tend to think so. I think that who has however
many voting shares is probably neither here nor there in the scheme
of things. One maybe ought to look more at how donors are interacting
with the Bank. Let's look at these multidonor trust funds,
for example, many of which are extremely inefficient.
Chair: We're coming on
to those.
Peter Young: We're
coming on to those. I won't talk about them now.
Ed Hedger: Maybe
I could just comment on the way past on this question of incountry
impact. We did some work looking at the recipients' stakeholder
perceptions, particularly among members of the Executive, parliamentarian
and business leaders, about how they would rank multilateral donors
comparatively. One of the questions we posed was the nature of
the governance structures of the multilateral organisation, and
to what extent that had a bearing. At first cut, it appears to
have some influence, to the extent that African countries would
have some preference for the African Development Bank, because
they feel there is a perception of greater representation in that,
so there is a factor. That said, the much stronger factors that
emerged from a number of African countries, with key Government
officials, were on things like a sense of commitment to development
through the nature of the instruments used and the behaviours
displayed, and some of the more mechanical details of aid, and
an alignment with policy that is Governmentled, and getting
behind those sorts of questions. I think it was registered as
important, but not the most dominant of those priorities.
Jesse Griffiths:
I think your question is absolutely bang right. It is naïve
to suggest that who selects the president and who sits on the
board doesn't matter that much. Of course it matters enormously,
and it particularly matters in the Bank because of the gentlemen's
agreement that means the US always selects the president of the
Bank. Although the G20 and the Bank's board have made commitments
to phase this out and have a meritbased process, it is still
very uncertain whether that will happen next time a president
is selected, because of opposition within the US. It affects
the selection of the president, and the Bank is a very presidentdominated
institution. The amount of oversight by shareholders is much
lower than you would expect. For example we had a strategy from
the Bank this year, the first strategy we've ever had overall
from the Bank, and that only came about because shareholders demanded
it as part of the IDA16 process. The strategy, if you read it,
is not really a strategy; it's more a summary of what the Bank
is doing.
The president matters enormously. For example, my
characterisation of this particular president's agenda is that
he has an expansionist agenda for the Bank. He wants to see the
Bank engaged in all the different aspects of development, and
you can argue whether that's a good idea or not, but a different
president would have a completely different attitude. I think
it is vitally important who selects the president, and I think
it does poison developing countries' relationships with the Bank
that it is seen to be dominated by Western institutions. I think
you are right: some reform is needed, and certainly a meritbased
selection process that is open to anybody, as the G20 have promised.
The issue of voting shares, as you say, is vitally important,
and the G20 did agree to move to equality of voting between developed
and developing countries over time. To my mind that would create
the kind of institution we would like to see: a cooperative based
on sharing of governance between the borrowers and the lenders,
if you like.
There is a deeper institutional issue, which I've
alluded to and I'm sure DFID actually shares this view, in that
overall the Bank shareholders don't have enough influence over
the way the Bank operates. I mentioned the issue of there not
really being a strategy. They meet through an executive board
of delegated civil servants that meets at least twice a week and
approves almost every project. The board operates much more like
a part of the Bank than an oversight body, because every project
is approved by the board, so they have a stake in every single
one of those. There are ongoing reforms, or suggestions for reform;
Zedillo, the exPresident of Mexico, led a highlevel
panel on governance reform, which suggested some of the reforms
you mentioned in terms of parity, meritbased selection,
but also having a much stronger oversight of the Bank staff through
executive board and also through increased transparency and accountability
to citizens and parliaments.
Q87 Mr McCann:
One final question, and hopefully it's a yes/no: should donors
withhold assistance from recipients who break undertakings?
Peter Young: I
generally think there should be a relatively tough line on this.
If we don't take a tough line, then people don't pay attention
to these sorts of agreements. Conditionality has had a bit of
a bad name. If a country is absolutely wasting money on something
or other, it's perfectly okay to make a condition that it sorts
that out before one lends it more money or gives it more money
and it hasn't addressed the first problem. I think "yes"
is the answer to your question.
Ed Hedger: I'd
say provided it's proportionate, and provided it's relevant.
Those are two questions that have not always been applied. Clearly
there is evidence of conditionality having effects and securing
traction on reforms. When there is a sense of a lack of ability
to achieve those conditions, or some factors beyond the control
of the Government to achieve them, is one point that's relevant,
and second is the timing; the point at which funds are withheld.
One of the objectives of course is around predictability. Conditionality
applied at short notice can fundamentally undermine that, and
that takes you into questions about whether conditionality is
a prior condition or an ex post condition. It's a complex set
of arguments rather than a simplistic one of withholding or not
withholding aid.
Jesse Griffiths:
If I could emphasise that last point, predictability of aid is
crucially important for developing countries. It matters, exactly
as you said, how you make these disbursements and on what conditions
you might withhold the disbursements. The IMF estimates that
aid is several times less predictable than tax revenue for Governments
in developing countries, for example. That's a real problem.
The issue about withholding disbursements should only be done
under very clear conditions that are agreed in advance, and over
a timeframe that allows the developing country to adjust. Suddenly
cutting off aid is possibly one of the most damaging things any
donor could do; you could probably even argue it could do more
damage than the aid did good in the first place.
Ed Hedger: There
is evidence on this, about the borrowing costs upon Governments
of recourse to private markets in order to compensate that. It
links in with the harmonisation agenda as well, where donors act
in concert, which is a good thing for all sorts of reasons in
terms of transaction costs upon Government and themselves, but
equally the impact of multidonor withholding needs to be
treated sensitively to those sorts of issues.
Q88 Chris White:
Good morning. How optimistic are you about the economies of lowincome
countries over the coming year?
Ed Hedger: It's
not an area that I was going to give substantial evidence on.
I can say a few words about the role of the crisis response window,
perhaps, in that context. I think that the evidence from ODI,
with which we can certainly provide you, is that they were to
some extent protected through their weak integration with international
financial systems, so the direct transmission was limited, but
there's a risk of second-round effects. They seem to have fared
quite well. In the context of the World Bank conversation, there
seems to be some encouraging progress around inclusion or ongoing
inclusion of a crisis response window, and I know that's something
the UK Government has pushed quite hard for. One of the big weaknesses
during the crisis was that much of the money was locked in the
trust funds, and therefore the ability to act fast and responsibly
is weakened. That would seem to be something to continue pushing
for, and a good emerging development, which could be supportive
of those countries if they become vulnerable.
Q89 Chris White:
If these fragile economies were to deteriorate, what sort of support
and assistance would multinational organisations be able to provide?
Ed Hedger: Through
these trust fund windows? It is still in negotiation as part
of the IDA16 negotiations, but, as I understand it, if a number
of countries' GDP were to decline by 3% or greater, or there were
to be some sort of systematic decline, then the idea is there
would be a more immediate response. This is partly to do with
the earmarking of funds, where a lot of the funds to IDA have
been earmarked to trust funds. This has been one of the significant
criticisms, from our perspective, of the way the World Bank operates,
and its inability to respond quickly. This would be a softer
earmark associated that could move faster.
Peter Young: I
think, to answer your question, that with lowincome countries
it is often very specific factors that are peculiar to the country
concerned, which are more important than the overall economic
climate. For example, take south Sudan. What's going to happen
with the referendum and the separation from the north? Take Pakistan:
unless its fundamental governance problems are addressed, and
the way that the state operates, it's going to have continued
decline. Take Nigeria: we're working on trying to sort out the
electricity problem, and getting rather close to making some breakthroughs
there. If that's sorted, then you can see an increase in GDP
of about £130 billion. There are all sorts of specific factors,
country by country, that are often very much more significant
than global ones.
Jesse Griffiths:
Regarding your question about what they would do if things got
worse, the crucial institution in that discussion is the IMF rather
than the World Bank, because obviously that's the institution
set up to provide emergency funding. Oxfam and Development Finance
International did some research looking at developing country
Governments' budgets, and their relationship with IMF conditions.
They found that the IMF has behaved much more flexibly during
the crisis than in the past, in terms of allowing Governments
to continue social security and other expenditures. That period
of relaxation is coming to an end next year, and those Governments
will be expected to cut back their expenditures on health, education
and other crucial social programmes. There has been some flexibility,
but also it's a shortterm issue, so next year there is a
big issue there for lowincome countries. The issue you
mentioned about second-round and other effects of the overall
global economy are obviously vitally important to developing countries.
I'm sure everybody has different opinions about the way that's
going. The crucial issue is that there isn't really a decent
crisis response mechanism for lowincome countries, and I
don't think the windows that they're proposing at the World Bank
is the answer. For a start, it's taking a long time to set up
for a crisis that started over two years agohere we are
in 2010, and it's still not agreed.
Peter Young: It
might be ready for the next crisis.
Jesse Griffiths:
It might be ready, but I think there are proposals for much more
rapid methods. For example, during the London Summit in 2009,
it was agreed to increase the Special Drawing Rights available
through the IMF by $250 billion overall, but only $19 billion
of that went to lowincome countries. There ought to be
mechanisms so you could transfer some of those Special Drawing
Rights, for example. I understand the UK Government did look
into that at the time, although I don't think any action was taken.
There ought to be more rapid mechanisms that don't rely on the
slightly slow bureaucratic procedures that the World Bank often
puts in place in this kind of situation.
Peter Young: I
was reading, in preparation for this session, the Special Themes
for IDA16 paper from the World Bank in relation to fragile states.
I'll just quote it. "Both external and internal factors
continue to hinder implementation performance in FCCs. These
include limited capacity of client Governments, limited Bank resources,
and continuing challenges with Bank processing and fiduciary issues
Slow procurement has been one of the problemsin addition
to limited capacity of implementing agencies and marketsin
situations where speed and flexibility are crucial." That
is basically the Bank saying, in its own bureaucratese, that its
systems are not suitable for the very speedy response that you
require in these fragile and conflictaffected states.
Q90 Pauline Latham:
That's something we are going to touch on, because obviously Adam
Smith International are highly critical of the World Bank. You've
identified a number of inefficiencies in the host countries' procurement
processes related to World Bank projects, and you've commented
that "as a result of such inefficiencies, it was usually
impossible to tell when the World Bank project would actually
be delivered." Do you have any examples of this problem
that you can tell us about? How widespread do you think these
problems are? How do you think that DFID's procurement compares
with that of the World Bank?
Peter Young: I
can give you some examples of that. Here's a pretty good example:
Nigeria, the GEMS programme, which is to do with growth. It is
a large programme agreed jointly between DFID and the World Bank.
There are three components of that financed and procured by DFID,
and three that are meant to be financed and procured by the World
Bank. The three DFID components have started; we are indeed implementing
one of them. The World Bank componentsit was meant to
be an integrated project, all running at the same timehave
not started. The World Bank's loans relating to them haven't
even been approved by the National Assembly. What they next need
to do, if they get those approved, is to go through a procurement
process to hire a procurement manager, who will then procure those
components. Given the time all that normally takes, it's two
years off on an optimistic basis, by which time the bulk of the
DFID components will have finished or will be almost finished.
That is a very clear example of how the two things match. Fundamentally,
DFID's procurement is staffed by capable people who are operating
in an effective meritbased system, and can do things in
a reasonable amount of time.
We really only see those things that we come into
contact with. We're not doing research into the generalities.
I can't comment on whether this is the case 80% of the time,
or 70% of the time, or 30% of the time. It's just that one comes
across an awful lot of cases where things are so terribly slow,
and you never know when the World Bank things are going to start.
There are many cases where we are implementing something for
DFID, and the World Bank is meant to take over, but then our project
has to be extended, and then extended again, and then extended
again, and then again, because the World Bank stuff has never
come into place. Those are direct comparisons. Obviously I can
point to a number of individual cases. I think there are a lot
of good examples to do with south Sudan Multi Donor Trust Fund,
which is run by the Bank, where some of the procurements that
we've been involved withwe are tendering to do some of
the workhave taken four years and still haven't resulted
in the award of a contract.
Q91 Pauline Latham:
With examples like that, clearly the World Bank, like any organisation,
has a budget for a financial year. They must always never hit
the target. Or is it that they have so much money to spend in
this financial year, that they are not going to hit this year's
priorities, but they'll hit three years behind's priorities because
they'll come into this year? Is that how it's working?
Peter Young: I
have myself never studied the overall finances of the World Bank. Perhaps
my colleagues are better informed. I know, for example, that
the money they will probably not be spending in Nigeria they want
to switch to Pakistan, because Pakistan are short of money. Sometimes
there are ways in which they can spend the money. The definition
of what is spending money is often a rather unclear one. If a
donor writes a cheque to a multidonor trust fund, then that
money, in the eyes of that donor, is spent, even though it may
be sitting in the multidonor trust fund for six years.
I don't know whether, if the World Bank itself puts money into
a multidonor trust fund, it thinks it has spent it. In
fact it has not actually been spent on anything in particular.
I bow to my colleagues' superior judgement on those points.
Ed Hedger: The
wider experience I think would bear out the real challenges, particularly
around investment lending, which it comes back to, and a tenet
of that is implementation around procurement and that being quite
a systematic challenge. I wouldn't necessarily classify it as
solely or largely a staff capacity issue to do with the relative
competence of staff. Part of the challenge is a procedural one.
There is a very strong compliance culture that seems to go on
around the procurement side of the Bank, particularly borne out
in fragile states. It's interesting to look at some of the pressures
associated with that, which is from the bilateral donors who are
represented in that group. On the one hand they are pushing for
speed, faster disbursement, faster execution on the ground. On
the other hand, many of those constituencies are also calling
for the very same safeguards and for the financial controls and
for the fiduciary role that the Bank plays in the stewardship
of their funds. I fear sometimes there is a little bit of buckpassing,
with some of those funders who are demanding one thing but also
requiring that. That doesn't mean to say that the problem doesn't
exist, but I would say it's perhaps a more complex institutional
one than a pure one of getting the right staff in the right place.
In terms of the issues of fragile states, where the
procurement is particularly strong, there seems a tension between
the fiduciary aspects of procurement and the potential development
aspects of procurement. Equally, there is a challenge of risk
assessment, where the full framework of risk assessment is applied
to everything, however large, however small. The one point I
might make is it is perhaps worth distinguishing between what
some of the multilateral donors are charged to do on behalf of
the bilateral donors, and what the bilateral donors do direct.
Largescale infrastructure projects are the sorts of things
that bilateral donors may be doing less of now, and those by their
very nature may attract and to some extent require a slightly
stronger process. I think that is worth comparing.
Q92 Chair: What
you've both said does seem to imply that too much is done in Washington
and not enough on the ground. That seems to be the implication.
Pauline Latham: Yes.
That's what I thought.
Peter Young: The
procurement is not done by the Bank. It is done by the recipient
country, but it is micromanaged by the Bank. The Bank has
to approve everything that's done, at a very detailed level.
Because those procedures are, as my colleagues are saying, very
tight, because of the increased risk of corruption, particularly
in the fragile states, that adds even further delay to the thing.
You have two sets of procurement things going on: one, the developing
country Government, which basically doesn't have the staff to
do it properly; and two, the World Bank, which probably has the
same quantity of resources going into the procurement as it would
have had if it handled it directly, checking every single thing,
but not actually intervening to speed anything up. It really
results in a mess, and it's just not a very sensible approach.
Q93 Pauline Latham:
There's an argument that people say, "We want to make sure
that the money is spent well," and you can see how those
sort of systems have built up. But it isn't like doing business
in the States, doing business in fragile states. It's completely
separate. Is it because of transparency that they're doing this,
or maybe the lack of transparency, to show how the money is being
spent as well as it could be? We're going down this route of
saying, "Every £1 has to count," and of course
it does, and we want to make sure that it's not going to corruption,
that it's going to where we want it to go to. Do you think that's
why the World Bank is so inefficient, because they've looked,
as we are doing now, at how we can get the best value for money
without it going to corruption? That is the thing that our constituents
say to us: "Why are you spending all this money? It's going
to corrupt Governments that just prop up themselves; it's not
getting down to real people." One of the questions I asked
when we were at the World Bank was, "How does what you spend
affect the people on the ground?" Do you think that is one
of the problems that they face, and that we may indeed face?
Jesse Griffiths:
I think that is a critical question. Before I answer that, may
I say, very quickly, in answer to your previous question about
whether there is a discrepancy, that every year there's a discrepancy
between the Bank's commitments, which are always larger, and its
disbursements. This points to one issue, which is that the Bank
has a culture of approval, so Bank staff want to commit money,
because they have targets, but it has a much slower culture of
disbursement, as people have highlighted.
Is it anticorruption? I think part of it is,
but part of it is also that the Bank is a bureaucratic institution,
as we've heard, with its own particular rules that have built
up over time and aren't necessarily always reviewed regularly
enough. What the Bank ought to be trying to do is turning this
discussion around. What really matters in developing countries
is the overall procurement across Government, not just the bits
that happen to be funded by the Bank or by other donor agencies.
I think it is right that this issue of shadow systems alignment,
as it's called, should take place. The Bank and other donors
ought to be trying to use developing country Government systems
when they lend to Governments, but make those systems better,
rather than set up parallel structures that may make sure your
particular £1 gets to where you want it to but will probably
cost you more in bureaucracy. But it doesn't address the wider
issue of how do we improve overall anti-corruption.
Peter Young: That
wider issue is usually associated with Civil Service reform as
a whole, because you are trying to get the Civil Service to work
effectively, to be able to recruit decent, midlevel officials
on a merit basis, who are paid properly, and so forth. By and
large, the evidence, as I'm sure you're aware, of all the Civil
Service reform programmes of the last 20 years, is that it hasn't
worked. They've never really been able to accomplish substantive
Civil Service reform. There are very few exceptions. The fact
of the matter is, on a pragmatic basis, that the Civil Services
in these countries are not capable of handling a procurement process
properly. That is simply the fact.
What will happen, if you insist on them doing it,
is that the Director General of the organisation, or the Permanent
Secretary, will have to lead the process, and get involved in
all sorts of details and whatever, rather than getting on with
the more important things of policy and management and whatever
his responsibilities are. So often, when we have some minor problem
with the administration, you cannot get it sorted out unless you
speak to the Permanent Secretary. If Permanent Secretaries in
Britain were spending their whole time sorting minor administrative
matters like that, they would never be able to get on with their
job. That is indeed the case in most of the countries that we're
talking about, particularly the fragile ones. Although it sounds
nice to say "Let's rely on incountry systems,"
in practice it doesn't work.
Jesse Griffiths:
That's a sweeping statement. It doesn't apply to all
Ed Hedger: Yes.
Peter Young: Not
in every case. There are some that are more or less all right,
but broadly speaking, particularly in fragile countries, that
is the case.
Ed Hedger: I would
say there are two things. The examples of failed Civil Service
reform almost necessarily won't be applicable to some of these
postconflict countries, where we're talking about the very
risks there. It is the fundamental absence of capacity, not the
failure to reform the Civil Service, that is one of the questions
there. This other question is you said that there were risks
in two directions: fiduciary control is served by avoiding use
of country systems, but then the opportunity for development gain
is also forgone. Part of the issue strikes at exactly what you're
saying: what is the defence to the constituent about the tolerance
of risk? These issues are not the exclusive challenge for multilateral
donors, of course, but also bilateral donors, particularly around
budget support. There's a strong amount of crosscountry
evidence on the merits of avoiding parallel systems, and of course
a huge international architecture around that. There are examplesRwanda,
Sierra Leone, otherswhere to some extent that risk has
been taken with what early evidence suggests are quite beneficial
results. I wouldn't say it was a simple yes or no, but I equally
don't think the evidence strongly supports that. A couple of
points on the question of measurement as well, which is something
that is shared. There I think it is a challenge around attribution
versus contribution, and the question of the extent to which you
can be clear on what you're getting.
Chair: You seem to have
stirred up the Committee. About four people want to make interventions
at this stage. I will let them do so, but I would be grateful
if they and you could be crisp, because we'll never get to the
end otherwise.
Q94 Mr McCann:
Peter, you made a contrast between the DFID delivery and the World
Bank delivery on that procurement point. If you go back then
to the Government striving to get 2% administration costs, doesn't
that tell us, in the example that you gave, that is based on the
general austerity that we're facing in the UK, and not on common
sense? The corollary to the point you made surely has to be that
we have to increase our bilateral rather than our multilateral
aid programmes through organisations like the World Bank?
Peter Young: I
think, yes, we should increase our bilateral aid programmes.
We did submit some evidenceI don't know if you looked at
iton the issue of the DFID administration, in which we
said that you need to have enough people in order to carry out
an effective programme. You're not actually saving money if you
have too few people. I think there may be ways around this problem
in terms of how people are classified, as to whether they are
programme staff or administration staff, and possibly that is
the pragmatic solution to this. But I am not au fait with
Q95 Mr McCann:
But that's a false economy. If they're doing administration,
and it's just a different budget that they're coming out of, that's
not saving administration.
Peter Young: If
you're going to say that you're saving administration costs in
the UK by handing over money to another organisation that's less
effective and has higher administration costs, you're not taking
into account that other organisation's administration costs in
your analysis of how much money you're spending on administration.
That whole administration thing is a nightmare of the first order,
but perhaps we don't want to get into that here.
Chair: No. We have put
these points to Ministers.
Q96 Hugh Bayley:
Peter, you said one of the factors that delayed the World Bank's
GEMS projects in Nigeria was their failure to get approval from
the National Assembly. Do you think it makes sense to put a major
World Bank scheme to the National Assembly? Did the UK get National
Assembly approval for its GEMS work?
Peter Young: Again,
I'm not familiar with the details of how this operates. It's
DFID's responsibility, not mine. I think the way it works with
DFID is that they get agreement for their programmes from the
Government, and DFID programmes are not put to the National Assembly,
because of course it is us spending the money. The money isn't
going into the Nigerian Government's budget. Whereas with the
World Bank, the way that the whole thing operates, where the Government
is actually borrowing the money, means that it could come under
the control of the National Assembly. I don't think that is a
very good idea, because the minutiae of which loans to accept
and which not is not particularly a useful thing for a National
Assembly to consider. I believe in this particular case what
happened was an administrative oversight. These things are normally
included in the budget, and a lot of these World Bank loans were
left out for some reason or another. When you get bound up in
these incountry systems, these are the sorts of problems
that inevitably occur.
Hugh Bayley: I passionately
disagree. I believe Parliament should scrutinise the Executive.
But I hear your point of view very eloquently put.
Q97 Alison McGovern:
A swift question to Peter. You described the absence of good-quality,
middleranking civil servants as being at the heart of some
of the delivery programmes. If the World Bank ought not to continue
working within a country's own administration, what solution do
you see for that problem? How will that be solved, ever?
Peter Young: Firstly,
by loading all these administrative tasks on to the country's
administration, which it is illsuited to do, and, as I say,
means that all the top people are involved in this extra level
of the administration, which is especially complicated because
of all the corruption safeguards that are insisted upon by the
donors, as we were discussing earlier, doesn't help. Civil Service
reform really is the solution, and unless one gets to grips with
that, which really involves some difficult governance issues,
one will not make progress on that, I'm afraid.
Q98 Alison McGovern:
Can you briefly be slightly more explicit about what you mean
by "difficult governance issues"?
Peter Young: Take
some countries: civil servants are appointed not on merit but
on grounds of political patronage. We did a report on Pakistan
recently, where that whole issue of patronage goes throughout
the system. Decisions are all taken on patronage grounds. The
state education system of Pakistan, which is staffed by civil
servants, is in such an atrocious state that 36% of the population
send their children to feepaying private schools as opposed
to the free state ones. The reason for that is all of those appointments
are done on the grounds of political patronage, and most of the
teachers don't turn up. The problem goes right to the top of
the system in that country. Other countries have different sets
of problems. It might be simply more to do with resources. You
will generally find that Civil Services are too large, because
they are used as a means of providing employment, and it would
be better to reduce the numbers and pay people more. Sometimes
simply the resources aren't available for that. It's not an easy
set of issues, and I don't think that we can go into detail here.
There has been very great difficulty in making progress on this,
for all sorts of issues that vary from country to country.
Q99 Jeremy Lefroy:
The Crown Agents are quite highly regarded in terms of procurement,
if you know the Crown Agents. I don't know the extent to which
DFID does use Crown Agents, but would this be a model that perhaps
the World Bank could look at?
Peter Young: That's
an interesting one. I had heard from, not Crown Agents but one
of the other UK firms that is on the DFID panel, Charles Kendall
& Partners, that they had been hired under a World Bank programme
in Cambodia to run the procurement system. By that I mean not
handling an individual procurement and then have the decisions
taken by the civil servants or the ministers, but that they would
have the final decision as to how the thing was run and who was
chosen, and so forth. I think that is a model, contracting out
the whole thing, including the politically sensitive decisions,
as opposed to just having someone come in and help.
Ed Hedger: A very
quick one, on a governance point. This is clearly not just an
issue of World Bank versus DFID. If anything, DFID is a stronger
supporter of the use of country systems than the World Bank, and
the World Bank has a greater use of project implementation units.
That argument will take you, curiously, away from that position
towards the World Bank.
Specifically on this point of Civil Service reform,
for most countries it creates a binding obstacle if you say that
you cannot invest in strengthening country systems until progress
is made, particularly on Civil Service reform, which is arguably
the least tractable of the issues. To some extent, the experience
leaves you with nowhere to go, except a permanent recourse to
international expertise, supplanting and substituting for domestic
capacity.
That leads on quite nicely to this role of international
agents. The same point could be argued on all of the fiduciary
functions: procurement, audit, and accounting. There is an array
of models in postconflict states, with an array of different
performance. The critical distinction, it seems to me, is not
whether the use of an agent in that function immediately is a
good or bad thingit is often quite necessary for an international
constituencybut whether there is an explicit remit that
is enforced for them to be starting to try to build capacity and
to transition from that executive agency role into that advisory
one. Too often, the incentives around the contracting and specification
of work fail to achieve that difference, and there are examples
of where it has been better done.
Peter Young: If
you take Afghanistan, there was a threeyear programme that
DFID financedin fact with that same firm, Charles Kendall
& Partnersthat attempted to improve the procurement
functions of the Afghan administrations. The progress made just
isn't sufficient for them to be able to carry things out properly.
In practice, under this World Bank procurement system, they're
often using some kind of agent. A lot in Afghanistanyou
wouldn't really believe itis actually done by a subsidiary
of Indian Railways. It appears to have the views on speed and
efficiency that one might expect from the Indian state railways
circa 1952. The Afghans might be even more efficient than that
organisation.
Ed Hedger: I think
it's also the sense of expectations in a threeyear period
about what could be achieved. If we look at the course of change
in the UK and some of the reforms, and the number of years that
attempts were made to introduce Whole of Government accounts here
versus what we expect of a fully fledged procurement system in
three years. Part of it is that, if you have an expectation of
what you can achieve, it's there.
Chair: Sorry, can I bring
in Anas Sarwar?
Q100 Anas Sarwar:
If I could pick up on what I think was a bit of a contradiction,
Peter? Earlier on in the answer you were saying that part of
the problem with the World Bank is that it's micromanaging too
much, and there's too much decision making in Washington, and
then later on it's incountry systems don't work. Which
is it?
Peter Young: Both,
because what you have is that they're relying on incountry
systems, which they're adapting to their own rules, which often,
as my colleagues have been saying, have been insisted upon by
donors. They are micromanaging every aspect of that process.
The developing country will do something like send out a request
for expressions of interest in something or other. The text of
that will have to be given a "no objection" by the World
Bank. Then who are they going to send it to? That will have
to be given a "no objection" by the World Bank. The
control by the Bank over what is done is there throughout the
process, without them actually doing it. It would be a lot easier
if they just did it themselves.
Jesse Griffiths:
It wouldn't solve the problem, though.
Peter Young: It
wouldn't solve the underlying problem.
Jesse Griffiths:
Exactly, and I think we should be interested in that.
Peter Young: The
point of providing assistance is to achieve the objectives of
the assistance.
Jesse Griffiths:
No, it's not.
Peter Young: It's
not necessarily to fix subsidiary problems a, b,
c and d.
Chair: Can I just bring
in Mr Griffiths?
Jesse Griffiths:
I think we're all interested in trying to achieve the Millennium
Development Goals. We're not interested in which bit of the Millennium
Development Goals our money can be said to have achieved; we're
interested in achieving them all. For example, if you take health,
in order for health to improve in any developing country, overall
the health system has to improve. A large part of that is about
Government improvement. To suggest that we can say, "Let's
care just about this particular project and make it perfect, and
not worry about the issues throughout the Civil Service and the
local Governments and all the other different agencies,"
is, if you like, abdicating.
Your point about the World Bank is critically important.
The Bank and other donors should be doing their best to try to
make the country systems work better in a way that does not add
additional bureaucracy and problems for that country. As we've
heard, what they're doing is saying that they want to improve
country systems, but adding additional levels of bureaucracy.
You get the worst of both worlds.
Q101 Anas Sarwar:
Yes. Isn't part of development about, yes, aid programmes, but
also creating systems in countries so these people can not be
dependent on developed countries for the rest of their lives?
Isn't part of the programmes that we do helping to set up governance,
helping to set up structures, but also have an effective aid programme
that is, for example, fighting malaria or something else? Would
you see that as part of the World Bank's role?
Peter Young: I
think there definitely should be a focus on trying to improve
the administrative systems of the host country Governments. The
particular solution the Bank has come up with, that involves relying
on a mixture of those systems with its own detailed procedures
and control, results in great inefficiency in much of the way
that the Bank's money is spent. It's a balance. One has to decide
on what is the most important thing. Would it be better to have
started this GEMS programme in Nigeria at the same time as the
DFID things and have a proper integrated programme? Or is it
better to rely on the Government system, supplemented by the World
Bank rules and so on, and start it three years afterwards, so
it can't be run together? If using the intracountry procurement
systems in every case, as adapted by the Bank, is the best thing,
then let's start that one three years late. I'm just saying,
from the practical perspective of someone who works on the ground,
that much of this approach is not working and needs to be changed
in some way or other. By contrast, the DFID system, where you're
having the procurement administration done by DFID directly, does
work to a much greater extent.
Q102 Anas Sarwar:
Just following up on that, do you have any estimates of the actual
cost of inefficiencies in the World Bankfunded procurement
process?
Peter Young: No,
because our remit is not to do those sorts of analyses. I'm just
reporting to you some of the practical problems that come up.
I think we highlighted in that paper that often, if you're actually
implementing a programme, and you're reporting directly to the
agency for which you are implementing the programme, it is difficult
to deal with inappropriate behaviour on behalf of your client.
They're the ones who pay your invoices.
I brought along quite a good practical example.
This is a letter, and I'm not going to say which organisation
it's from, but from a bureau that we were implementing a World
Bank programme for. The letter says: "The Bureau has a very
high workload. Consequently the Director General, along with
the top decision makers, is always under deadline pressure. The
situation has led to cancellation of annual vacations for all
the top management of the Bureau, which, as you know, is harmful
to their health. It is in the attempt to arrest a total breakdown
of their psychological wellbeing that we wish to propose a oneweek
vacation to countries of their choice under the sponsorship of
your organisation. We wish to request your organisation extend
the support you have given to this proposal by giving the Director
General and her team of eight a deserved holiday abroad, which
is expected to refresh the team and put them on a sound track
for the furtherance of the programme."
If you get a letter like this, what do you do? If
it was a DFID programme, you would say, "That's a very interesting
suggestion. I will speak to the DFID Project Officer," and
then you would report back, "They've said that diverting
resources to this trip is not appropriate. We can't do it."
But if they're controlling the money, and you've already had
tremendous difficulty in getting your invoices paid because they
keep losing them and so forth, do you say, "Most certainly
not; we're not going to pay for this holiday. This is totally
inappropriate," and they say, "We insist that you pay
for the holiday." Are you then going to call up the World
Bank task team leader and say, "We have a real problem here.
They're insisting on spending this money on this holiday."
The consequences of causing a huge fuss about it will be that
your invoices will take yet another six months to get paid. Dealing
with these issues on a pragmatic, daytoday basis is
problematic.
Q103 Chair: How
did you deal with it?
Mr McCann: Did they take
the holiday?
Peter Young: I
believe what happened, as far as I can rememberand I wouldn't
want to be held to anyone investigating the detailsis that
it was decided it was important to have a strategic thinkin
in a certain foreign country, where they could look in detail
at the forthcoming programme and take a variety of decisions on
how to organise things, free from the pressures of daytoday
work.
Q104 Pauline Latham:
That's one of the problems, isn't it, that we face? People, if
they hear stories like that, think money is going astray, and
it shouldn't be happening. I was interested in the fact that
you've done a report on Pakistan. Maybe we should get it and
read it before we go ourselves. Can I come back to something
specific? We've heard that the World Bank managed the pooled
South Sudan Multi Donor Trust Fund, but it provided little funding
for health facilities, years after it should have done, after
it was established. I know this is one of your pet hates. How
typical do you think this is of multidonor trust funds?
What needs to be done to improve the position? In this particular
case of South Sudan, with the impending referendum, how do you
think they will feel about that? Do you think it will have any
impact, because they haven't had these health facilities that
they should have had, many years ago?
Peter Young: I
think the South Sudan example is a good one. There have been
a lot of studies done on it; done, in fact, also by ODI. They
showed that the whole emphasis being placed on trying to use the
incountry systems, of which there were virtually none, because
South Sudan was a new creation, and having emphasis placed on
decisions being taken by the South Sudan administration as the
prime objective, as opposed to getting the particular tasks completed,
was mistaken. It added to a huge quantity of bureaucracy around
that particular trust fund, and that meant, as you've mentioned,
that for years and years and years most of the money wasn't spent.
It really ought to have been spent quickly upfront. The problem
with multidonor trust fundsthough you can get ones
that are more efficient than others, certainlyis that again,
noone is directly controlling it. All the donors that put
money into it want to put their own sets of rules on to it, because
they can't control it directly. The Bank, if it's running it,
has a hugely complicated set of rules to protect it and, added
to the whole set of problems we've just been discussing, that
means that it's an extremely inefficient way of spending money.
We have just been involved in setting up a multidonor trust
fund in Afghanistan, and the process of negotiating with everyone,
when everyone has a slightly different legal point of view, and
so forth, is a real nightmare. That mechanism ticks all the boxes
of the Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness, where everyone
needs to join together and put all the money in one pot, and have
one approach and so forth, but, in practice, you often have a
very poor result.
Ed Hedger: On this
question of trust funds, I'm interested in the contrast, potentially,
as I understand it, between Afghanistan and southern Sudan, where
it's generally accepted it has little to commend it. In Afghanistan,
the other research and the investigation we've done suggest that
there is more that has been more beneficial there. The stats
I have suggest that of $3.4 billion put into the trust fund, $3
billion has been disbursed, which suggests quite a high spend,
particularly through the recurrent window, which is trying to
get money out quite quickly to support areas such as salary payments
for key social sector workers. I know there's a different procedure
then applied to the development window, as I understand it, in
Afghanistan, which applies external procedures and has agencies.
My understanding is that Afghanistan suggests the possibilities
of how multidonor trust funds can work effectively, and
can strengthen country systems, in quite stark contrast to southern
Sudan, where it doesn't. Perhaps, rather than concluding that
this is an instrument without merit, it's rather a question of
what it is about that country's specific context that can give
it the possibility to work well.
Q105 Hugh Bayley:
Can I just refer to the Committee's own Report on Afghanistan
recently, which found that the United States had spent six times
as much money as DFID on reconstruction and development. The
lion's share of DFID's money had gone through a World Bank multidonor
trust fund, yet it was found to have produced half as much, in
other words three times the value for money, as having a bilaterally
managed programme where the work was given to American contractors.
I'm not immediately persuaded that running things yourself, using
your own inhouse procurement system, and buying from your
own people necessarily delivers good development. In South Sudan,
it appears not to have worked well. I wonder whether this is
a problem in South Sudan. How do you make the general argument
stand up?
Peter Young: I
would agree with Ed that you can have some multidonor trust
funds that work a bit better. That ARTF in Afghanistan does pump
a lot of money into key sectors and has worked relatively well.
It's a very big thing with very broad objectives that perhaps
could be distinguished from the bulk of multidonor trust
funds. I believe there are about 500 trust funds of one sort
or another run by the World Bank. Many of them have rather more
specific objectives and much poorer performance. Where it's possible
to set up something like the thing in Afghanistan, in practice,
many of them don't work. We did a study of the plans to set them
up in Zimbabwe, where they had gone down part of the route towards
setting it up, and it looked like all of the problems of South
Sudan were about to be replicated. The donors generally decided
to pull away and not put money into that fund. Many of the things
don't function.
Chair: We're not yet halfway
through the questions we want to ask you, and we're threequarters
of the way through the time we've allocated. I think we're going
to have to speed things up.
Q106 Anas Sarwar:
Just very quickly, it's already been mentioned a few times that
DFID is moving down to 2% of admin costs, and you quite rightly
pointed out the fact that the World Bank has massively higher
admin costs than DFID does. Do you think there is scope for the
World Bank to reduce its administration costs if not to 2% then
close to 2%, or is that a silly question?
Jesse Griffiths:
As has been alluded to, it is extremely difficult to know what
the answer is to the issue of admin costs. A critical component
of this, which we haven't talked about, is the use of technical
assistance. The OECD Development Assistance Committee did a report
in 2005 looking at technical assistance, and estimated that, according
to the statistics, 25% of aid is spent on technical assistance.
If you dig deeper and include technical assistance that is attached
to other programmes, it goes to 50%. The question is, to what
extent are, for example, admin costs being offloaded? I used
to work in DFID Nigeria, and if DFID has a programme and various
different agencies implementing your programme, all of those agencies,
who are classed as technical assistance, themselves have administration
costs. That doesn't show up in the figures. I would worry very
much about taking any of these figures at face value. In the
World Bank's case, I think there are a lot of hidden administration
costs. For example, the Bank sees itself as a knowledge bank
and spends a lot of time on its information and research, but
to what extent is that really necessary, for example, in some
of the projects and programmes that it's implementing? To what
extent is it just a way of finding jobs for World Bank staff to
do whom you want to shunt to something that doesn't impact the
programme, which we've discovered on different occasions. It's
quite a complicated issue, and I certainly wouldn't take any of
these figures at face value.
Ed Hedger: There
are two parts to it. First of all, the pressure that is exerted
on DFID to reduce its costs should absolutely be applied in the
context of negotiations. On the DFID administration charge, I
think the evidence by the Permanent Secretary two or three weeks
ago suggests that programme posts might rise by 300 to 400. This
is partly to do with the negotiations that it has had with the
Treasury about admin in programme delivery, and how that's treated.
This 2% risks being a little misleading, partly because of the
negotiations internally on the way it's allocated, and equally
because of the indirect overheads associated with the World Bank
and other multilaterals. The question might be, were you to bring
all of the multilateral spend back under a bilateral programme,
could you run that programme effectively and achieve the same
result on the 2%? That's a question that is well worth asking.
The other point, on the World Bank itself, there's
this role that Jesse alluded to in providing global public goods
and regional public goods, whether it is a knowledge bank or taking
on other functions. That needs to be priced into that equation.
It is a value judgment about the effectiveness or otherwise of
that, but there are roles that other bilateral donors delegate
to the World Bank on their behalf, be those fiduciary, knowledge,
or the reliance on analytic sector work, which do increase those
costs. Whether those are reasonable increases is, of course,
a judgment call.
Peter Young: This
whole admin thing is just barking up the wrong tree. The question
is, is the money being spent wisely and achieving results? If
it takes 10% admin costs, or 0.5% admin costs, it's not really
important. The issue is to do with quality and achieving the
results, and whatever you need and whatever you want to brand
as admin should be applied in order to achieve the results.
Chair: A tickbox
approach, unfortunately, seems to dominate the way these things
are done.
Q107 Hugh Bayley:
The Bank's Independent Evaluation Group has made some quite penetrating
criticisms of the efficiency and effectiveness of certain Bank
programmes. Does that mean it's doing a good job? What would
you say about how efficient and effective the IEG is overall,
or would you say that its investigations are too burdensome, too
timeconsuming?
Jesse Griffiths:
I think the IEG does a good job overall. I don't think it's a
large burden on the organisation, given that any organisation
of that size ought to be doing the kind of evaluations that the
IEG is doing anyway. It makes sense for an arm's length body
to do it rather than inhouse. There are issues, though.
There are two main issues that I would highlight. First, the
IEG bases its own evaluations on internal World Bank assessments.
For example, when it reports what percentage of health programmes
in subSaharan Africa are satisfactory, as it did and found
that only 27% were, it's basing that on the Bank's own evaluation
rather than doing its own independent evaluation.
That hits on a second critical point, which is that
there isn't a culture of independence within evaluation more broadly
within the Bank. The kinds of evaluations that the Bank does
itself are more geared towards proving that what the Bank did
was the right thing, than necessarily having an independent assessment
that could feed back into better results. Independence overall
within the Bank is probably a bigger issue, to my mind, than the
IEG's own operation, which I think works, on the whole, rather
well.
Q108 Jeremy Lefroy:
I'd like to ask this question to Mr Griffiths first. You have
expressed concern that a significant expansion of the Bank's work
in health is commencing without evidence that the major failings
that we've already discussed have been addressed. How do you
think the Bank can improve its performance on health programmes?
Jesse Griffiths:
There are three issues. The first is: should we be encouraging
the Bank, which has a bad track record on health, to be massively
increasing its role in health? Aren't there other organisations,
like the Global Fund, or bilateral programmes, or other ways that
health outcomes could be achieved more effectively? That's a
very important question.
Secondly, the Bank still has issues in terms of the
kinds of policies that it promotes through its health programme.
In the past there has been this big debate about user fees.
The Bank insisted on promoting user fees in developing countries
for a long period of time, and only eventually gave in and agreed
that it makes more sense for countries to offer health services
free at the point of delivery if you actually want people to use
them. Those kinds of issues about its overall health perspective
still linger. For example there's a great deal of concern, which
Oxfam has raised in a report called Blind Optimism, that
it overpromotes the private sector's health provision role,
when in fact in many developing countries that's either negligible
or not the main way in which people receive health services.
There are questions about the policies it promotes.
Then the IEG report is based on actual implementation
problemswhether it achieved what it set out to doand
found that in many cases it didn't, particularly in subSaharan
Africa. My question would be more: if the Bank has all of these
problems, why is that we keep looking to the Bank to be the solution?
My overall perspective on the Bank is that it should focus on
the areas where it has an advantage or a strong track record,
and other institutions can pick up other areas. Health, to me,
doesn't seem to be one where an expansion of Bank activity is
necessary.
Q109 Jeremy Lefroy:
One followup to that: would you say it's partly to do with
the kind of people, and the background of those people, the Bank
uses in those projects? Clearly we have very different health
systems in the developed world, ranging from statebacked
insurance systems, such as in Germany, much more privatesector
insurance systems such as in the US, or free at the point of delivery,
such as in the UK. Is there a problem in that there are people
from a certain background who are driving the health programme?
Jesse Griffiths:
I think so. There is not quite an ideology, but there's certainly
a perspective that the Bank has, which its staff have, which is
not necessarily the one that would be most beneficial. It is
promoting, if you like, a more privatised or private sectorled
health delivery system, and not paying enough attention to the
fact that you also need strong public institutions if you want
to deliver health care for all in the developing world. In any
country, in fact, you need either strong regulatory or strong
delivery systems.
Q110 Alison McGovern:
Very briefly, in Britain the Civil Service changed massively post1945,
because they had to deliver the NHS and largescale public
welfare programmes. Is this question in fact linked to our discussion
earlier, which is that the development of public services and
a sort of welfare state for developing countries is linked to
the development of the Civil Service? Would I be right in making
that assumption, would you say?
Jesse Griffiths:
There is no question but that if you want to deliver, as the Millennium
Development Goals set out for example, massively improved health
care or education for populations in the developing world, then
Government or Governmentregulated service providers will
play the majority role. The Oxfam Report looked at the evidence
and found that, although the Bank, for example, highlights what
percentage of people go to privatesector deliverers when
they're looking for health care, mostly they're talking about
going to a chemist, a local healer or some probably untrained
person, rather than using an effective health system. It concluded
that only the countries that had invested in public health infrastructure
could actually demonstrate those kinds of improvements that we
all want to see.
Q111 Anas Sarwar:
I'll just move on slightly. Do you think DFID and the World Bank
are doing enough to help developing countries counter tax evasion
and also the misuse of tax havens by multinational and transnational
corporations? If not, what more do you think they should and
could be doing?
Peter Young: The
issue of not paying taxes is most important in respect of the
countries themselves. There are a lot of countries where, basically,
the elites in particular don't pay tax. I won't list them, because
it would be a long list. The most important thing is for those
tax administration systems in those countries to be strengthened,
the governance to be strengthened, such that people in those countries
pay tax. If they don't pay tax, why should we be sending them
money to enable them to afford not to pay tax? If they don't
pay tax, they have no stake in the system. That to me is the
critical issue, rather than what multinationals are doing, which
is no doubt important in itself, but not nearly as important as
making sure that people in the countries themselves, particularly
those running the countries, actually pay some tax.
Jesse Griffiths:
The amounts that developing countries lose every year, as I'm
sure you've seen, in terms of tax avoidance and evasion, are in
the hundreds of billions, so it is a very important issue, and
I don't think the Bank is doing enough. In September, the IFC,
the World Bank's private-sector arm, approves a loan to Petra
Diamonds in Tanzania. Petra Diamonds is based in Jersey and the
revenue from that will be channelled through a company based in
Bermuda, so there are still serious issues. In April, the Bank
finally issued a policy on how it deals with offshore financial
centres, but most independent experts who have reviewed that don't
think it goes anywhere near far enough. For example, there is
no due diligence procedure that ensures that, for every project
where offshore financial centres are involved, they should properly
check that isn't being done to avoid tax. The Bank is picking
up the issue but it ought to be doing a lot more.
Q112 Anas Sarwar:
Is DFID doing enough?
Jesse Griffiths:
It's hard to say, because I'm not sure it's necessarily DFID's
responsibility to solve some of these issues. For example, many
experts and campaigners are calling for countrybycountry
reporting, so that all multinationals should report what taxes
they pay, what revenues they earn, in every country in which they
operate, which is one of the main things that might help solve
this problem, but DFID cannot do that.
Q113 Anas Sarwar:
Would you be in favour of such legislation in the UK?
Jesse Griffiths:
Yes.
Q114 Pauline Latham:
We know that the World Bank is a bit patchy on gender. We also
know that the genderrelated MDGs are particularly off track.
You said earlier that women choosing to have fewer children,
women getting a good education, women getting good health care,
improves the lot of everybody in the country and the wealth of
the country. How do you feel that the World Bank could improve
its performance on gender?
Jesse Griffiths:
There is a serious issue in terms of how it mainstreams gender
across its overall portfolio. The IEG Report found that in the
financial year 2009 the number of World Bank projects that were
genderinformed fell from 45% to 38%. There is a sense that
maybe they're not taking it seriously enough. They did have this
gender assessment plan and strategy that we had hoped would push
them forward, but it doesn't seem to have done that. I know DFID
has made gender one of their key issues for the IDA replenishment,
which is welcome. Like all of these things, it requires a real
stepchange in attitude and culture at the Bank. That can
only come from the top, and yet there doesn't seem to have been
enough attention paid to it, to my mind, by President Zoellick.
Q115 Pauline Latham:
Do you think that the new shadow chairman of UN Women will have
an impact on the World Bank as well as on the UN?
Jesse Griffiths:
I hope so, but I think it will be difficult. Certainly in terms
of relative power and influence, the Bank is much more powerful
than most UN agencies, so it often tends to be the other way around
that influence spreads. It was a good idea to set up that institution
and merge existing institutions into it, and I hope that it will
have that impact. That requires that institution to be backed
up by Governments, including the UK's Government.
Q116 Jeremy Lefroy:
Do you think that the World Bank is supporting the right sectors
in developing countries? Are there particular public sector areas
or industries that you feel that the World Bank should be supporting
but isn't at the moment?
Ed Hedger: One
piece of evidence from our side was some survey analysis we carried
out in a range of countries in Africa and South Asia, asking about
the comparative advantages of different multilateral organisations.
One thing that was reported there was a preference for a focus
in a lot of the cases on infrastructural and productive sectors,
which is not necessarily well attended to by some of the bilateral
organisations that don't have the scale of budget to address that,
nor sometimes the inclination, in tandem with the social sectors,
which are obviously absolutely critical as well, so that sort
of feedback. I wouldn't have a particular view on whether it
supports the right sectors. Of course, one of the arguments in
favour of the multilateral channels is that they are capable of
supporting a whole range of sectors and therefore dealing with
systemic issues, but that specific feedback was given on productive
and infrastructure.
Q117 Jeremy Lefroy:
That would therefore add greater weight to our concern about the
problems you've already raised on procurement, because infrastructure
programmes inevitably require much greater procurement.
Ed Hedger: In our
discussion, we've ranged across fragile and postconflict
states, and other aiddependent lowincome countries
as well. Of course there is the IBRD class of borrower countries,
where there might be much stronger countries. I suggest it wouldn't
be right to generalise across that whole range of countries.
Much of the problems you're talking about are particularly focused
on the most fragile and, therefore, the most weakly capacitated
countries.
Q118 Jeremy Lefroy:
Would you view agriculture, which many of people have raised as
a sector that needs far more investment in the coming years, as
one in which the World Bank has expertise and could make a contribution
to, particularly smallholder agriculture?
Ed Hedger: I'm
not a particular specialist in terms of my knowledge on that.
I could certainly ask colleagues who do work on that to offer
a view.
Jesse Griffiths:
The truth is the Bank engages in almost every sector. That's
part of the problem, as I mentioned earlier. For me, it's more
how it engages in different sectors. Yes, it is right that much
more attention should be paid to agriculture. There have been
problems with the Bank's overall approach. For example, the Foreign
Investment Advisory Services, which the Bank runs, have been implicated
in pushing changes to developing country laws that facilitate
the "land grab" as people are calling itthe increasing
buyingup of developing country agricultural land by foreign
investors and countries. There are problems about the approach
it takes. One that is particularly controversial at the moment
is to do with energy, because the Bank is reviewing its energy
strategy and yet, this year, lent its highest ever amount, over
6 billion, to fossil fuel projects. That is not to say that
the Bank should be telling developing countries what kind of energy
systems they should be running, but rather that the Bank, with
limited resources, might better focus on energy solutions that
actually reach the poorest and help countries transition to lowcarbon
solutions, rather than providing its expertise and support to
large infrastructure coal plants, like they did in South Africa
this year, for example.
Ed Hedger: Related
to that is one of the Independent Evaluation Group Reports at
the moment looking at this issue, which suggests a lack of innovation
in the way that the Bank approaches this, and also some lack of
the mix of instruments it uses. Perhaps grants, which create
less risk from the recipients, might be used to approach the more
innovative alternatives to coal power, which could then be followed
up by borrowing if those worked, so perhaps some more innovation
in the selection and mix of instruments, as well as the services.
Peter Young: Certainly
in talking with some of the former World Bank staff about these
issues, they stress there's a lot of innovation in the whole knowledge
area. I think it's a very good investment in the World Bank that
it does put so much into research and thinking through these various
issues, but there's much less innovation in the lending area.
The priority is largely to get money out of the door, because
people are judged on how much money they get out of the door,
more than anything else. I agree very much with what you're saying
there, Ed.
Ed Hedger: Added
to that, another push in terms of negotiations around the replenishment
is this question of the resultsbased lending instrument
and what that starts to look like, which I understand is still
some three to six months away from board approval. Therefore,
the decision can be made of allocation ahead of that, but that
might start to push away from disbursing loans into something
that looks at tackling the results in general more strongly.
Q119 Hugh Bayley:
In your evidence and your comments today, the Bretton Woods Project
has advocated some quite sweeping reforms for the World Bank.
You seem to be arguing that the UK's IDA16 contribution, whatever
size it is, should be made conditional upon changed behaviour
by the Bank. In other words, conditionality should apply. We've
put these questions to DFID, and their senior officials had this
criticism of conditionality: if each and every IDA donor attached
conditions to their IDA contributions, so that they could withdraw
funding or hold back funding if various conditions weren't met,
you could have absolute chaos. There'd be a lack of predictability
for the Bank. She said to us, "There would be absolutely
no certainty, no predictability and no ability for countries to
know how much money they were going to get, and the whole thing
would collapse." One obviously wants to change for the better
some of the things the Bank does badly, but surely it would be
a very bad thing to make funding to IDA conditional in the sense
that it could be withdrawn partway through the IDA round if certain
conditions weren't met. How would you coordinate the conditions?
Different donors would have different views about priorities.
Jesse Griffiths:
I actually agree 100% with that, so I think we were mischaracterised,
perhaps, in that evidence session. In fact, I think it is a problem
with the IDA round that it does focus attention on what donors
want and not so much what developing countries want or what civil
society and Parliament want, for example. There's very little
interaction in that round from people who are more impacted.
What we say, and we've said this in a statement with nine other
UK NGOs, is that what matters, at the end of the day, is the total
amount given by the UK Government. That, if you like, is an assessment
by the Government on: has the Bank made enough progress that we
can give it more or less money? When it does that, it should
take into account the critical issues, which we think are things
like climate and energy, gender and overall governance. I guess
our assessment is that the Bank hasn't made enough progress on
those to be given the seal of approval that would come with the
UK increasing its dollar contribution.
Q120 Hugh Bayley:
That's very helpful. Also in the evidence that we received from
DFID was a suggestion that the Bank needs a crisis intervention
window. If you look at the way that the IMF and the World Bank
responded to the global financial crisis and the global food crisis,
there was a lot of resource made available and speedy responses,
particularly through the IMF, to countriesby and large
not the poorest countriesto help them protect themselves
against the international financial crisis, but relatively less
funding was available to the poorest countries, because the instruments
weren't available. Does the panel in general support DFID's ambition
that some World Bank funds should be held back to deal with crises
of this nature when they affect lowincome countries? In
particular, she had a proposal that, since IBRD has become recapitalised
quite substantially, one might set up a mechanism whereby IDA
could in effect borrow from IBRD and then make grant funding available
to lowincome countries and pay back IBRD in the fullness
of time. How would people react to those two suggestions?
Jesse Griffiths:
That second suggestion I think would be wrong, would be a disaster,
because essentially what it's saying is that, in times of a crisis,
we should allow lowincome countries to borrow more money.
Q121 Hugh Bayley:
Forgive me, I don't think that's what she was suggesting. She
was suggesting there should be borrowing by one arm of a bank
from another to enable grants, aid in the form of gifts, to be
made available to a lowincome country hit by a food crisis
where it has a food deficit.
Jesse Griffiths:
If you're talking about a transfer from IBRD to IDA, which could
then be given as grants, in terms of retained income from IBRD
that goes to IDA and is given as grants, I don't have a problem
with that. My understanding of the proposal is more that IDA
could make use of the borrowing capacity of IBRD. Maybe I misunderstood
but, if it is a loan from IBRD to IDA that then has to be repaid,
then it has to be paid back. Maybe I don't quite fully understand
exactly what she was proposing.
Q122 Hugh Bayley:
The idea of having resources retained to deal with crises is something
that certainly you support, but you'd like to know more detail
about how it would be financed.
Jesse Griffiths:
I support it but I worry about whether the Bank is the right window
in which to do that, given how slowly it reacted this time around.
As with all the problems we've discussed about disbursement,
can we really rely on that to react more quickly next time? I
wouldn't be so certain.
Hugh Bayley: ODI and Adam
Smith?
Ed Hedger: Part
of this question is bound up in what the instrument looks like,
and an instrument that should attract support is one that is capable
of overcoming exactly these rigidities. My understanding of the
proposed instrument, which I think incidentally represents, to
some extent, an emerging success for UK negotiation within the
IDA roundit was added in later in addition to the special
themes, because of this response, these problems around slow lendingis
to break down these silos of trust funds. The particular class
of trust funds associated with fragile states in these crisis
environments is locked in funds. The Indonesia one particularly
has a large amount locked into it. A mechanism that can do that
and can respond faster, which has soft earmarking rather than
hard earmarking, would seem to be sensible. Related to this question
of sweating other bank assets in order to provide temporary additional
resources to IDA, it's one again that I haven't looked at in detail,
but more looked at the additional contributions through the CRW.
Peter Young: I
would also agree that the Bank really isn't the organisation to
react quickly to things. I quoted earlier from the Bank's own
analysis of its implementation in fragile states, where it referred
to all of those problems. One of the difficulties is that donors
are giving money to the World Bank. They don't then have direct
control over it, so they want to impose greater controls over
how it's spent to make sure that things are done properly and
whatever. It's an awful lot easier just to control the funds
oneself and then spend those quickly. Accountability is much
more immediate if it's to DFID or whatever it is that's spending
money directly. You don't have to construct these elaborate rules
and so forth, have them interact with the Bank's own rules for
this and that. Generally speaking, crisis stuff, best to do it
bilaterally, I would have thought.
Ed Hedger: Part
of the challenge is these rules are the rules insisted upon by
those who are making the financial contributions.
Peter Young: That's
exactly what I'm saying. The donors want to insist on the rules,
because they can't be absolutely sure it's going to be spent.
You get the extra rules imposed by the donors, which then make
it difficult to move fast. Why don't the donors just spend it
themselves, then it's easier.
Ed Hedger: I think
it's probably a question of scale of resourcing and also perhaps
it's convenient to be able to pass those rules across.
Jesse Griffiths:
Any crisis response would have to be done multilaterally, otherwise
you get the "donor darling" effect where some countries,
if it was just done bilaterally, may have access and others wouldn't.
Peter Young: They
can agree with each other. We'll put in this amount of money;
they'll put in that amount of money.
Ed Hedger: CRW
is a potential mechanism in order to achieve that. The breakdown
in that co-ordination is exactly typified by the challenge there.
Q123 Chair: We're
getting close to the end, but not there yet. You mentioned climate
change before. I don't want to pursue that other on a very specific
point. We raised your concerns with the Minister about lowcarbon
and highcarbon investment. His comment is, "If there
is an alternative," that's an alternative to fossil fuel
or particularly coal, "that can be delivered for energy production
in [a particular] country
it's not just fine; it's desirable.
But the problem is that in so many countries you cannot, at the
flick of a switch as it were, have another source of energy production."
The question of IDA16 is: to what extent is it realistic to believe
it can deliver lowcarbon solutions, which, after all, are
more expensive? Are you actually suggesting that they shouldn't
under any circumstances, as opposed to the South African circumstances,
support coalfired or other forms of fossil fuel power stations?
Jesse Griffiths:
I think they should phase it out. That is the position we and
other NGOs have adopted. Over a time period, I think to 2020
for the lowincome countries and for 2015 for middleincome
countries, we have suggested the World Bank phases out of fossil
fuel funding, for a number of reasons. First, if it's serious
about climate change, then it shouldn't be making the problem
worse. Secondly, the World Bank in energy is a very small player,
particularly in middleincome countries but also in many
lowincome countries. With its limited resources, where
is it best for those to be focused? We think there are two areas:
first improving energy access for the poorest, which is actually
an interesting question. If you really want to improve energy
access for the poorest, for example when we know that the majority
of poor people live in rural areas, which are often a long way
from electricity grids
Q124 Chair: Sorry,
that's not entirely true nowadays. There are increasingly poor
people living in urban areas, where they can get access.
Jesse Griffiths:
Absolutely the urban poor is growing as a whole, but still the
vast majority of people living on less than one dollar a day live
in rural areas. Those are the difficulttoreach people
for energy access that an institution like the Bank, focused on
poverty reduction, ought to be focusing on. In those cases, the
decentralised lowcarbon solutions are much more applicable.
Peter Young: What
is that by the way? Where's the energy coming from?
Jesse Griffiths:
If you're talking about rural areas without access to the electricity
grid, you have to talk about, for example, solar or other ways.
Peter Young: Solar
will power a light bulb but it won't power motive power. We're
working mainly on the energy in Nigeria, and there one of the
main problems is there isn't much electricity to speak of, which
is a terrible problem for the economy. You have to build gasfired
power stations, because there is gas, and actually that is environmentally
beneficial, because at the moment they're flaring the gas. Flaring
untreated gas is very, very bad. All sorts of pollutants go directly
into the atmosphere. In that case, it's absolutely essential
that one pushes ahead with a programme of constructing gasfired
power stations, which one hopes is done mainly by the private
sector. It varies country by country, as to what is the appropriate
solution. The main problem there is the electricity grid is there,
but there's no damn electricity coming down the wires. That's
what the problem is there.
Jesse Griffiths:
You're absolutely right: there doesn't seem to be any problem
with the private sector building gas power stations, coal power
stations or fossil fuels in general. The question is always:
why does the Bank have to take part in that?
Q125 Chair: Just
to clarify before I bring in Richard Harrington, you obviously
have a difference of view, but in a sense what you're saying is
the World Bank's involvement is low and it should therefore concentrate
on trying to help low carbon, but you don't disagree that the
mix is required. It's more of an argument of how funds it.
Jesse Griffiths:
Yes.
Peter Young: There
are things the Bank can do, for example providing some of the
partial risk guarantees that will take away some of the political
risk that would allow the private sector to come in and put in
the appropriate investment. Those things in the energy area are
very helpful and important. Whether it's just the traditional
thing of trying to build bits of infrastructure, the Bank really
doesn't have the funds and we have to rely on the private sector.
We come back to the same issue of some of the deficiencies in
some of the systems. We're generally not involved in building
infrastructure, but we are a little bit in Nigeria in overseeing
it. In some transmission lines, the contracting process started
eight years ago and not one single pylon has yet been built.
Some of those problems also exist in the infrastructure area.
Q126 Richard Harrington:
Conveniently, Peter, just mentioning the private sector and their
own development, which we have not covered very much today, I'm
obviously very aware that the Bretton Woods Project has expressed
serious doubts as to the value added by the use of the private
sector. I would be very interested in comments on what people
feel about the relationship between the World Bank Group and the
private sector, whether it should be further developed and, if
so, how that should be.
Peter Young: I
think private sector investment is absolutely critical, because
the resources aren't there in the public sector to solve these
development problems. Trying to facilitate private sector investment
is absolutely a critical thing for the Bank and other donors to
be focusing on. The Bank does do that to a good extent but, I
agree with you that that should be central to the Bank's activities,
as well as that of other donors.
Jesse Griffiths:
I agree. We're not at all critical of the role of the private
sector. It plays a vital role in development. It's a question
of how the Bank interacts with the private sector that we're concerned
about. Mostly that's the role of the International Finance Corporation,
the private sector arm of the Bank, which has a number of different
concerns about what it does. If you look at the most recent IEG
evaluation of that, it found that, in only 25% of cases did it
add value; i.e. did it do something that the finance that could
be available through banks and other private-sector institutions
wasn't doing. In only 25% of cases did it actually provide something
in terms of improving social environmental sustainability or improving
the design of the projects. One of our main concerns is that
here you have a publicly backed institutionthe British
taxpayer provides the capital on which the IFC lendsdoing
things that are in a sense replicating what private-sector lending
institutions are doing, and not adding that much value. There
is a real problem with its overall focus. What is the point of
the IFC if it doesn't do stuff that the private sector wouldn't
do?
Q127 Richard Harrington:
Does the IFC actually compete for loans? They'll be a loan process;
somebody wants to borrow some money and the IFC will compete against
commercial
Jesse Griffiths:
In essence the IFC's strategy is to follow the market. Wherever
the market is, we try to engage in that. There's a rationale
for that, but our argument is that that's in no way, for example,
opening up new markets to companies that can't get credit.
Q128 Richard Harrington:
You think it should follow defects within the commercial financial
sector really, rather than keeping within mainstream lending.
Jesse Griffiths:
Exactly, it should be trying to lend to countries and businesses
that find it very difficult to access credit, so small businesses
in particular, small and medium enterprises, and lowincome
countries. As the DFID submission points out, only 10% of IFC
lending went to lowincome countries in the last round so,
to our mind, it's focusing where it doesn't need to focus.
Q129 Hugh Bayley:
Two final questions: the first to Peter Young; the second to Ed
Hedger and Jesse Griffiths. Mr Young, I'll probably appal you
by saying I found your approach this morning statist in the extreme.
You seem to be arguing it should be for donor countries and their
Governments to just get on and do the job, and engaging with civil
society and parliamentarians in the country in question was just
an encumbrance; it would just waste time and delay delivery and
make the whole process slow and ineffective. How would you respond?
If you look at the American role in Afghanistan, by spending
money outside the Government of Afghanistan process, they were
failing to develop Afghanistan's own capacity to manage its own
affairs, and were spending money hopelessly inefficiently compared
with the World Bank. How would you respond to this appalling
charge that the Adam Smith Institute is statist in the extreme?
Peter Young: Firstly,
I want to say that Adam Smith International is not the same as
the Adam Smith Institute. It's a separate employeeowned
company, so I don't want to be held to account for what the Adam
Smith Institute says. I think also that your characterisation
of my views is entirely incorrect. You give the example of me
saying that adding the Nigerian Parliament into the process of
approving every single bank loan was going to slow the whole thing
down to suggest that I would be against consulting with local
people, including with the Parliament, on the direction of what
a particular donor should be doing, engaging with civil society
and so forth. I think that's all a very good thing. The processes
that one uses once you're trying to actually do something need
to be relatively streamlined, so that you can do something within
a reasonable amount of time. If it's going to take you five years
after you originally identified it as a problem, the problem is
probably a different problem by that point.
With regard to USAID in Afghanistan, I hope that
no one from USAID pores over the minutes of these meetings, but
I don't think USAID is a terribly efficient donor. I would agree
with that. They seem to spend very large amounts of money compared
with the results that are often achieved. This whole business
of tying their aid is clearly the wrong thing: forcing everyone
to travel on US airlines and all this type of thing. It's a very,
very bureaucratic organisation, not too dissimilar in fact to
the EU's aid programme. I don't think you should mix up the issue
of use of incountry systems with the issue of trying to
get support and understanding from the Government. If you agree
with the Government, after a consultation on what you want to
do, you can involve the Government or the host country in that
procurement process. For example, have them sit on the panel;
have them express their views, but don't ask them to do the whole
thing themselves if they don't have the administrative systems
to do so and the result will be the thing's a mess. Get their
involvement and support, but in appropriate ways.
Q130 Hugh Bayley:
Thank you for correcting my misrepresentation of your views.
I'm grateful. To Mr Hedger and Mr Griffiths, I think and I believe
you think and indeed Mr Young thinks it's important for the Bank
to be transparent and engage with people in the countries they're
trying to help to make sure that their policies are regarded as
sensible, useful and benign. How should the World Bank better
engage with civil society and parliamentarians in Part II
countries?
Ed Hedger: I would
say, firstly, directly, which it's likely to do. For example
we're talking in the governance sphere, in strengthening parliamentary
oversight, scrutiny, committees, working with those sorts of capacitybuilding
efforts, engaging civil society. There is greater work more broadly
around participatory processes and povertyreduction strategies
and so on, so there is progress under way. Indirectly, it's partly
by greater attention to the internal dynamics, so these questions
of accountability. Conditionally was raised earlier. For example,
in Liberia it took a very long time to pass the public financial
management revised law, because it was stalled in the Parliament
for 18 months, whereas the responsibility for conditions
that were missed was not met. The executive was incapable of
meeting them, so a greater sensitivity and attention to those
sorts of details would be important.
Jesse Griffiths:
I think it's possibly the most important question for the Bank,
and there are lots of different parts to the answer. Transparency
of the Bank's operations is important, and the Bank's new disclosure
policy is a lot better, but there are still problems of implementation.
Also, one major area where transparency doesn't apply is in terms
of the Bank's negotiations, or the process by which the Bank ends
up with, for example, a project or a loan that is not visible
to parliamentarians or civil society, so you only get it when
it actually gets approved, which I think is problematic. Secondly,
the point you raised about parliamentary approval: of course it
makes sense for Parliaments to scrutinise the Bank's overall approach
and the Bank's activities in that country, particularly in countries
that are heavily aiddependent, where the Bank will be a
major player, not just in terms of delivering projects but also
in terms of influencing the overall Government's approach to different
issues. If there is no parliamentary scrutiny there then, in
effect, you're undermining democracy in that country if the Bank
is just allowed to get on and do what it wants to do.
Conditionality has been mentioned. I think progress
has been made but a lot more progress needs to be made. I simply
don't agree that it's right for the Bank to set conditions in
sensitive policy areas, which should really be agreed by the Government
in negotiation with the Parliament and its people, not by the
Government in negotiation with a donor. Finally, I think there
are still issues of accountability. What are the mechanisms,
in particular recourse mechanisms, that people have if they are
impacted by Bank projects on the ground? The Bank does have an
inspection panel and various other bodies, but we are particularly
concerned, or a lot of NGOs are particularly concerned, about
the lack of recognition of human rights responsibilities that
the Bank has. You can't, for example, have recourse on human
rights grounds to the Bank as an institution in a country, which
I think is a severe problem.
Chair: Thank you very
much. We had a lot of questions, but quite a lot of others were
raised that we didn't have, and I think we've had some very interesting
answers. I just might mention to you, as you made passing reference
the role of the European Union, that the Committee is considering
an investigation into the European Union as a development partner
for DFID, so we may well be looking to you for a contribution
on that in due course in light of some of the comments you made
en passant. Thank you, all three of you, very much. It's good
to see a debate among the panel as well as collective evidence,
so thank you for that and obviously for your submissions. We
look forward to working with you again. I'm sure we will. Thanks
very much.
|