Fixed-term Parliaments Bill - Political and Constitutional Reform Committee Contents


Examination of Witness (Questions 58-91)

PROFESSOR ROBERT BLACKBURN

7 SEPTEMBER 2010

  Q58  Chair: Welcome, Professor Blackburn. I'm sorry that we have overrun by a couple of minutes, but we can make that good if we get to 12 o'clock. I was remiss—Mr Hunt and Mrs Laing put me right—so it might be helpful if you just take a few minutes to introduce your remarks and your paper to give a refresher to colleagues around the table.

  Professor Blackburn: Thank you, Chair, and thank you for inviting me to speak to you today.

  In the written paper that I sent in advance, I just gave a few thoughts. This is a fairly complex legal, constitutional and political issue, and even now I am not sure that I have managed to digest all the implications of the Bill as you yourselves are in the process of doing.

  The point I tried to make by historically looking at the genesis of this Bill was that it is, I think, fairly clear that it is driven by the political self-interest of the coalition Government. They want to fix the lifetime of this Government—not the Parliament, but the Government—and I explain that in various ways. It is clear what the advantage is, both to the Conservative Party leadership and the Liberal Democrat leadership, of fixing this arrangement for five years. The Liberal Democrats want to be sure that the Conservative leadership would not cut and run in the same way that a minority Administration with an informal pact with the Liberal Democrats in Parliament might—as in 1974, although there wasn't a pact then—without some assurance. The other side of the coin, of course, is that the Conservatives want some guarantee that the Liberal Democrats won't change their mind.

  This is particularly important in the present financial climate whereby some fairly unpopular measures are going to have to be taken, such as public expenditure cuts and raising taxation. So it is to the advantage of the Government to help to implement their financial programme and hopefully, from their own point of view, come out the other side restoring some popularity before they meet the electorate again.

  That leads me to the conclusion that there is a confusion of purpose behind this Bill between, on the one hand, dealing with the immediate situation, or crisis, in the coalition Government, and, on the other—this should be the main purpose of the Bill—reforming the law relating to election timing. I think it's a shame that they are not being dealt with in two different processes; they very easily could be dealt with in two separate processes.

  I very briefly touched on the consequences of the Bill, which I could say more about later. I have also put forward what would probably be my own preference for a fixed-term Parliament arrangement, but I hasten to add that I think that there is no perfect model that can be taken for election timing. There are a number of different schemes that would work, and perhaps we will discuss those later.

  If one took some of the conclusions from what Dr Jack has just been saying, for example, you could adopt a much more minimalist reform, which would solve some of the main mischiefs. Perhaps I should also say that in approaching this Bill, as it does have quite a lot of consequences and aspects to it, one obviously needs to be clear about what you think its main purposes are. What is it you are trying to achieve through this legislation and what are the main mischiefs that you are trying to resolve? There might not necessarily be consensus about that.

  In my own view, the guiding principle or purpose behind reform of election timing should be to do something about curbing the excessive power that a Prime Minister has had over the general election date. That is the main objective. There are other things that would be desirable as well, such as ensuring that the monarchy doesn't get drawn into politics, which would be damagingto the institution itself, and could very well end up with the result that one political party was seriously upset about the outcome. Later on, we might look at some historical episodes that show how that could arise again in the future. I think that's all I should say for now.

  Q59  Chair: On a point of history, while of course there is a current political situation—as there always is—and that has been a trigger, none the less all parties at various points have been committed to fixed-terms. I'm thinking back: the Labour Party was certainly committed to that under its leader Neil Kinnock, and I know that on occasions stuff has been approved through the policy-making process through the Labour Party on a fixed-term Parliament. Of course there have to be the right political circumstances for something like this to happen, but none the less there's a long history of people proposing changes in the relationship between the Executive and the legislature, of which this is one part.

  Professor Blackburn: I think that's right. The idea of fixed-term Parliaments has slowly gathered momentum over the last 20 years, and it is quite striking that there does now seem to be a virtual consensus that something ought to be done about election timing, and that the Prime Minister has an excessive amount of power over the issue. But, of course, the devil is in the detail of exactly how you draft a fixed-term arrangement. So, yes, I absolutely agree with that.

  Q60  Mrs Laing: Can we call on your knowledge of similar legislatures in other countries to examine the issue of the actual term of a fixed-term Parliament? In practice, during the past 70 or 80 years, in normal times, Parliaments have generally tended in this country to last for four years rather than five, although of course there have been different arrangements. In some parts of the world, Australia, for example—I might be wrong—there is a three-year term, although Australia at the moment is an interesting example perhaps of how not to construct a constitution, and how not to call an election for political purposes. Is there a body of evidence of which we ought to be aware that would suggest three, four or five years or some other term of Parliament?

  Professor Blackburn: My feeling on that is, no, generally speaking. One can look around the world, and there are 101 different ways of organising election timing. I think one has to evaluate this proposal within our own indigenous political and constitutional circumstances. I don't think there is a lot to be gained by going around the world, shopping around looking for the best scheme. The other thing is that you can hardly find two schemes that are identical. They are all slightly different. They all have slightly different nuances attached to them. Even within the Commonwealth where there might be a Governor General, the position of a Governor General is not the same as a monarch, so the relative powers are slightly different. Some fixed-terms relate to where there is a separation of powers, as in America of course. But there are, as you suggested, three and, probably most commonly, four-year terms. There are three-year terms in Australia and New Zealand, as you say. There are some five-year terms as well, such as in the National Assembly in France, but they have a president and a different system of Government. It is useful looking back on how long our own terms have been in the last 100 years or so. While we can take an average—the average does in fact come out almost exactly at four years—of course, the range has fluctuated depending on particular circumstances.

  Q61  Chair: But it would be true to say, wouldn't it, that most western democracies have fixed-terms for their legislature and their Executive?

  Professor Blackburn: Yes. Most. Quite a few systems have floating dates.

  Q62  Chair: None the less, there are provisions that are not normally used for extraordinary circumstances. If the President of the United States is indisposed, there are means by which—for example, in the Nixon presidency—handovers can take place, but those are for extraordinary circumstances rather than a way of getting round having a president for four years or whatever.

  Professor Blackburn: Absolutely, and of course in our own system we have the extraordinary process of a no confidence motion. There is no good reason why, in the past, Parliament couldn't have served its full term, but it has suited the Executive, particularly over the last 100 years, to keep the machinery of Dissolution well-oiled by using it on every occasion.

  Q63  Simon Hart: Both my questions have been answered, but I will think up a third one instead. We are looking at a five-year fixed-term. In a paragraph, why should we vote against that when the opportunity comes next week?

  Professor Blackburn: A judgment has to be made by yourselves as to what the right balance is between giving a Government a sufficiently long period of time to carry out their programme for office and, on the other hand, having a mechanism for accountability and responsibility to the electorate. My own feeling is that in this country five years is held to be a very long time. If you think back to five-year terms in the past, the last year of every one has been pretty awful. I think everybody has felt, [odq]For God's sake let's have an election[cdq], and usually it redounds badly on the Government as well.

  Q64  Chair: Is that because it is the last year, or because it is the fifth year? Won't there be a last year in a four-year Parliament which would be pretty awful?

  Professor Blackburn: There is a combination of both. I am not so sure, actually, that—this might confuse the issue—seven years isn't the time when people start getting fed up and want a change.

  Simon Hart: I thought that that applied to marriage rather than Parliament.

  Professor Blackburn: I think there might be something in that.

  Chair: Is this an evidence-based scientific view, Professor Blackburn? Is this your opinion?—[Laughter.]

  Professor Blackburn: All I am saying is that this might explain why Governments tend to win their second terms. If you look back at elections, it is the incumbency that usually wins a general election—even more so under a system where they can determine the election date themselves.

  Q65  Simon Hart: I rather support your view that it is not much good going round the world to try and pick decent examples. We had a debate yesterday about whether Papua New Guinea was a shining example of what was under discussion, so it doesn't always work very well. Surely there must be some examples we can call upon which help us come to a decision about whether fixing the term, if you like, at the maximum—which is what we are doing next week—is a more desirous route than fixing it perhaps at what has tended to be the average, which is four years.

  Professor Blackburn: I am not sure that you can. You can look at particular examples, but the political equation will always be different. Relative size and strength between the Government and the Opposition—all these are variables. It really comes down to a question of how strong you want Government to be and how strong you want the mechanism for accountability to the electorate to be. Things would be different if we had a separate Executive of course.

  If we had a separate Executive, the arguments for having much more frequent elections for Parliament would be much stronger—the Chartists' idea of annual Parliaments could even come into play. I have to say that I think that there is some irony in the fact that one of the big issues that has troubled the political class over the past few years—over the past 10 years I think—is disengagement from politics. How can we promote greater popular participation in politics? The irony in the proposal is that it makes elections less frequent.

  Q66  Chair: We are not confusing media participation in politics with grass-roots activism in politics, are we? They may wish to have an election every year because it's great fun and you can take strips off anybody.

  Professor Blackburn: For most people, the one occasion when they participate in the political process is a general election. I say [odq]most people[cdq] because, of course, the turnouts for other electoral processes are pretty low. This is an incredibly important issue on which legislation is being introduced. A general election really is the main political event of our democracy; it determines not just the composition of our representatives in Parliament, the legislature, but the composition of the Executive—in one act. It is a really important issue.

  Q67  Sheila Gilmore: Having read a lot of these papers, I wondered if, in fact, the difference between the impact of having fixed-terms and not having fixed-terms is slightly exaggerated, or whether it changes the mindset. For example, there seem to be ways in which, certainly in some countries and Governments, despite there being a fixed-term, elections can come along relatively frequently or can be encouraged, in one way or another, to happen. Equally, the politics of early elections—the argument that the Prime Minister can use it as a lever over his own party—still exists to some extent within the fixed-term arrangement, but maybe in a slightly different way in Scotland.

  In the current Scottish Parliament, it appears that no one has wanted to trigger that kind of vote of confidence, and, to some extent, that still gives the First Minister the power to say, [odq]If you rock the boat, we'll have an election[cdq], and people don't want that. Is this not more about the political context than the legal one?

  Professor Blackburn: I think that's right. I don't think we should get too hung up on ensuring that there isn't a general election within the fixed-term. General elections aren't necessarily a bad thing. My own feeling is that the Bill as drafted sets the threshold too high; the term is too long and it is too difficult to have a Dissolution. Personally, I'd prefer a more straightforward Bill that goes more with the grain of our system of voting in the House of Commons, and that is reflected in the alternative scheme that I put to you.

  Q68  Sheila Gilmore: In terms of making it simpler, do you therefore argue that even if it could be triggered more easily, the political realities are that that will happen only when there is a real need for it? The political parties themselves don't necessarily want to defeat a Government just for the sake of it. That has very much been the context in Scotland, certainly in the three years since the previous Scottish Parliament election. Arguably, the Government might have been overthrown, but no one has wanted to do it.

  Professor Blackburn: Absolutely, I think that there is no tradition of manipulating the power of Dissolution for party purposes in Scotland yet, whereas there has been a tradition of that over here.

  Q69  Tristram Hunt: The Committee notes your advocacy of four rather than five years and your comments about the political agenda behind the Bill. I just wanted to tease out a couple of things, first, the very interesting idea that this takes away what you call the facility, and what others might call the prerogative, of the Prime Minister to make an appeal to the people. So one goes from making something an issue of confidence—dissolving a Parliament and having an election on an issue, be it a war or a major piece of legislation—and moves towards referendum politics. Can you tease out that idea?

  Professor Blackburn: I think, historically, the idea of an appeal to the people has been one of the main justifications for the prerogative of Dissolution. As you all know, it hastended not to be a very useful weapon for the Prime Minister; it has tended to be counter-productive. Even when there was an appeal to the people over the House of Lords back in 1910, the Asquith majority went down. Of course, it also backfired famously with Edward Heath in 1974. But yes, it is there, and if there is some issue or principle on which a Prime Minister specifically wants the backing of the people, it is a mechanism for an issue of confidence: a vote of confidence in the Government that they are doing a good job and that we trust them with this particular issue. Removing it raises the whole issue of the desirability of referendums. I have some reservations about referendums, but if one was enthusiastic about them and thought people should be consulted much more , we would have to go down the route of having more referendums outside our Dissolution arrangement.

  Q70  Tristram Hunt: The other element you suggested is rather than reducing the power of the sovereign, which it does in Dissolution affairs, it could heighten the power of the monarch in terms of appointments during prolonged hung Parliaments. How would that work?

  Professor Blackburn: I think this is an interesting issue. It was an interesting issue in the May 2010 general election as well. There is a bit of a story behind all this, some of which has taken place behind closed doors. You all know that in the past when there has been a hung Parliament, it was dealt with slightly differently. With what happened in 1974, the convention was much clearer that the incumbent Prime Minister had the first opportunity to form an Administration. So Edward Heath entertained Jeremy Thorpe at 10 Downing Street to have negotiations about that. The monarchy was in the background, of course. You can look at other situations going back where the monarchy has been quite heavily involved in Dissolution or Government formation issues.

  I suppose 1931 is the most famous example to remind ourselves of where the monarchy played the leading role in what happened. From 1929 to 1931 there was a minority Labour Administration. There was the Wall Street Crash and the financial crisis. The American bankers, J P Morgan, were threatening to call in the loan that the British Government had with them unless effectively public expenditure cuts were made and agreed by the Cabinet. The Labour Cabinet could not agree on those cuts, so Ramsay MacDonald went to see King George V and informed him about all this. King George V returned from Balmoral, as I recall, in the summer in a crisis mentality. Normally, what would have happened in this type of situation is that either there would have been a general election, or MacDonald would have resigned and Stanley Baldwin, the Leader of the Conservative Party, would have taken over. Baldwin was on a yacht in the Mediterranean or somewhere and wasn't around. The King started brokering what should happen in the circumstances, consulting Sir Herbert Simon, the Liberals and so on. He more or less put together the National Government, reappointing Ramsay MacDonald as Prime Minister with the Conservatives joining in. Stanley Baldwin was quite happy to go along with that because the National Government would be implementing unpopular public expenditure cuts, yet there was a Labour figure fronting them. The Labour Party, which knew absolutely nothing about the negotiations, were outraged and expelled MacDonald, Philip Snowden and a few others from the Labour Party. That was regarded by some as a palace coup, but it just shows what can happen. The monarch was playing a very leading role in Government formation.

  Times have changed since then, but we should not be lulled into a false sense of security by the fact that, on the throne over the past 50 years, we have had a monarch who has been an absolute model of constitutional propriety. She has had absolutely no problems in suppressing her private views for her public duties. In the future, different personalities will be on the throne who will be more interventionist-minded. The whole idea behind having an hereditary Head of State is that we do not know what human nature will throw up. We need to have some constitutional machinery to deal with the position of a Head of State and, by the same token, to deal with exercising the royal powers of Government formation and the appointment of a Prime Minister.

  Q71  Tristram Hunt: My final question is about your own model for what should happen, the idea of the permanent Parliament. An early election is followed by another term of Parliament, which makes up the length of the Parliament as it were. Have I got that right?

  Professor Blackburn: I always feel rather uneasy during the election campaign because there is no Parliament in existence for about five weeks. There might be an emergency, there could be a terrorist outrage or an environmental disaster, and no Parliament would be in existence. Of course, the Government still carries on. This might be seen as a small matter, but it would be more logical if we were trying to construct a good electoral and constitutional process, for Parliament to be kept in continuous existence. Of course, it would go into recess and adjourn during the election campaign, but it could be recalled by the Speaker at any time if a national crisis or disaster had to be dealt with.

  You are a professional historian, so perhaps I can digress. To answer the question in a slightly different way, it helps to have an historical perspective when evaluating the current system. The basis of our system of election timing is the relationship between the Crown and Parliament. The Crown is the ultimate authority in the state and, historically, Parliament came into existence, was summoned and dissolved as the personal creature of the Crown. As a result of the 17th century constitutional conflicts, Parliament was very concerned with its existence and, during the written constitutions in the interregnum—fascinating documents to look at—there was great concern with making sure that Parliament was summoned.

  Particularly as a result of King Charles II and his extraordinary long period of 17 years without convening a Parliament, the Triennial Act came into existence so that a Parliament should be summoned within three years and last for no longer than three years. There was then the Septennial Act in 1716. In the 20th century, as we moved into the modern era, the rather archaic system of election timing has been manipulated by the Prime Minister. We must remind ourselves that, in the 19th century, Parliaments were expected to last their full term. If we look at 19th century constitutional texts, there was an idea that Parliament could be dissolved only in certain constitutional situations, such as if there was a conflict between both Houses, a Representation of the People Act had just been passed, or if there was a division in the Cabinet.

  In the 20th century, all those conventions disappeared and we have just been left with a naked power of a Prime Minister being able to manipulate the power of Dissolution for some advantage in the electoral outcome. That is also seen to some extent in the way in which the public announcement of the general election is made, which has evolved interestingly—going back to Dr Jack's point about Standing Orders. In the first half of the 20th century, the Prime Minister usually announced a general election in the House of Commons. That was normally accompanied by a motion being put forward to give precedence to Government business for the remainder of the Session. Asquith, Baldwin and MacDonald all did this.

  Since the second world war, Standing Orders have been changed to give automatic precedence to Government business, so in the wash-up period, as it were, the Government have automatic precedence anyway. So things were replaced by the Prime Minister just putting out a press release and MPs feeling somewhat disgruntled that they were hearing the news of their own demise in the same way as everybody else, through the media. More recently, John Major turned the public announcement into a photo opportunity in 1992 outside No. 10 Downing street, and in 2001 Tony Blair took that one stage further to a photo opportunity in a schoolroom—if you remember—in south London.

  It is useful, I think, to have a historical perspective on this whole scheme of arrangement, and it would be better really, in an ideal world, to start again and not be starting from the point of view of having the royal prerogative controlling the summoning and Dissolution of Parliament. But you are talking here, I think, about a written or codified constitution. The idea of a permanent Parliament would work best in that arrangement. The German Bundestag has a system not dissimilar to this, whereby it is kept in more or less permanent existence, but there are fixed periods between the election dates.

  Q72  Chair: So the Government continue come what may, whereas Parliament is unstable in that it finishes and restarts again, really at the behest of the Executive. So, you're suggesting that Parliament should have a degree of continuity and stability, punctuated by only general elections—that it has a life of its own.

  Professor Blackburn: Absolutely. A point I make in my written evidence also, is that there are much wider issues to consider. In looking at constitutional reform more generally and being joined up, where does reform of the House of Lords fit into this electoral cycle? If you have a permanent Parliament, it makes it much easier to set up a system of elections in the second Chamber. I think that will probably emerge as the preferred option, whereby there is rotating membership or elections at different times, so that you do not have a new House being elected all at the same time.

  Q73  Mrs Laing: I was going to come on to another subject, but just to continue this idea about the permanent Parliament, you have prompted me to consider the other side of a Member of Parliament's duties, and that is our pastoral duties in our constituencies. You rightly said that Government goes on and there is no possibility for scrutiny or holding to account because there is no Parliament here in the House of Commons, but, of course, Members of Parliament have pastoral duties towards their constituents. It is a strange situation that for a month or more, a Member of Parliament has to say to constituents, [odq]I'm not your Member of Parliament. I hope I might be in another few weeks, but I'm not just now.[cdq] If one is dealing with a difficult personal case for someone, of course you don't stop doing it because there is a general election. If somebody is in difficulties, you keep helping them. Have you considered that side of a permanent Parliament?

  Professor Blackburn: No, I haven't. I think it's a very good point. I think that you should continue with your constituency duties at the same time as electioneering.

  Q74  Mrs Laing: Thank you. On to the other matter, which is the balance of power between the legislature and the Executive, the Deputy Prime Minister has said, on the record several times, that he believes that the proposals he has put forward in this Bill effectively [odq]strengthen the power of the House[cdq]. Do they, in fact, strengthen the power of the House, given that, at present, on a simple majority of Members of Parliament, the Government can be defeated on a vote of confidence, and that will no longer be the case? Does that strengthen the position of the House?

  Professor Blackburn: I'm not sure that it does. I feel that I need to still reflect upon all the implications of the Bill regarding that. My feeling is that it certainly curtails the power of the Prime Minister to control the election date, so it does something to place some limitation on the power of the Executive. I'm not sure about the extent to which it enhances the power of the House of Commons.

  Q75  Mr Chope: Does it enhance the power of the House of Commons at all?

  Professor Blackburn: I am not sure that it does. Of course, one has to take into account the influence of the party Whips and the extent to which party Back Benchers will follow the wishes of party leaders.

  Q76  Mr Chope: May I ask you the question I raised earlier with Dr Jack about what's happening with this Bill? Parliament's already begun and we are now legislating to have this Parliament with a fixed date. In Scotland, there were proposals for a fixed-term Parliament, which were then legislated on, and then that applied to subsequent Parliaments. Are you aware of any precedent whereby a Parliament has decided, after it has already been elected, to change the terms of engagement?

  Professor Blackburn: I heard you ask that question. I am afraid that my knowledge of foreign legislatures doesn't extend to a specific example of that, although I could go back and try and consult my reference books to find out. I would imagine that there are quite a few examples of that happening. Of course, the British Parliament extended its own life in the Septennial Act, so I would not be surprised if there were examples. I don't think this is an extraordinary thing to do.

  Q77  Mr Chope: What about the idea that the Bill could be amended to have fixed-terms of seven years?

  Professor Blackburn: Yes, if later on Parliament wants to change the scheme of arrangement, it can certainly do so.

  Q78  Mr Chope: You are saying in your paper that you would be in favour of just a simple majority being sufficient to trigger a general election and a Dissolution?

  Professor Blackburn: Yes.

  Q79  Mr Chope: That appeals to me, simplistically. How would that work in a hung Parliament?

  Professor Blackburn: The scheme of arrangement I had in mind was that the Prime Minister would not be able to call a general election in the same way that Harold Wilson did in 1974, unless other non-governing party Members supported the resolution. So the Prime Minister couldn't call a snap election just to try and gain a majority. Otherwise the scheme would work as at present but curtail the length of the Parliament following an early Dissolution as outlined in my written evidence. What I suggest in my scheme was that you could have a constructive motion of no confidence, whereby you could actually present the alternative Prime Minister, as well.

  Q80  Chair: On the question that a number of colleagues have raised about the balance between Executive and legislature, it may be that the legislature per se hasn't got a paragraph where it says, [odq]And this is really strengthening Parliament[cdq], but I would have thought that defining a prime ministerial power for the first time ever legitimately inhibits the Executive to an extent, and therefore, in the balance of things, Parliament in that equation is slightly stronger. Would that be true?

  Professor Blackburn: Yes. I think that's probably right. In my paper, I pointed out that the reform removes not only the tactical advantage of a Prime Minister, but what I call a sort of penal power that a Prime Minister has over his colleagues by threatening a Dissolution if they don't support him. To that extent also I think it extends the power of his parliamentary colleagues.

  Q81  Chair: We always tend to look for the things that might go wrong if there's any change, and we're a bit cautious. The Clerk produced a very good paper outlining some of the potential difficulties, but we've asked him to go away—I don't know if you were in the room at the time—and also mention one or two of the positive things. Obviously, having a full five-year session to implement a programme is not only useful for the Executive. In terms of scrutiny, having five years' worth of Select Committees and elected members and Chairs who would be able to set out a programme for five years so that perhaps we would not need to rush a couple of very important Bills on to the Floor on virtually day one, but have a measured programme over five years, are just some of the possible advantages for the legislature in conducting its business more effectively. Are there others that spring to mind, or do you accept that they are in fact useful advantages of a fixed-term?

  Professor Blackburn: As I said earlier, I think that there is a balance to be struck. There are arguments for five years, particularly in terms of planning. If that can also be combined with a culture—

  Chair: Sorry, I've confused the issue by talking about a five-year term. What are the advantages of fixed-terms, which could be four or five years?

  Professor Blackburn: Well, I think the advantage is also one of planning. I will be interested to see if the super-majority procedure goes through. That would make it very difficult for the Prime Minister to call a Dissolution himself. If there was just a simple majority, which is what I have suggested that I would prefer, I would hope that that would be accompanied by some new culture or some expectation that a Prime Minister won't call snap elections for no good reason.

  Q82  Chair: Finally, do you know of any other western democracy that has initiated a written constitution and said, [odq]We think the Prime Minister should have the power to decide when the legislature meets and when elections take place[cdq]?

  Professor Blackburn: No.

  Mrs Laing: There's a surprise.

  Q83  Mr Turner: I have two questions. First, you said that, in the 19th century, there were particular reasons for which you could call an election, and otherwise not, I assume. In the 20th century, almost the reverse has apparently been true. When did it change?

  Professor Blackburn: It was a gradual process. There is a similar debate that there used to be a convention—it was thought, anyway; perhaps it was theory and not so much practice—that it was very much a Cabinet decision, a collegiate decision. But, as Lloyd George promoted a much more Executive-minded, president-orientated chief executive—a stronger form of government—perhaps it went with the requirement in the early part of the 20th century that we needed a stronger Executive, because we were running a much larger enterprise with the welfare state, the interventionist state, not to mention dealing with the huge war effort between 1914 and 1918. I think that all those tendencies somehow elevated his position, and that they elevated his position vis-a"-vis his Cabinet colleagues. So I think that the control over the power of Dissolution has gone hand in hand with the whole process or transition from Cabinet government to prime ministerial government that has taken place over the course of the 20th century.

  Q84  Mr Turner: Secondly, we are rather talking as if everyone had a break when they had an election, but in the United States there is no such thing. There are four-yearly periods for the President, but two-yearly ones for the Congressmen and six-yearly, broken into three and therefore two-yearly for a third, for Senate. Why should we not have such a system here? After all, when I lived in Oxfordshire, it had a four-yearly term, but Oxford City Council had three separate years for each ward. Why aren't we thinking of those?

  Professor Blackburn: You mean different terms for the two Houses, or—

  Mr Turner: No, I was thinking that, let's say, a fifth of the House of Commons shall retire each year.

  Professor Blackburn: That's quite a radical proposal. It would have a major impact on Government formation; you may find that the Government suddenly lost their majority. It would lead to a fairly unstable form of government perhaps, but, so be it, if Parliament should be the determining factor in these matters. Such a system would, again, throw the whole process of Government formation into high relief. Linking it back to the question earlier—which I didn't entirely answer—in 2010 the Cabinet Office took a lead in facilitating the inter-party negotiations. There had been a draft Cabinet Manual prepared by the Cabinet Secretary that came into operation, and the previous conventions were slightly modified. I think that that did have a subtle impact on the outcome of the negotiations, but we can only conjecture upon it.

  One interesting psychological change was that 10 Downing Street was no longer the forum for negotiations, it was the Cabinet Office. That might be a good thing. Exactly who is going to be brokering this very important decision as to who is to be Prime Minister and which inter-party negotiations or which combination is going to prevail? It needs to be thought about very carefully. Is it going to be the Cabinet Secretary or the monarch? Do you revert to the incumbent Prime Minister playing a key role or should the Speaker play an enhanced role? Those factors need to be thought about very carefully. Similarly, note the idea of a confirmatory vote, which is attached to the no confidence procedure in the Bill. As I said in my written evidence, I think that this is going to give rise to the query, [odq]If you have a confirmatory vote then, should there be a confirmatory vote in the House of Commons when a new Prime Minister is appointed every time?[cdq] That would be the key issue to come out of what you have suggested.

  Q85  Nick Boles: Why are you so opposed to the super majority? Surely, the point is to stop—given that we have this merging of the Executive and Parliament in our system—a Prime Minister who has won a majority at the previous election of the House of Commons from whipping a Dissolution motion. That is a good thing. What is wrong with it?

  Professor Blackburn: I am not so opposed to it; I am a pragmatist, and I am just stating my preference. I am instinctively concerned about introducing a super majority. This is an unprecedented procedure. We haven't had this before. In what other circumstances might it be used? It would be a precedent for later on perhaps. I think a simple majority does the trick, and it goes with the grain of our parliamentary tradition in which our culture works at the moment. It means that if the House of Commons thinks that there should be a general election, there should be a general election. An election is not an unwelcome prospect, why should you make it so difficult? Taking away the power of the Prime Minister to control the election debate unilaterally and arbitrarily, and making it subject to the House of Commons—thereby having to carry his colleagues with him and a majority in the House in a minority Government or coalition situations—would be my preferred way forward.

  Q86  Nick Boles: Are you not then denying that there is any value in distinguishing between constitutional matters, which should require more than the level of support of normal matters of Government business? Certainly, is it not the case that most countries in the world feel that there should be greater protection for constitutional measures, so that they cannot be changed by the whim of a Prime Minister who happens to have a majority of five?

  Professor Blackburn: Yes, but you are talking about special procedures to change the constitution.

  Q87  Nick Boles: Isn't moving an election forward for no reason, when your Government are perfectly functioning and capable, not a constitutional change?

  Professor Blackburn: I see them as different. I think this is a political decision. I don't think general elections are necessarily unwelcome. If there is a majority feeling in the House that there should be a general election for a good reason—

  Nick Boles: Like we could increase our majority.

  Professor Blackburn: The Prime Minister is going to have to come down to the House, and give the reasons and articulate why he wants a general election. If the Opposition think he is just cutting and running because he is ahead in public opinion polls, they will say that. The electorate can then decide whether they think the Prime Minister has behaved properly, or has brought an election unnecessarily in advance and should suffer the consequences. I think there is a cultural aspect to it as well.

  Nick Boles: An unnecessarily conservative view.

  Q88  Chair: I think the cultural aspect is very important. Again, because we have 100 years of history behind us of Prime Ministers doing this, we are looking at it from the point of view of how the Prime Minister could wangle his way around a fixed-term, which is an open and clear commitment from the current Administration. Culturally, however, it would be viewed with great disdain if someone wanted to manipulate the system that the House had agreed, which I think was in manifestos—I am not too sure about that—and which has become the way we do things. People would cry foul if other people sought to play around with the rules. You would move to a different cultural view of what the political norm was. Have I got that right?

  Professor Blackburn: I would anticipate that to be the case. In your discussion with Dr Jack, I think it came out that any system can be manipulated by the Executive. I can foresee that the no confidence mechanism could be manipulated by getting someone else to table a motion and it succeeding through abstentions or whatever, and then possibly even manipulating the power of Prorogation to put off an alternative Government being confirmed within the 14-day period. Anyone who is manipulating a system as blatantly as that would suffer the consequences eventually. I hope that the new legislation will, possibly with amendments, bring in a new constitutional hygiene, as it were, into the whole process related to general election timing.

  Q89  Mr Chope: You mentioned earlier the possible interaction of the Fixed-term Parliaments Bill with an elected second Chamber. Do you think the fact that we haven't yet got a draft Bill for the second Chamber, but we're being expected to vote on this without being able to look at the two together, is a disadvantage? Would it not be much better to be able to look at the whole of this issue at one time? Are there not implications with, depending on what was to happen to the other Chamber, having a mid-term election—for want of a better expression—which would give the other Chamber a massive majority against what would be the elected Government in this Chamber?

  Professor Blackburn: Yes. All my academic colleagues and I think, [odq]For heaven's sake, what is going on with reform of the House of Lords? How long will it be put off for?[cdq] Again, there is obviously some party-political interests about the whole business. Yes, this reform needs to be dealt with in conjunction with the other part of the legislature. I can see that in practical terms it is difficult to get through some constitutional reforms, and perhaps they sometimes need to be driven through to get one change done. However I think we've reached the stage, particularly after the wide number of constitutional reforms taking place over the last 12 years or so, at which a much more joined-up approach to constitutional reform is necessary. That may require some co-operation between Select Committees to take a coherent view of what's going on and join up the different parts of the constitutional structure. The idea of a codified constitution as advocated by some would be not so much a radical reforming measure, but a means by which to bring some stability and coherence to the way forward.

  Q90  Sheila Gilmore: I have a couple of questions about what you said. Would you think that in fact, by creating fixed-term Parliaments for Scotland and the Welsh Assembly, it has created a culture change and an expectation that it would be exceptional? I would like your comment on that.

  One of the practical issues that has arisen out of the particular suggestion for five years—I know it doesn't happen every time—has been the fact that immediately, the first time that we have this new situation, we have a conjuncture of the Scottish and Welsh elections, unless something is done to move them apart. That is something that people feel quite strongly about, particularly in Scotland. The fear is that the politics in the Scottish Parliament will be subsumed in this. An effort to keep them quite separate might be valuable.

  Professor Blackburn: I agree. I think the success of the devolved Assemblies has had a subtle impact on the political culture generally within the country, and has some effect down here as well. I was struck, during the 1997 election that brought Alex Salmond to power, by the fact that when the Scottish National party got just one more seat than the Labour Party, everyone simply assumed that Alex Salmond was going to be First Minister. I wondered later on whether that had some impact on the outcome of the 2010 election, whereby there was a much stronger expectation that David Cameron, because he had got more seats, would be Prime Minister and whether that influenced Nick Clegg himself. I think that there is an organic interplay between the cultures between the different legislative assemblies.

  Q91  Chair: If there are no more questions from colleagues, would Professor Blackburn like to have a minute to conclude?

  Professor Blackburn: I would like to wish you well in your scrutiny of the Bill. Like Dr Jack, I would like to have seen this in a draft Bill. I think it is very difficult for you to perform your job of reporting to the House with such extraordinary short notice. I think this is a major reform that requires some gestation period, thinking through all its implications very carefully and separating out the different objects that are being desired. There are a few issues that we have not mentioned today, which I think need to be tidied up. If elections are going to be in May, how will that affect the annual parliamentary cycle? Are we always going to have a long period between May and November the following year, and a short final session? You are going to have to readjust that. The Bill seems to also settle the argument that has been running for some time about whether general elections should be at the weekend as part of promoting greater participation and greater turnout in elections. It seems to have been decided that it has to be Thursday.

  There are a lot of little and large consequences of the Bill, and I wish you well in your scrutiny. Thank you for inviting me.

  Chair: Professor Blackburn, thank you very much indeed. Thank you, colleagues.







 
previous page contents

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 21 September 2010