Written evidence submitted by Professor
Robert Hazell,
THE CONSTITUTION UNIT, UNIVERSITY COLLEGE
LONDON (FTPB 03)
FOREWORD
The new Conservative-Liberal Democrat coalition
government has an ambitious and wide ranging agenda for political
and constitutional reform. One of the main items, on which it
is proceeding apace, is the proposal for fixed term parliaments.
This featured in the Programme for Government, published on 20
May; with further detail given by the Deputy Prime Minister in
a statement to the House of Commons on 5 July. On 22 July the
government introduced its Fixed Term Parliaments Bill, just before
the summer recess, and indicated that Second Reading should take
place in mid September.
The rapid pace has allowed almost no time for
public consultation or debate. There has been no Green or White
Paper. The bill has not been published in draft, with time allowed
for pre-legislative scrutiny. The new Political and Constitutional
Reform Committee in the Commons will hold some quick evidence
sessions in September; and the Constitution Committee in the Lords
is to conduct an inquiry into fixed term parliaments in the autumn.
This briefing is being submitted as evidence to both Select Committees.
It is also being published to facilitate a wider debate, and to
put into the public domain evidence about the experience of fixed
term parliaments in other countries.
The Unit's work on this subject started in 2006,
when one of our summer interns, Claude Willan, did a lot of research
and left us a draft briefing. This was revised and updated by
two more interns, Ceri Lloyd-Hughes and Ruchi Parekh, with further
help from Jessica Carter. I am grateful to all of them for their
excellent research and support for this project. Without our interns
we would not be able to produce nearly as many reports, nor such
high quality work as we manage to do.
SUMMARY OF
KEY POINTS
Fixed term parliaments remove the Prime Minister's
power to decide the date of the next election. They should create
greater electoral fairness and more efficient electoral administration,
and enable better long term planning in government. Their potential
disadvantage is a loss of flexibility and accountability.
Fixed term parliaments are a big constitutional
change. Yet the government's Bill has been introduced with no
public consultation, no Green or White Paper, no draft bill. The
legislation should not be rushed. It could still be passed with
all party support: the Labour party also had a manifesto commitment
to fixed term parliaments.
The key issues to decide are: the length of
the fixed term; how to allow for mid term dissolution; how to
reform the prerogative powers of dissolution and proclamation.
The fixed term should be four years, not five.
The norm in other Westminster parliaments with fixed terms is
four years; as it is in Europe. To avoid clashes with devolved
or European elections, general elections should be held in October,
with the next one scheduled for October 2014.
The two thirds majority for mid term dissolution
is aimed mainly at majority governments. It should make it impossible
for them to call an early election without significant cross-party
support. Even if it is sometimes circumvented by engineered no
confidence motions, it should help to establish a new norm.
If the new parliament served only the remainder
of the previous term that would also be a disincentive to mid
term dissolutions.
No confidence motions will continue to come
in different forms. If government or opposition have declared
an issue to be one of confidence, the Speaker should indicate
at the beginning of the debate whether the motion is a confidence
motion.
Dissolution rules need not be too elaborate,
or restrictive. Political incentives should also prove a force
for stability. Political parties do not like frequent elections;
nor do the electorate, who may punish a party which forces an
unnecessary election.
Investiture votes are a more direct way of establishing
who can command confidence, at the beginning of a parliament,
and after successful no confidence motions.
The power of proclamation should be reformed so that
the Electoral Commission is put in charge of the election timetable,
and the date for first meeting of the new parliament is set by
the outgoing Speaker.
It is very difficult to entrench the Fixed Term
Parliaments Act. A future government and parliament can always
amend or repeal it. It will create a norm, not a rigid constitutional
rule.
One way of entrenching the Act could be to give the
Lords an absolute veto over any amendment under the terms of the
Parliament Act 1911. The Wakeham Commission recommended against
extending the veto powers of the Lords.
1. THE CURRENT
SYSTEM IN
THE UK
1.1 Length of parliamentary terms
The electoral timetable in Britain has grown
out of several pieces of legislation. The Meeting of Parliament
Act of 1694 (also known as the Triennial Act) provided that a
UK parliamentary general election must be held every three years.
This was amended by the Septennial Act of 1715 which extended
the parliamentary term to a maximum of seven years. The Parliament
Act of 1911 amended this to provide for the current five year
maximum term.
1.2 Dissolution of parliament
1.2.1 The procedure
The decision to call a general election is made
by the Prime Minister, who asks the Monarch to dissolve parliament.
This is done by a Royal Proclamation requiring the writs to summon
a new parliament to be sent out. The general election timetable
then comes into effect, running for eighteen days excluding weekends
and bank holidays.[12]
1.2.2 The Prime Minister's role
Parliament is dissolved by the Crown on the
advice of the Prime Minister. The Prime Minister makes his or
her choice independently of parliament, government, and often
even their closest colleagues in the Cabinet.
1.2.3 The Royal Prerogative
Dissolution of parliament is the Crown's prerogative.
Theoretically, the Monarch can exercise discretion over whether
to grant a request for dissolution by the Prime Minister. The
Lascelles principle provided that the Crown may justifiably refuse
a request for dissolution where:
(1) the existing Parliament was still vital,
viable, and capable of doing its job; (2) a General Election would
be detrimental to the national economy; [and] (3) he could rely
on finding another Prime Minister who could carry on his Government,
for a reasonable period, with a working majority in the House
of Commons.[13]
A modern formulation of the circumstances in
which the Monarch might refuse a dissolution is in the draft Cabinet
Manual: see section 1.3.1 below.
1.2.4 Announcing the dissolution
Since 1945, the Prime Minister has made the
announcement of dissolution to the press rather than to parliament.
Parliament does not need to be sitting. The interval between the
announcement and the dissolution itself has become shorter. From
1945 to 1970, there was an average interval of 16 days.[14]
But in February 1974 Harold Wilson gave only one day's notice.
Since then, the interval between announcement and dissolution
has rarely been more than seven days,[15]
maximising the advantage the government holds over the opposition.
1.3 Extraordinary dissolutions
Early dissolutions may take place if the government
loses the confidence of the House or decides to resign.
1.3.1 Constitutional rules governing issues of
confidenceIt is a cornerstone of the British constitution that
the government must have the confidence of the House of Commons.
Chapter 6 of the draft Cabinet Manual says:
A Government or Prime Minister who cannot command
the confidence of the House of Commons is required by constitutional
convention to resign or, where it is appropriate to do so instead,
may seek a dissolution of Parliament.[16]
Should the government resign, rather than seek
dissolution, it is for the Monarch to invite the person who appears
most likely to be able to command the confidence of the Commons
to serve as Prime Minister and to form a government. However,
it is the responsibility of the parties and politicians to determine
and communicate clearly who that person should be.[17]
The draft Cabinet Manual states the following
with regard to the choice between dissolution and resignation:
A Prime Minister may request that the Monarch
dissolves Parliament and hold a further election. The Monarch
is not bound to accept such a request, especially when such a
request is made soon after a previous dissolution. In those circumstances,
the Monarch would normally wish the parties to ascertain that
there was no potential government that could command the confidence
of the House of Commons before granting a dissolution.[18]
1.3.2 Extraordinary dissolutions in practice
There have only been three successful votes
of no confidence since the start of the 20th century. On the last
two occasions, the government announced the dissolution of Parliament
on the following day (October 1924 and March 1979). Following
the January 1924 defeat on the Queen's Speech, however, the Prime
Minister Stanley Baldwin resigned rather than dissolve Parliament.
Parliament need not be dissolved in the case of the resignation
or death of the Prime Minister, as made clear by practice and
the draft Cabinet Manual.[19]
However, the government may choose to call an election in such
a case.
2. THE COALITION
GOVERNMENT'S
PROPOSALS
2.1 The coalition government's proposal
"The date of the next general election
will be 7 May 2015. This is a hugely significant constitutional
innovation. It is simply not right that general elections can
be called according to a Prime Minister's whims, so this Prime
Minister will be the first Prime Minister to give up that right."
Nick Clegg MP in the House of Commons, 5 July 2010[20]
The 20 May 2010 Programme for Government set
out the government's initial commitment on fixed term parliaments:
We will establish five year fixed term Parliaments.
We will put a binding motion before the House of Commons stating
that the next general election will be held on the first Thursday
of May 2015. Following this motion, we will legislate to make
provision for fixed term Parliaments of five years. This legislation
will also provide for dissolution if 55% or more of the House
votes in favour.[21]
On 25 May 2010, the first adjournment debate
of the new Parliament considered dissolution of parliament and
fixed terms. There was considerable uncertainty about the proposals,
as well as some resistance from backbenchers and opposition MPs.
Much criticism focused on the 55 per cent threshold.
Much of the same ground was covered in the House
of Commons debate on the Address on 7 June 2010. Calls for active
discussion and pre-legislative scrutiny of any proposals for fixed
terms continued, as did confusion and distrust over the difference
between a no confidence motion and a dissolution motion.[22]
Similar concerns were raised in the House of Lords.[23]
Following criticism of the measures as originally
proposed, Nick Clegg announced on 5 July that the coalition government
had revised and clarified their proposals:
A majority of two thirds would be needed
to dissolve parliament, as opposed to the 55% first suggested
Votes of no confidence would still require
only a simple majority.[24]
On 22 July 2010 the government published its
Fixed Term Parliaments Bill, with the following provisions:
A fixed term of five years, with the
next election scheduled for 7 May 2015
The Prime Minister can move the election
date forward or back by up to two months, by Order subject to
affirmative resolution
Parliament can be dissolved early of
its own motion, or following a vote of no confidence
A motion to dissolve must be passed by
a two thirds majority, but a no confidence motion by a simple
majority
A no confidence motion will lead to dissolution
if no alternative government is formed within 14 days
Parliament cannot otherwise be dissolved.
The prerogative power of dissolution is abolished, but not the
power of prorogation
A mid term dissolution resets the clock,
so that the next election follows five years later
The Queen by proclamation appoints the
day for the first meeting of the new parliament
The committee stage of the bill will be taken on
the floor of the House of Commons, as a constitutional measure.[25]
Under the Coalition Agreement, the Bill will be whipped through
both Houses.[26]
2.2 Timetable for coalition government's bill
The Fixed Term Parliaments Bill was prepared
on an extraordinarily rushed timetable. It was introduced with
no prior consultation, no Green or White Paper. Nor has time been
allowed for pre-legislative scrutiny of a draft bill. The new
government felt that fixed term legislation was essential to ensure
the stability of the coalition. But the coalition will survive
if it is effective; not because it has legislated that the Parliament
must last for five years.
A rapid timetable was necessary for the legislation
to reduce the size of the House of Commons, because of the need
to start the wholesale boundary reviews which are required. But
the Fixed Term Parliaments Bill does not need to be rushed. The
Labour party also had a commitment to introduce fixed term parliaments.
The legislation could still be introduced with cross-party support,
if the government is willing to take it slowly. That is what the
government is seeking to do with reform of the House of Lords.
It should adopt the same approach with this bill.
3. ARGUMENTS
FOR AND
AGAINST FIXED
TERMS
3.1 Arguments in favour of fixed terms
3.1.1 Electoral fairness
The advantage an incumbent government has in
calling the election when it chooses has been famously compared
to an athlete arriving at the track already in running shoes and
being allowed to fire the starting pistol.[27]
Professor Blackburn describes this unfair advantage:
...[A] Prime Minister sets an election date at
the time when he thinks he is most likely to win it. Conversely,
he will avoid such times as he is likely to lose it. The anachronistic
state of the law on electoral timing adversely affects the fairness
of the election process as a whole. It gives the party in government
a tremendous tactical advantage over the opposition parties, and
of all the possible flaws to be found in our electoral law and
administration, this perhaps above all other matters does most
harm to the integrity of the electioneering contest.[28]
3.1.2 Reduction of Prime Ministerial power
The power to determine the date of the election
is a source of additional power for the Prime Minister over his
colleagues. It enables him to bring into line his ministers and
backbenchers. If they threaten to rebel he can in turn threaten
them with an early election. John Major as Prime Minister was
able to threaten the Maastricht rebels with an early election
if they did not fall into line. With fixed term parliaments a
Prime Minister could no longer threaten a snap election in this
way.
3.1.3 Better electoral administration
The Electoral Commission has long had an interest
in fixed term parliaments, which would enable electoral administrators
to be better prepared because the election date would be known
in advance. It has also argued for a longer general election timetable,
to bring it into line with the 25 day local election timetable.
There are three main problems: organising simultaneous elections
on different timetables; the heavy workload associated with postal
and proxy votes; and problems for voters in the short deadline
for registering to vote, and organising a postal vote.[29]
The Electoral Commission reported on the 2010
general election:
Returning Officers haveas in previous
electionsexpressed concerns about the statutory timetable
for UK general elections, and in particular the challenges of
key deadlines within the timetable...[30]
The report urges the government to use the fixed
term parliament legislation to address the issue of lengthening
the election timetable.
3.1.4 Better governmental planning
Fixed term parliaments create an expectation
that the parliament will run for the whole term, which could reduce
short termism. This is particularly important when there is a
minority or coalition government, or when the government's majority
is narrow. Fixed terms should give the government reasonable time
to develop and implement their legislative agenda or programme.
There should be no need for a wash up, because
with good planning all bills should have been passed. Ill timed
measures could be avoided, such as outlining a budget just before
an election, as happened in 1992. The increased certainty will
enable greater confidence in the government's ability to tackle
economic issues on a medium to long term basis.
3.1.5 Protection of the Crown
By minimising or regulating the discretionary
use of prerogative powers, constitutional crises as have occurred
in some Commonwealth countries could be avoided. The King-Byng
affair in Canada in 1926 and the Australian constitutional crisis
of 1975 demonstrate the difficulties for the Crown when faced
with requests for early dissolution.
3.2 Arguments against fixed terms
3.2.1 Loss of flexibility and reduced accountability
Fixing terms could prevent a general election
from taking place when it may otherwise be seen as appropriate.
For example, Anthony Eden's decision to call a premature election
in April 1955 can be justified on a mandate basis: he had only
taken over as PM nine days earlier after the resignation of Winston
Churchill. Fixed terms will remove or at least limit the government's
capacity for testing electoral opinion on a major public issue
where it might be in the country's interest to do so.
There is a risk that rigidity could lead to
"lame duck" governments, lacking the full confidence
of the House of Commons but not capable of being brought down.
This concern has been strongly expressed in New South Wales, where
a deeply unpopular government cannot be removed (see section 5.3).
3.2.2 Ineffective
Experience of fixed term parliaments in other
jurisdictions show that governments have been able to circumvent
the fixed term requirement and call elections according to their
convenience. The 2008 election in Canada is a recent example,
when the government ignored its fixed term legislation, passed
only the previous year (see section 5.2.1). In Germany, Chancellors
Helmut Kohl in 1982 and Gerhard Schrder in 2005 engineered to
lose a vote of confidence in order to dissolve parliament mid
term. These examples suggest that a government desperate to call
an election will find a way, regardless of the safeguards in place.
4. LENGTH OF
FIXED TERM
4.1 Four years or five
The coalition government proposes a five year
fixed term for Westminster, with the date for the next general
election set for 7 May 2015. This is long by comparison with most
other parliamentary systems. In the Westminster world, Australia
and New Zealand have three-year maximum terms. The legislatures
of Canada and many of its provinces have four year fixed terms,
as do most Australian states. The devolved legislatures in Scotland,
Wales and Northern Ireland all have four year fixed terms. Ireland's
lower house has a five year maximum, as in the UK.
In continental Europe most countries have four
year fixed terms, and only three (France, Italy, Luxembourg) have
five years. The length of parliamentary terms in other Westminster
parliaments and in Europe is shown in Figure 4.1.
Figure 4.1
FIXED TERMS IN EUROPE, AND OTHER WESTMINSTER
COUNTRIES
|
Country | Length of
Fixed term
| Maximum Term |
|
Austria | 4 |
|
Belgium | 4 |
|
Denmark | 4 |
|
Finland | 4 |
|
France | 5 |
|
Germany | 4 |
|
Greece | 4 |
|
Iceland | 4 |
|
Ireland | | 5
|
Italy | 5 |
|
Luxembourg | 5 |
|
Netherlands | 4 |
|
Norway | 4 |
|
Portugal | 4 |
|
Spain | 4 |
|
Sweden | 4 |
|
Switzerland | 4 |
|
Australia | | 3
|
Canada | 4 |
|
India | | 5
|
Ireland | | 5
|
New Zealand | | 3
|
South Africa | 5 |
|
Northern Ireland | 4 |
|
Scotland | 4 |
|
Wales | 4 |
|
|
| |
|
Five years is also long by comparison with Westminster's
recent experience. The average term since 1945 has been 3.7 years,
although discounting the three occasions on which parliaments
lasted less than two years, this rises to 4.3 years. This has
remained stable, with an average term length of 4.4 years since
October 1974. The length of each parliament since 1945 is set
out in Figure 4.2. Analysis of those parliaments which ran for
a full term records seven parliaments which lasted around four
years (1951, 1966, 1970, 1979, 1983, 1997, 2001); three which
lasted four and a half years (1945, 1955, 1974); and four parliaments
which ran for five (1959, 1987, 1992, 2005).
The balance between four and five years is more even than
folk memory might suggest. But those parliaments which lasted
for five years did so because the government had become unpopular
and did not want to hold an earlier election. The Prime Minister
stayed on hoping that his or her party's luck might change. It
did not, save for the case of John Major, who scraped through
with a narrow majority in 1992.
Figure 4.2
LENGTH OF POST WAR PARLIAMENTS AT WESTMINSTER
|
Year | Month |
Length
(years.months) |
|
1945 | July |
|
1950 | February | 4.7
|
1951 | October | 1.8
|
1955 | May | 3.7
|
1959 | October | 4.4
|
1964 | October | 5.0
|
1966 | March | 1.6
|
1970 | June | 4.3
|
1974 | February | 3.8
|
1974 | October | 0.7
|
1979 | May | 4.6
|
1983 | June | 4.1
|
1987 | June | 4.0
|
1992 | April | 4.9
|
1997 | May | 5.0
|
2001 | June | 4.1
|
2005 | May | 3.11
|
2010 | May | 5.0
|
|
| |
|
Politicians and academics who have addressed the issue support
parliaments running for four years rather than five. During the
debates on the Parliament Act 1911, which reduced the maximum
term from seven to five years, Prime Minister Asquith said:
In the first place we propose to shorten the legal duration
of Parliament from seven years to five years, which will probably
amount in practice to an actual legislative working term of four
years. That will secure that your House of Commons for the time
being, is always either fresh from the polls which gave it authority,
orand this is an equally effective check upon acting in
defiance of the popular willit is looking forward to the
polls at which it will have to render an account of its stewardship.[31]
Professor Blackburn has also argued for a four year term:
In the UK, there can be little doubt that the period between
general elections should be four years. The proposal for fixed
term Parliament as a whole should fit as closely as possible into
existing constitutional expectations, and the idea that four years
is about the right length of time between elections is very prevalent.
It was the period expressly approved of as being normal in practice,
when the Parliament Act set the period of five years as a maximum.
In an ideal democracy it may be that there should be elections
as frequently as possibleeven annually as supported by
the Chartists in the eighteenth centurybut a government
must be allowed a sufficient period of time in which to put its
programme of public policies into effect before submitting its
record of achievement, or otherwise, to the voters. Three full
legislative sessions, and certainly four, is sufficient for this
purpose.[32]
Recent reform proposals by the political parties have all
supported a four year term. This can be found in the Labour party's
1992 report Meet the Challenge, Make the Change; in the
1993 report of the Labour party's Plant Commission; in the 1992
and 1997 Liberal Democrat manifestos; and in the Liberal Democrat
policy papers Real Democracy for Britain (2006), and For
the People, By the People (2007). The three Private Member's
Bills introduced in the last ten years, by the Labour MPs Jeff
Rooker and Tony Wright, and the Lib Dem David Howarth MP all supported
four year terms (see chapter 6). Indeed, none of the proponents
of fixed term parliaments have advocated a term of five years.
4.2 Fitting around other electoral cycles
Thought also needs to be given to how Westminster's fixed
terms will fit with the electoral cycles for the devolved assemblies,
the European Parliament and elections to the second chamber. The
table below sets out the electoral cycle for future elections
to the European Parliament and the devolved assemblies, with separate
columns for a four and a five year cycle for the House of Commons.
Dates in italics indicate a combination of a UK general election
and European Parliamentary election on the same date; dates in
bold indicate a clash between a general election and devolved
assembly elections.
Figure 4.3
ELECTORAL CYCLE FOR UK GENERAL ELECTIONS AND OTHER ELECTIONS
| | |
|
European elections | Devolved elections
| UK elections 4 yrs | UK elections 5 yrs
|
| | |
|
2014 | 2015
| 2014 | 2015
|
2019 | 2019 | 2018
| 2020 |
2024 | 2023 | 2022
| 2025 |
2029 | 2027 | 2026
| 2030 |
2034 | 2031 |
2030 | 2035 |
2039 | 2035 | 2034
| 2040 |
| | |
|
| |
| |
Second chamber elections are likely to be for one third of
the House each time. They could be held at the same time as elections
to the Commons; or if they were to be staggered between general
elections, they could be held at the same time as European Parliament
elections (five year intervals, 15 year terms), or devolved assembly
elections (four year intervals, 12 year terms).
If the government wished to avoid any clash between UK general
and other elections, the simplest solution might be to move the
date of general elections to October, and provide for the next
UK general election to be held in October 2014. That would allow
the Conservative-Lib Dem coalition a term of four and a half years,
but provide for four year terms thereafter. To enable the electoral
register to be as up to date as possible, the annual canvass forms
would need to be sent out in the spring or the summer, instead
of in the autumn as at present.
4.3 Time of year, and day of the week
Although in the last 30 years general elections have been
held in April, May or June, four post war elections have been
held in October: in 1951, 1959, 1964 and 1974 (see Figure 4.2).
Elections have traditionally been held on Thursdays, but in 2007
the Electoral Commission issued a consultation paper on moving
general, and potentially local, elections to weekends. The findings
of the public consultation show that 53 per cent of those who
participated favoured retaining polling on a weekday.[33]
This lack of consensus combined with thin evidence that weekend
voting would increase voter participation led to the conclusion
that "the government do not propose to move forward with
weekend voting at this time."[34]
Further, the estimated costs of changing to voting across Saturday
and Sunday was £105 million.[35]
5. COMPARATIVE EXPERIENCE
FROM OTHER
COUNTRIES
Fixed term parliaments are reasonably common in other countries,
with one 2005 study categorising three quarters of the 41 democracies
analysed as having fixed terms.[36]
But within that universe there is a wide variation of practice,
ranging from completely fixed terms with no provision for early
dissolution, to more flexible systems which allow the legislature
to be dissolved before the scheduled date. This range is illustrated
in Figure 5.1 (at the end of this report).
Almost all parliaments with fixed terms have a safety valve of
some kind to allow premature dissolution, though Norway is a notable
exception. There is also variation in the term length, the timing
of elections after a premature dissolution, and the mechanism
for varying the election day.
5.1 Devolved institutions of the UK
The devolved legislatures of Scotland, Wales and Northern
Ireland all have fixed terms with provisions for extraordinary
dissolution. Their elections are scheduled for the first Thursday
in May every four years.[37]
The date may be varied by up to one month either way by the Monarch
on the proposal of the Presiding Officer.
They can be dissolved prematurely if the legislature so resolves
(with at least two-thirds of members voting in favour), or if
the legislature fails to nominate a First Minister within 28 days
of an election. There are thus two routes to dissolution. Either
the parliament resolves to dissolve itself by a two thirds majority,
or a dissolution may result if a government is defeated on a confidence
motion (on a simple majority), if no First Minister is nominated
to replace the defeated government.
A new parliament elected mid term serves only for the remainder
of that term. But if an extraordinary election is held in the
six months before the date of the next scheduled election, that
election is vacated: so that the next term runs for slightly longer
than four years.
5.2 Canada
5.2.1 At the federal level: the Canadian House of Commons
Canada introduced fixed parliamentary terms at the federal
level in 2006, under Bill C-16 (An Act to Amend the Canada
Elections Act). This set elections for the third Monday in
October of the fourth calendar year after the previous poll, starting
with 19 October 2009.[38]
However, the Bill provided that the prerogative power of the Governor
General to dissolve parliament was not affected.[39]
The reason for this was that altering the powers of the Crown
would have required a constitutional amendment, which in Canada
is a difficult procedure involving all the provinces.
The Bill became law in May 2007, adding the following section
to the Canada Elections Act 2000[40]:
Powers of Governor
General preserved |
56.1 (1) Nothing in this section affects the powers of the Governor General, including the power to dissolve Parliament at the Governor General's discretion.
|
Election dates | (2) Subject to subsection (1), each general election must be held on the third Monday of October in the fourth calendar year following polling day for the last general election, with the first general election after this section comes into force being held on Monday, October 19, 2009.
|
| |
A governmental press release on the day the Bill was introduced
stated that the fixed election dates were intended to improve
fairness and improve transparency and predictability, and that
the practice concerning confidence would remain unchanged.[41]
This statement was echoed during the Bill's passage through Parliament.[42]
This Bill followed several Private Members' Bills tabled since
1970 proposing fixed term parliaments, including one in April
2004 by then Leader of the Opposition Stephen Harper.[43]
However, the change in the law has not made much difference
in practice. In September 2008, Stephen Harper requested a dissolution
from Governor General Michaëlle Jean a year early. Harper
argued that Parliament was becoming increasingly dysfunctional,
and that in light of the economic crisis he needed a renewed mandate.
The Governor General granted the request, relying on her prerogative
powers as preserved by the Bill to do so. Harper headed a minority
government which was struggling to get its legislation passed.
His request came after repeated confidence votes proposed by the
government, challenging the opposition parties to defeat it and
trigger an election. The Liberals repeatedly spoke against government
bills but then abstained to avoid an election. When Harper said
that virtually every government bill would be a confidence vote,
the Liberals abstained from voting even more. The dissolution
allowed Harper to take advantage of a rise in his party's poll
numbers, so that his party increased their number of seats at
the ensuing general election, but still failed to gain a majority.
This episode shows that simply fixing election dates through
legislation is not enough if the prerogative power of dissolution
remains unaffected. But if the prerogative power of dissolution
is retained as a safety valve, it needs to be protected from manipulation.
The Governor General was put on the spot by Harper's request for
an early dissolution, and the Crown drawn into political controversy.
5.2.2 Canadian provincial legislatures
British Columbia was the first Canadian province to introduce
fixed parliamentary terms, which it did in 2001. The Constitution
(Fixed Election Dates) Amendment Act 2001 amended the Constitution
Act 1996 to put in place four year parliamentary terms by
setting the date for the next election and subsequent elections
on the second Tuesday in May every fourth year after that.[44]
The Act explicitly retains the prerogative powers of the Lieutenant
Governor to prorogue or dissolve parliament at his or her discretion.[45]
The Act was not intended to alter the practice concerning confidence.
The election schedule has so far been followed, with elections
taking place as planned in 2005 and 2009.
Ontario followed suit and passed the Election Statute
Law Amendment Act 2005, amending the Election Act 1990
to require elections to be held on the first Thursday in October
every four years, from 2007.[46]
Again, the prerogative powers of the Lieutenant Governor, including
to dissolve parliament as he or she sees fit, are retained.[47]
The legislation allows for the day of the election to be moved
to any of the seven following days on the recommendation of the
Chief Electoral Officer to the Lieutenant Governor in the case
of a clash with a religiously or culturally significant day.[48]
This mechanism was used to move the election by six days in 2007
to avoid a Jewish holiday.
Most other Canadian provincial legislatures have followed
suit and adopted similar mechanisms to implement fixed four year
parliamentary terms, including Manitoba,[49]
New Brunswick,[50] Newfoundland
and Labrador,[51] the
Northwest Territories,[52]
Prince Edward Island[53]
and Saskatchewan.[54]
This means that a total of eight out of the thirteen provinces
and territories have implemented fixed terms, with moves to introduce
fixed terms for the remaining legislative assemblies.
5.3 Australia
Australia does not have fixed terms at the federal level,
imposing only a three year maximum. However, most of the legislatures
of the Australian states have fixed terms of four years with provision
for extraordinary dissolutions. For example, election dates have
been fixed in Victoria since 2003[55].
Mid term elections can still be called if the government should
lose a confidence vote with no reversal within eight days,[56]
or if the Premier should request a dissolution in case of a failed
dispute resolution procedure following a deadlocked bill between
the upper and lower houses.[57]
The Australian Capital Territory, New South Wales, the Northern
Territory, South Australia and Tasmania also have flexible four
year fixed terms along similar lines, with mid term dissolution
only allowed to resolve a serious deadlock or in the case of a
loss of confidence. Some states have restricted dissolution so
that parliament may only be dissolved in the final year of the
four year term.
In New South Wales fixed term parliaments have been called
into question since the election of the current Labor government,
which quickly became deeply unpopular. Pinning the problem on
the fixed term is more psychological than rational. The NSW Labor
government would be hanging on even with flexible terms, because
if they called an early election they would lose. However, under
flexible terms there was always the possibility that the
election would be earlier. The perceived problem with a fixed
term is that the election date is far away. So the angry public
have started demanding more radical action to force an election.
The Governor has received petitions asking her to dismiss the
government. The Leader of the Opposition is demanding a right
of recall. What is really being sought is not so much a right
of individual recall, but a right for voters to petition for an
early election.
5.4 South Africa
South Africa's lower house, the National Assembly, has semi-fixed
parliamentary terms of five years.[58]
The South African model for early dissolution provides a useful
example of some imposed stability. Although it could be argued
that it is over-flexible and prone to majority party manipulation,
all parliaments since 1994 have lasted for five years. Section
50 of the Constitution of 1996 provides:
50. Dissolution of National Assembly before expiry of its
term
(1) The President must dissolve the National Assembly if:
(a)the Assembly has adopted a resolution to dissolve with
a supporting vote of a majority of its members; and
(b)three years have passed since the Assembly was elected.
(2) The Acting President must dissolve the National Assembly
if:
(a)there is a vacancy in the office of President; and
(b)the Assembly fails to elect a new President within 30 days
after the vacancy occurred.
5.5 Europe
Many parliaments in European countries have fixed terms,
flexible to a greater or lesser extent and with differing safety
valves for extraordinary dissolution. Most have four year terms,
though a few have five year terms. However, some of those with
five year terms, such as France and Italy, tend to have more flexible
election dates in practice.
Norway is notable as the only parliamentary system with fixed
term parliaments that has no safety valve. There have been numerous
debates about reconsidering this, with provision for early dissolution
being suggested several times, but they have never managed to
obtain the necessary two thirds majority in parliament that is
required for a constitutional amendment.
Some European systems demonstrate the importance of practice
even in cases where the term is theoretically fixed. In Belgium
in recent years, the parliament has repeatedly been dissolved
by relying on a declaration to amend the Constitution, which results
in the dissolution of both chambers; the mechanism for institutional
reform has been used instead of the mechanism to resolve political
crises.
In Germany, confidence votes have been manipulated by the
government to engineer an early dissolution, as happened in 1982
and 2005.[59] However,
on both occasions all the main parties were in favour of an early
election. In 2005 in particular, the Chancellor was faced with
serious difficulties including intra-party splits and numerous
election losses at the regional level.[60]
The early dissolution can be justified by the government's need
for support for its reform policies.
In France, the President has the power to dissolve parliament
upon consultation with the Prime Minister and the Presidents of
the two houses.[61] This
power was originally intended either as a way of resolving a serious
crisis by testing the opinion of the people, or as a way of deciding
a disagreement with the lower house, but dissolution has only
been used twice for such reasons (1962 and 1968). On other occasions
it has been used by the President to increase his support in parliament.
In 1981 and 1988 dissolution was declared by the President at
the beginning of his term so that he would have a majority in
the lower house to support his policies, and in 1997 to bring
forward an election to a time considered more advantageous. As
a result, the French parliamentary terms appear to be only nominally
fixed.
In Italy, there is theoretically a semi fixed term of five
years, but in practice this seldom holds; the Italian legislature
has been dissolved early eight times in the last 40 years. This
is done by the President, upon consultation with the Speakers
of both houses, but without formal involvement of the Prime Minister.
The example of Italy shows how flexible and uncertain a supposedly
fixed term can be.
Fig 5.1
CONTINUUM OF FIXED TERM EXPERIENCE
Completely Fixed | Semi-Fixed
| Nominally Fixed | Completely Flexible
|
Norway | Germany |
Canada | UK |
| Sweden | France
| Australia |
| South Africa | Italy
| New Zealand
Ireland |
| |
| |
Completely Fixed: No provision for calling an election
before the scheduled date Semi-fixed: Mechanisms in place to allow
for dissolution before the scheduled election date Nominally Fixed:
Safety valves being used in practice to undermine fixed term Completely
Flexible: Length of term decided at the discretion of the executive
6. RECENT REFORM
PROPOSALS AT
WESTMINSTER
Fixed term parliaments have been the subject of reform proposals
since at least 1991. Three private members' bills have been introduced,
in 1994, 2001 and 2007; and Labour and the Liberal Democrats have
supported fixed term parliaments. This chapter will discuss these
and other proposals, as well as the plans set out by the coalition
government in 2010.
6.1 Reform proposals in the 1990s
Fixed term parliaments have frequented opposition party discourse.
It was a prominent pledge for Labour in 1992 in the wake of the
uncertainty on the timing of that election, and fixed term parliaments
also featured in the Liberal Democrat manifestos for 1992 and
1997.
In September 1991 the Institute for Public Policy Research
issued The Constitution of the United Kingdom, recommending
the adoption of four year parliaments. On 10 March 1992, Tony
Banks MP presented a Bill to make statutory provision for fixed
term parliaments. The following day, Lord Jenkins of Hillhead
also proposed fixed terms. He said:
To give the pistol in a race to one of the competitors and
encourage him to fire it whenever he thinks that the others are
least readywhen they are tying up their shoelaces or something
of that kindis not in accordance with the best athletic
practice.
...On the whole I believe that a fixed four year term would
certainly be more rational, somewhat fairer and maybe militate
against both the economic uncertainty and the awful cacophony
which has been the too long-drawn-out overture to this election.[62]
In 1993 the Labour Party commissioned The Report of the
Working Party on Electoral Systems led by Professor Raymond
Plant. Section 2 of the Report on voter participation made 37
recommendations to improve voter participation in elections, including
the introduction of fixed four year parliamentary terms.[63]
The relevant recommendation reads:
The current system, which allows the Prime Minister to call
an election at the most advantageous time to the party in office,
gives the government of the day too much power.[64]
Labour MP Jeff Rooker's Parliamentary Elections (No. 2)
Bill received its first reading on the 20 May 1994. This sought
to implement all 37 of the Plant Report's recommendations on voter
participation of the year before.[65]
Clauses 1 and 2 stipulated that:
The Septennial Act 1715 would be repealed.
The Secretary of State would by regulations specify
the regular weekend dates every fourth year upon which general
elections would be held.
Parliament would automatically be dissolved 28 days
before the election date.
Notwithstanding ordinary dissolutions, if the government
were subject to a vote of no confidence in the House of Commons
then Her Majesty should dissolve parliament by proclamation.
A parliament meeting following an extraordinary general
election should be dissolved on the same date under such calculations
as would the previous parliament.
The Labour government in 1998 introduced fixed terms for the Scottish
Parliament,[66] the Northern
Ireland Assembly[67]
and the Welsh Assembly,[68]
each of four years.
6.2 Reform proposals in the 2000s
In the early 2000s, interest in fixed term parliaments continued,
but in a low key way.
In its report Election 2001: The Official Results, the
Electoral Commission commented:
Because of the administrative benefits of fixed term Parliaments,
and the anomalous position of Westminster elections in comparison
with all other elections held in the UK the Commission plans to
look further at the case for adopting fixed term Parliamentary
terms for Westminster.[69]
The intention to examine fixed term parliaments at length
was reiterated in the Electoral Commission's report on election
timetables in June 2003;[70]
but no such report has been produced.
A Ten Minute Rule Bill on fixed term parliaments was introduced
by Labour MP Dr. Tony Wright on 1 March 2001. Wright's key proposals
were as follows:
To introduce four year terms.
For parliament to consider itself automatically dissolved
28 days before the fourth anniversary of the previous general
election.
Whenever the House of Commons expresses no confidence
in the government, parliament should be dissolved on the seventh
day following that resolution.
Whenever the House of Commons expresses no confidence
in a Prime Minister and fails to express confidence in the same
or another minister in 28 days, parliament should stand dissolved.
Should such extraordinary dissolutions occur more
than six months before the previous term was due to expire, the
poll date would remain unchanged despite any change of government.
Should such extraordinary dissolutions occur less
than six months before the term was due to expire, then the next
election would occur on the fourth anniversary of that expiry
date.
The Electoral Commission should decide on the dates
for issue of the writs, polling and the meeting of the new parliaments
but allowing:
Three to five weeks between dissolution and election.
Parliament to reconvene between one and two weeks
following the election.
Interest in fixing parliamentary terms began to pick up in
the second half of the 2000s. David Cameron reportedly began to
consider the idea of fixed term parliaments from 2006.[71]
However, this was tempered by his calls that a general election
should be required if there was a new PM, in the light of Gordon
Brown taking over as Prime Minister.[72]
The Liberal Democrats revived their interest in fixed term
parliaments, for example in their papers Real Democracy for
Britain (2006) and For the People, by the People (2007).
The Liberal Democrat MP David Howarth's Fixed Term Parliaments
Bill 2007-8 had its second reading on 16 May 2008. It provided
for four year fixed parliamentary terms, with elections to be
held on the first Thursday in May. Dissolution was to take place
30 days before the scheduled election. Dissolution could only
take place on those dates, with no provision for a safety valve.
David Howarth argued that the main problems with the current
arrangement were: (1) the unfair advantage to the incumbent party
in choosing the election date; (2) the interference with good
government; (3) adding to the government's power over their back
benchers; and (4) the "macho style of politics" and
"game of political chicken" with parties trying to show
they did not fear a general election.[73]
He also pointed out that fixed terms were widespread in many other
elected bodies in the UK and abroad.[74]
In the 2010 election manifestos, both the Liberal Democrats
and Labour had pledges to introduce fixed term parliaments. The
Conservatives did not, but had a more general pledge "to
make the Royal Prerogative subject to greater democratic control
so that Parliament is directly involved".
7. MID TERM
DISSOLUTION
7.1 Restrictions on mid term dissolution
There must be a mechanism to deal with the situation where
the government has lost the confidence of the House of Commons
and no alternative government can be found. Having to engineer
a declaration of no confidence in order to agree to a dissolution
everyone wants would simply bring the system into disrepute. We
are proposing that there should be a period of up to 14 days in
which the search for an alternative government can take place.
If no such government can be formed, then dissolution will follow.
This will deal with the theoretical possibility of a limbo in
which the Government could not command the confidence of the House,
but the House refused to dissolve Parliament.
Memorandum from the Deputy Prime Minister to the House of Lords
Constitution Committee, July 2010.
Mid term dissolutions are the most crucial aspect of any
fixed term parliament law. The government must always command
the confidence of the House of Commons; and a government which
has lost that confidence must be allowed to fall. But governments
must not be allowed to fall too easily, or we might experience
the volatility of parliaments in Italy, or the Fourth Republic
in France; nor can they be too protected, or they will lose their
accountability to parliament and the public.
Lord Fraser of Carmyllie said of early dissolution of fixed
term parliaments in the House of Lords in 1999:
If there is to be a fixed period, the only real issue is the
circumstances in which earlier dissolution is permissible. If
the circumstances allowing for that are too restrictively stated,
it is not difficult to envisage a wide variety of occasions when
it could not be for the good of the country to require a Parliament
and government to continue without seeking a fresh mandate from
the electorate. If conditions for early dissolution are too loosely
framed, the change proposed would in effect be purely cosmetic.[75]
Key considerations are how and by whom dissolution may be
initiated, what threshold must be reached, and any limitations
on the process. The government initially proposed a 55% threshold
for dissolution, but that proposal was widely misunderstood to
apply to no confidence motions as well. Nick Clegg set the record
straight, and raised the bar for government initiated dissolutions
in a debate in early July:
First, traditional powers of no confidence will be put into
law, and a vote of no confidence will still require only a simple
majority. Secondly, if after a vote of no confidence a government
cannot be formed within 14 days, Parliament will be dissolved
and a general election will be held. Let me be clear: these steps
will strengthen Parliament's power over the executive. Thirdly,
there will be an additional power for Parliament to vote for an
early and immediate dissolution. We have decided that a majority
of two thirds will be needed to carry the vote, as opposed to
the 55% first suggested, as is the case in the Scottish Parliament.
These changes will make it impossible for any government to force
a dissolution for their own purposes.[76]
7.2 Thresholds
Clause 2 of the government's Fixed Term Parliaments Bill
envisages two routes to dissolution:
"a motion that there should be an early parliamentary
general election"; or
"a motion that there should be no confidence
in Her Majesty's Government".
A motion for dissolution would require a two-thirds majority
of all MPs (not just all MPs voting); while a no confidence motion
could be passed by simple majority.
No confidence could still lead to dissolution, but only if
an alternative government cannot be formed. The justification
for a higher threshold for government-initiated dissolution is
twofold. First, it is aimed mainly at majority governments. It
should make it impossible for them to call an early election without
significant cross-party support. Second, immediate dissolution
is a more drastic change. A no confidence motion seeks a change
of driver; a dissolution motion seeks a change of car.
But such a dual threshold is rare in other parliaments. Figure
7.1 sets out the threshold requirements for confidence motions
elsewhere in Europe. In all cases the threshold for a no confidence
motion is a simple or absolute majority (an absolute majority
being of the total number of MPs, rather than of those voting).
In those cases where dissolution can be triggered by a parliamentary
vote, the threshold is the same.[77]
Figure 7.1
THRESHOLDS FOR CONFIDENCE AND NO CONFIDENCE MOTIONS
Country | No Confidence Threshold (Initiative rests with Parliament)
| Confidence Threshold (Initiative
rests with Cabinet)
|
Austria | simple majority
| |
Belgium | absolute majority (constructive)
| absolute majority |
Denmark | simple majority |
|
Finland | simple majority |
|
France | absolute majority |
simple majority |
Germany | absolute majority (constructive)
| absolute majority |
Greece | absolute majority |
simple majority |
Iceland | absolute majority
| |
Ireland | simple majority |
|
Italy | simple majority |
simple majority |
Luxembourg | simple majority
| |
Netherlands | simple majority
| |
Norway | simple majority |
|
Portugal | absolute majority
| simple majority |
Spain | absolute majority (constructive)
| simple majority |
Sweden | absolute majority |
|
| |
|
The precedent the government points to for a dual threshold
is the devolution legislation of 1998, which also requires a two
thirds parliamentary vote for dissolution. Those provisions so
far remain untested, and it is not known how they would operate
under fire. But it is instructive to read the parliamentary debates
on the Scotland Bill, where an amendment was moved to replace
the two thirds requirement with a simple majority. The Lords were
reminded that high thresholds had been circumvented in other countries.
In reply Lord Sewel recognised that risk, but nevertheless felt
it was justifiable to raise the bar:
I accept that one cannot guarantee in all circumstances that
the way in which something is intended to happen will in reality
happen. We can try to make it that little bit more difficult.
That is what these provisions seek to do.[78]
There are other possibilities which could be considered to
restrict the use of dissolution motions:
A minimum number of MPs to be signatories of the motion.
In the parliaments of Sweden, Spain and Italy such a motion must
be signed by 10 per cent of the members.
A requirement that the motion be signed by the Prime
Minister and Leader of the Opposition, or the leaders of the three
largest parties, in order to ensure that the motion has cross-party
support.
There are also other ways of restricting the use of no confidence
motions:
Requiring an absolute, not a simple majority
Requiring a "constructive" vote of no confidence,
as in Germany and Spain.
A constructive no confidence motion is one which nominates
an alternative government, rather than merely seeking to remove
the present government. An alternative to a constructive vote
of no confidence would be to require an investiture vote for any
new government formed after a successful no confidence motion.
The government's bill comes close to this in cl 2(2)(b) ("any
motion expressing confidence in any Government of Her Majesty").
It could specifically require the House to nominate a Prime Minister,
as the Scottish Parliament is required to nominate a First Minister
under section 46 of the Scotland Act.
7.3 Confidence motions
The legislation will give legal effect to a vote of no confidence,
but will not seek to define a vote of no confidence on the face
of the bill. In practice there is little doubt about what constitutes
a motion of no confidence in a government, and there is no need
to limit the flexibility of Parliament unnecessarily.
Memorandum from the Deputy Prime Minister to the House of Lords
Constitution Committee, July 2010.
Not all confidence motions take the classic form, "This
House has no confidence in Her Majesty's Government". In
Canada this has recently given rise to confusion and controversy
as to whether a particular motion is one of confidence or not.[79]
Although motions in the House of Commons at Westminster have been
equally varied, there has been little doubt when an issue has
been one of confidence.
In particular, any issue which is made one of confidence
by the government becomes a motion of confidence in the government.
Motions of confidence in specific policies ("this House has
no confidence in HM Government's management of the economy"
19 Nov 1973) are confidence motions. But in addition governments
have treated as issues of confidence motions about:
specific bills: "That the [European Communities]
Bill be now read a second time" 15 Feb 1972
specific issues: "That item A be reduced by £100,
in respect of the salary of the Secretary of State" 21 June
1895
or "a Select Committee be appointed to investigate...
withdrawal of the proceedings instituted by the DPP against Mr
Campbell" 8 Oct 1924
and even purely procedural motions, eg "That
this House do now adjourn" 11 March 1976.
In such debates the main speakers are generally the Leader
of the Opposition and the Prime Minister; and all MPs know the
government's future is at stake.[80]
The government's bill provides that
2(2) An early parliamentary election is also to take place
if the Speaker of the House of Commons issues a certificate certifying
that:
(a)on a specified day the House passed a motion of no confidence
in Her Majesty's Government...
At first blush this appears to contemplate only formal confidence
motions in the classic form. But the Bill goes on to provide that
the Speaker's certificate is conclusive for all purposes. So the
Speaker would have discretion to certify any of the motions listed
above as confidence motions. If the government or the opposition
have declared an issue to be one of confidence, the Speaker is
likely to indicate at the beginning of the debate that the motion
is a confidence motion, so that all MPs know what is at stake.
The Speaker's certificate is taken from the procedure under
the Parliament Acts. It provides an impartial arbiter, and avoids
the need for the Prime Minister or the Crown to get involved in
deciding whether the House should be dissolved. The certificate
also minimises the risk of the courts being asked to rule on whether
a no confidence motion has been properly passed, or a new government
properly formed. The Speaker's certificate is final, and conclusive
for all purposes.
If a no confidence motion is passed, the government remains
in office until a new government can be formed in which the House
has confidence. It cannot immediately resign, because there must
always be a government. But once it has lost confidence the government
should be subject to the caretaker convention, which means it
has authority only to transact essential business, and not to
make new policy or major appointments or new contracts. The caretaker
convention is explained in the new draft Cabinet Manual, but it
has not yet been extended to mid term resignations or dissolutions.[81]
It needs to be.
7.4 Time limits and cooling off periods
A motion of confidence or dissolution should take precedence
over other motions. But a period of reflection may be helpful
to allow the motion to be properly considered, debated and voted
upon. The German Basic Law states that 48 hours must elapse between
a motion of confidence and the vote (Articles 67(2) and 68(2)).
The Spanish Constitution of 1978 requires five days (Section 113(3)).
The Australian state of Victoria requires three clear days' notice
(Constitution Act 1975, s.8A(2)).
Erskine May states that
In allotting a day for this purpose the government is entitled
to have regard to the exigencies of its own business, but a reasonably
early day is invariably found... the government has everything
to gain by meeting such a direct challenge to its authority at
the earliest possible moment.[82]
The latter argument may be unduly sanguine. In Canada in
December 2008 when the government were facing a no confidence
motion which they were widely expected to lose, the Prime Minister
chose instead to invite the Governor General to prorogue Parliament
(see section 8.3). If the UK wanted to guard against this we could
consider time limits; and provide in the Cabinet Manual that parliament
cannot be prorogued while a confidence motion is pending.
Time limits also apply after a confidence motion. The most
important are the time limits on the period in which a new government
can be formed, failing which parliament will be dissolved and
fresh elections held. In Belgium a new Prime Minister must be
nominated within three days of a successful no confidence motion,
or parliament stands dissolved. In New South Wales eight days
must pass before parliament may be dissolved (Constitution Act
1902, s 24B(2)(b)). In Germany the period is 21 days, and in Scotland
28 days. Many Westminster countries do not have automatic dissolution
after a set period, including Australia, Canada, Ireland and New
Zealand.
The government's bill proposes 14 days for Westminster, which
seems a sufficient period in which the parties can try to form
an alternative government, and test whether it has confidence.
Given the two thirds threshold for a dissolution motion, it is
important to have a trigger for automatic dissolution. Otherwise
there is a risk of limbo, as there might be a simple majority
to vote out the government, but not a sufficient majority to dissolve.
If a no confidence motion is unsuccessful, some systems also
use time limits to restrict further confidence motions until the
time has elapsed. So in Spain, the movers of an unsuccessful no
confidence motion cannot move another until a new session of parliament.
7.5 Time limits on dissolving near beginning or end of
parliamentary term
It is quite common to limit or prohibit dissolution towards
the beginning or the end of a parliamentary term. The French Constitution
prohibits dissolution in the twelve months following a general
election,[83] as does
the Spanish Constitution.[84]
Other legislatures only allow dissolution in the final year of
their four year term, while the South African lower house cannot
move to dissolve itself in the first three years of its five year
term.[85] At such times,
there can of course still be the possibility of confidence motions.
7.6 Flexibility to advance or postpone election
The bill provides that the Prime Minister may by statutory
instrument provide that the polling day is moved forward or backward
by not more than two months. This is to provide for emergencies
like the foot and mouth crisis in 2001, which led to the local
government elections scheduled for May being postponed until June.
Similar provisions are found in most other countries. The statutory
instrument would be subject to affirmative resolution in both
Houses.
7.7 Remainder of the parliamentary term
An important consideration is whether a parliament elected
mid term merely serves out the remainder of that term, or whether
dissolution restarts the clock and it serves a full new term.
The former is a strong disincentive to a government inclined to
call an early election. In Scotland only the remainder of the
term is served, unless the dissolution takes place within six
months of the next scheduled election. (In that event, the next
scheduled election is not held; but the one after that is, to
get back on schedule).
An alternative solution to prevent elections taking place
too close to each other is a ban on dissolutions in the run-up
to elections. Sweden and Finland are two such examples, where
no premature election may take place within 75 days of the next
scheduled election. As in Scotland, scheduled elections take place
every four years, even if during the previous four years a premature
election has taken place.
Countries where mid term dissolution restarts the clock and
the new parliament serves a full term are the Canadian provinces
of British Columbia and Ontario, Belgium, the Netherlands and
Hungary. This is the arrangement proposed in the government's
bill, which provides that a mid term dissolution initiates a new
five year term. The next scheduled election will then take place
five years from the previous May. But if the mid term election
is held before May, the next general election will be held four
years later. So if there is a mid term dissolution in October
2011, the next general election would be in May 2016; but if the
mid term election is in March 2011, the next election would be
in May 2015.
Which model to choose depends on how strong the disincentives
should be against mid term dissolutions. These tend to be conceived
primarily from the government's viewpoint. The lack of such a
disincentive in Canada may have contributed to Stephen Harper's
decision to call an early election following the rise in his party's
poll ratings in fall 2008. He stood to gain a further four years
in office, rather than the one year he still had to serve. But
it may also serve as a disincentive to opposition parties tempted
to force a mid term dissolution, if the only prize is the remainder
of the term. This need not prevent opposition parties putting
down confidence motions leading to a change of government; but
it might give them greater pause before seeking a mid term dissolution.
7.8 Political incentives and disincentives
This chapter began by explaining the need to balance government
stability against democratic accountability. The rules for mid
term dissolution can be seen as a set of incentives and disincentives
to regulate the behaviour of the parties in parliament. Running
through the chapter are a whole set of possible incentives to
buttress stable government, and disincentives to making it easy
to obtain a mid term dissolution:
Procedural restrictions on dissolution or confidence motions
Motion to be signed by minimum number of MPs
Motion to be signed by named office holders
Constructive no confidence motions
High thresholds for the vote
Absolute not simple majority for no confidence
Two thirds majority for dissolution
Time limits
Before debating a no confidence motion
Before a further no confidence motion can be tabled
After a no confidence motion, in which an alternative
government must be formed
No dissolution near the beginning or end of a parliament.
Subsequent parliamentary term
New parliament serves only the remainder of the previous
term.
But the rules need not necessarily be too elaborate, or too
restrictive. Any moves towards a mid term dissolution will be
played out in an intensely political context, in which the political
incentives are as important in guiding behaviour as the legal
rules. The political context is not always that of a government
seeking to increase its majority. Although that is the most common
reason, it accounts for only about one third of early dissolutions
in countries we have surveyed: see Figure 7.2. Other reasons recorded
in Figure 7.2 for early dissolution are a constitutional or political
crisis, major policy change, loss of a confidence motion, resignation
of the Prime Minister, the collapse of a coalition or a government
split.
The main question for the parties in any mid term crisis
will not be whether dissolution is too easy or too difficult,
but whether they stand to gain or lose by forcing a dissolution.
And much of the time, the political incentives in themselves may
prove a further force for stability. Political parties do not
like excessively frequent elections: they are expensive for the
parties, who are chronically short of money, and exhausting for
the participants. And whatever the polls may say, the outcome
is always slightly uncertain. In particular, a party which forces
an unnecessary election risks being punished by the electorate,
who also dislike frequent elections.
The political incentives can be seen at work in Scotland
and in Canada, where the opposition parties have been harassing
a minority government, but have not had the courage to combine
to force an election for fear of the electoral consequences. In
Scotland the opposition parties voted down the SNP budget in March
2009; but when Alex Salmond threatened to resign to force an early
election, they backed off and voted the budget through. In Canada
Stephen Harper's minority government would have welcomed an early
election in 2007-08, but whenever they came close to a substantive
confidence motion the opposition parties abstained. They did not
want to be held responsible for forcing the third election in
four years, nor to face the electorate when their poll ratings
were low.
What Canada shows is that a minority government cannot force
a mid term dissolution through losing a confidence motion if the
opposition parties will not play along. The same is not necessarily
true of a majority government. In Germany the Chancellor has twice
engineered a vote of no confidence in order to force an early
election. The first occasion was in 1982, when the SDP/FDP coalition
split, and the FDP joined a new coalition led by the CDU leader
Helmut Kohl.[86] To force
an election in which he hoped to obtain a stronger majority, Kohl
tabled a confidence motion in which the governing parties then
abstained. In 2005 the Chancellor Gerhard Schrder followed a similar
tactic, following his party's dramatic defeats at the regional
level as well as intra-party splits. In both cases the early election
was supported by all the main parties.[87]
Germany offers a reminder that no confidence motions can
be manipulated to force an early dissolution. The experience in
1982 also shows that a party forcing an early election will not
necessarily pay an electoral price, since Kohl increased his majority
following the dissolution. On the other hand, the 2005 episode
brought the opposition (Angela Merkel) into power. This was not
surprising given that at the time early dissolution was contemplated,
the CDU-CSU coalition was ahead in all polls.
It is difficult to devise a set of rules robust enough to
withstand the wishes of a parliamentary majority. But that does
not undermine the case for trying to construct a set of rules
in the first place. Rules in politics are occasionally circumvented;
but if they succeed in creating a new norm, obeyed by most of
the parties most of the time, that can be a net gain.
Fig 7.2
PATHOLOGY OF MID TERM DISSOLUTIONS
Reason for early dissolution
| Cases | Total
|
To increase a government majority
| UK 1900, 1911, 1924, 1951, 1966, Oct 1974.
CANADA 1958, 1965, 2000, 2008.
IRELAND Sept 1927, 1938, 1944, 1951, 1954, 1965, 1981, Nov 1982, 1989.
FRANCE 1981, 1997.
GERMANY 1972, 1983, 2005.
| 24 |
After a constitutional crisis / major constitutional change
| UK 1910
CANADA 1949
IRELAND 1948, 1961, 1977
GERMANY 1990
SWEDEN 1921, 1970
| 8 |
After losing a vote of no confidence | UK 1979
CANADA 1926, 1963, 1974, 1980, 2006
FRANCE 1962
| 7 |
After major policy change | CANADA 1911, 1965, 1974, 2000, 2008
| 5 |
Resignation of a Prime Minister, new mandate sought
| UK 1906, 1923, 1955
CANADA 1957, 1968
SWEDEN March 1920, October 1920
| 7 |
Collapse of a coalition / loss of supply |
UK 1922
CANADA Feb 1982, 1987, 1992, 1994
| 5 |
Post-war | IRELAND 1923 |
1 |
After political crisis/ collapse of a government
| UK Feb 1974
FRANCE 1968
SWEDEN 1914, 1958
| 4 |
After a new constitution | IRELAND 1937
FRANCE 1946, 1958
| 3 |
Government split | UK 1931 |
1 |
Dissolution before a no confidence motion |
IRELAND 1957 | 1 |
To form a united government (with the presidential party)
| FRANCE 1988 | 1 |
| |
|
8. THE ROYAL
PREROGATIVE
8.1 Power of dissolution
The bill removes altogether the prerogative power of dissolution.
Parliament would automatically be dissolved every five years for
ordinary general elections. For extraordinary elections, parliament
can only be dissolved mid term by its own resolution under clause
2. Clause 3(2) provides that "Parliament cannot otherwise
be dissolved". So there is no residual prerogative power
to dissolve.
This should help to protect the Crown from controversy. As
Robert Blackburn has argued, the role of the Monarch may be protected
rather than eroded by fixed term parliaments:
A final constitutional advantage of fixed term Parliaments
would be to remove any prospect of the British monarchy becoming
the subject of political controversy if some special difficulty
over the legitimacy of a dissolution arises |
Any monarch who allowed him/herself to be persuaded to go
ahead and reject the advice of a Prime Minister | would be tempting
political suicide. | It is very much therefore in the monarchy's
own interests to avoid such a situation. Until the law is modernised
within a framework of a fixed term Parliament, the Palace's wisest
course of action | will be always to follow Prime Ministerial
advice.
[Fixed term parliaments] would remove any question of the
personal discretion of the monarch | Far from diminishing the
role of the Crown within the constitution, its future would be
better protected.[88]
This view is echoed by the coalition government:
|[It] instead removes a difficult dilemma for the monarch,
who is bound under the current conventions to take the advice
of the Prime Minister seeking the dissolution. That puts the monarch
in an invidious position if that advice is not consistent with
the political situation that, it might be suspected, is present
in the House. By removing the prerogative exercised by the Prime
Minister, the monarch is in the stronger position of not being
put in the embarrassing position of having to divine by means
that are not clear the intentions of the House.[89]
The prerogative power to dissolve parliament, and in exceptional
cases to refuse a dissolution, has long been regarded as an important
constitutional long stop. It is a big step to remove a constitutional
reserve power. In other Westminster systems such as Australia,
Canada and New Zealand the Crown retains the power to dissolve
parliament, and to refuse a dissolution. In most western European
countries the head of state retains a discretionary power to dissolve
parliament.[90] So it
is tempting to retain the discretionary power as a deep reserve
power, to be deployed only in an extreme political or constitutional
crisis.
It is tempting, but unwise. The difficulty is that once the
prerogative power is retained, politicians may be tempted to use
it. This is what happened in Canada in 2008, when the Prime Minister
Stephen Harper asked the Governor General for an early dissolution
only a year after the Parliament had passed legislation for fixed
term parliaments. The legislation had preserved the prerogative
powers of the Crown, in order to avoid the need for a constitutional
amendment. The Prime Minister went against the spirit of the fixed
term legislation, and inevitably drew the Governor General into
political controversy, whether she refused the dissolution, or
granted it (in the event, she followed prime ministerial advice
and granted it).
8.2 Power to appoint new Prime Minister
The prerogative power to appoint a Prime Minister is unaffected
by introducing fixed term parliaments. The test is who can command
the confidence of the House of Commons. As the new Cabinet Manual
puts it:
The Sovereign will invite the person who it appears is most
likely to be able to command the confidence of the House to serve
as Prime Minister and to form a government. However, it is the
responsibility of those involved in the political process, and
in particular the parties represented in Parliament, to seek to
determine and communicate clearly who that person should be.[91]
The occasions when the Monarch will be required to appoint
a Prime Minister will be after an election, or following the death,
retirement or resignation of the incumbent Prime Minister. On
each occasion the Monarch is invited to make an informed guess
("the person who it appears is most likely to be able to
command confidence |"), and that person then faces an early
test of confidence in the debate on the Queen's Speech. One way
of avoiding the guessing game would be for the House of Commons
to hold an investiture vote, rather than leaving the test of confidence
to the Queen's Speech debate. This is what happens in the Scottish
Parliament, where the first business of a new parliament is to
nominate a new First Minister, who is then appointed by the Queen.
The switch to an investiture vote could be made by statute, or
by a change to Standing Orders.
8.3 Power of prorogation
The Bill does not affect the prerogative power to prorogue
parliament. Prorogation has not been called into question in Britain;
but it has in Canada. In December 2008 the Prime Minister Stephen
Harper asked the Governor General to prorogue Parliament only
days before a confidence motion which he seemed likely to lose.
In January 2010 he again sought a prorogation until March, leading
to allegations that he wanted to shut down a critical parliamentary
inquiry. In the British context it may not be necessary to seek
to regulate the power of prorogation; but to prevent prorogation
being used to avoid a confidence motion, the Cabinet Manual could
perhaps specify the circumstances in which prorogation is used,
and those in which it should not be used.
8.4 Power of proclamation
The Bill retains the system of issuing writs for the election,
and a proclamation to summon the new parliament and appoint the
date of its first meeting. Writs for the election are issued by
the Lord Chancellor and the Secretary of State for Northern Ireland
(cl 3(3)). The proclamation is issued by the Queen, and the appointed
day for the first meeting of the new parliament is chosen on the
advice of the Prime Minister. In 2010 the date for the first meeting
of the new parliament was set for 12 days after the election,
to allow more time for the induction of new MPs, following a recommendation
of the Modernisation Committee's 2007 report Revitalising the
Chamber. But this incurred criticism from some Conservative
MPs, who thought the outgoing government had deliberately delayed
the start of the new government's programme.
It does seem odd that election writs are still issued by
government ministers, and that the date of the first meeting of
the new parliament is decided by the Prime Minister. The main
justification for fixed term parliaments is to take power from
the Prime Minister and give it to parliament. Following the same
logic, consideration should be given to the Electoral Commission
issuing the writs for the election; and the Speaker deciding the
date of the first meeting. In Tony Wright's Fixed Term Parliaments
Bill 2001 the power to decide the dates for issue of the writs,
polling day, and the meeting of the new parliament was conferred
on the Electoral Commission (see section 6.2). That seems right
in terms of who should control issue of the writs and polling
day. But parliament should decide the date of its first meeting,
with the decision being made by the Speaker of the outgoing parliament.
9. ENTRENCHMENT AND
JUSTICIABILITY
9.1 Entrenchment
This chapter addresses two questions:
Would a future government and parliament be bound
to observe the new law, or to retain it?
Would the courts enforce it?
The answer to the first question is almost certainly not.
Under the UK's doctrine of parliamentary sovereignty, a government
can always invoke the current sovereignty of the current Parliament
to repeal the legislation of a previous Parliament. So it would
be difficult for the new law to be legally entrenched. A later
Act of Parliament could always provide that the next general election
shall be held on x date, notwithstanding the provisions of the
Fixed Term Parliaments Act 2011; or simply repeal the Fixed Term
Parliaments Act altogether.
The question may be raised of whether fixed term parliaments
should be more strongly entrenched than this. It is not easy to
entrench legislation within the British system of parliamentary
sovereignty, but there are three possible mechanisms:
Requiring the consent of both Houses to any measure amending
the new law, by excepting amendments to the Fixed Term Parliament
Acts from the terms of the Parliament Act 1911 (so that the Lords
have a veto)
Requiring special voting majorities for any amendments to
the Fixed Term Parliaments Act (as New Zealand requires for amendments
to provisions of their Electoral Acts)
A referendum requirement for any amendments.
In the past entrenchment has been considered difficult if
not impossible, but attitudes are changing. The Fixed Term Parliaments
Bill itself contains a super majority requirement. The Conservatives
are proposing a form of entrenchment for another constitutional
change (the requirement that future EU Treaties be subject to
a referendum). If entrenchment is desired, the first mechanism
above is preferable for a strong and effective form of entrenchment:
and an appropriate one, since the consent of the Lords is already
required to extend the term of a parliament beyond five years.
Special majorities are so far unknown in the UK. A referendum
seems too high a threshold for what may sometimes be minor amendment;
and it is impossible in advance to distinguish a minor from a
major one.
Entrenchment may prove unnecessary. What is sought is to
create a new norm. In other countries which have introduced fixed
term parliaments, the norm has generally been observed. The one
exception is Canada, where it was not a later government which
breached the norm, but the very government which had introduced
it. But in all the Canadian provinces and Australian states which
have introduced fixed terms, the new law so far has been observed.
9.2 Justiciability
A related question is whether there could be recourse to
the courts to enforce the requirements of a fixed term law. The
probability is that they would consider the issue to be non-justiciable;
an obligation to be enforced in the political but not the legal
sphere.
The most likely context for a legal challenge would be an
attempt by a government to seek an early dissolution, as happened
in Canada in 2008, and in Germany in 1982 and 2005. In the former
instance, the Canadian Federal Court of Appeal dismissed the challenge
on the basis that section 56.1(1) of the Canada Elections Act
2000 specifically preserved the powers of the Governor General.[92]
By convention, this extended to the power of the Prime Minister
to advise the Governor General about the dissolution of parliament.
With regards to the 1982 early dissolution in Germany, the
German Constitutional Court held that in the absence of unconstitutional
actions, it would be politically inexpedient to go against the
judgments of the President, Chancellor and leaders of the political
parties.[93] The Court
accepted that Kohl faced general difficulties due to which he
could not rely on a consistent majority in parliament. The Court
responded similarly to the 2005 episode; the Chancellor's assessment
as to whether continuous governance could be assured was accepted.[94]
The international experience demonstrates that courts are
unwilling to engage with such politically sensitive decisions,
and a similar response is to be expected from the British courts.
10. ROLE OF
THE HOUSE
OF LORDS
10.1 Does the Bill come under the exception to the Parliament
Acts?
The Parliament Act 1911 states that the Parliament Acts procedure
for passing legislation without the consent of the House of Lords
cannot be used in the case of bills that extend the life of a
parliament. It could be argued that the Fixed Term Parliaments
Bill contains "any provision to extend the maximum duration
of Parliament beyond five years". It enables the Prime Minister
to delay a general election by up to two months, so enabling a
parliament to last for five years and two months.
This is a hypothetical issue, which would only come alive
politically if the Bill is rejected by the House of Lords, and
then reintroduced in the next session with a view to passing the
Bill without the consent of the House of Lords under the Parliament
Acts. It seems unlikely that it is a bill over which the Lords
would have an absolute veto; but equally fanciful arguments were
advanced in Jackson v AG.[95]
10.2 The Lords as constitutional guardian
The Wakeham Royal Commission on reform of the House of Lords
recommended that the Lords should play a vital role as one of
the main checks and balances within the British constitution.
One of its most important functions was to act as a "constitutional
long stop". This is reflected in its existing veto power
over any attempt to extend the life of a parliament beyond five
years, and its veto powers over the dismissal of key office holders,
such as senior judges and the Auditor General. But although the
Commission were invited to extend the veto powers of the second
chamber to other constitutional legislation, they declined to
do so:
Our fundamental concern about any such proposal is that it
would alter the current balance of power between the two chambers
and could be exploited to bring the two chambers into conflict.
It would be inconsistent with the requirement in our terms of
reference "to maintain the position of the House of Commons
as the pre-eminent chamber of Parliament" and with our view
of the overall role that the second chamber should play.[96]
10.2 Giving the Lords a veto
Notwithstanding the views of the Wakeham Commission, the
House of Lords could be given a special power of veto in relation
to certain aspects of the operation of the Fixed Term Parliaments
Act, or any attempt to amend it. Under the bill the Lords will
already have a power to veto any proposal by the Prime Minister
to move the date of an election forwards or backwards by two months.
The necessary statutory instrument must be approved by each House
of Parliament: and the Lords can if they wish withhold their approval.
The Parliament Acts do not apply to delegated legislation. Although
the Lords rarely veto such legislation, they have occasionally
done so. One recent occasion was in connection with an election,
when the Lords vetoed the Greater London Authority Expenses Order
2000, in order to require the provision of freepost delivery in
the London mayoral elections.
If there was concern about the risk of abuse of the provisions
for mid term dissolution, the Lords could also be given an absolute
veto before an early general election takes place under clause
2 of the bill. There is a parallel with the Lords' existing power
under the Parliament Act 1911 to veto any extension of the life
of a parliament beyond five years. In this case they would also
have the power to veto any attempt to reduce the term of a parliament
to less than five years. But the two cases are not equivalent.
In the former case the Lords has power to prevent a government
postponing an election, possibly for ever; in the latter case
the proposal is to bring forward the date of an election, which
is much less anti-democratic. The Lords might feel uncomfortable
with such a power, arguing that it was essentially for the House
of Commons to decide whether it should face early dissolution.
A third role for the Lords could be to give them a special
protective role in relation to the Fixed Term Parliament Act as
a whole. This could be done by excepting amendments to the Fixed
Term Parliament Act from the terms of the Parliament Act 1911,
so that the Lords have an absolute veto in relation to any amendments
to the Act. It would be a means of entrenching the Act against
subsequent amendment, which is discussed in chapter 9.1.
12
Representation of the People Act 1983, Schedule 1, §2(1)(a) Back
13
"Dissolution of Parliament: Factors in Crown's Choice",
The Times, 2 May 1950, p.5 Back
14
For a table of dates relating to general elections since 1918,
see: House of Commons Library Research Paper 09/44, Election Timetables,
13 May 2009 Back
15
Ibid. Back
16
Draft Cabinet Manual Chapter 6 (Feb 2010): Election and Government
Formation, para.14 Back
17
Ibid. Back
18
Ibid. para.18 Back
19
Ibid. para.21 Back
20
HC Deb 5 Jul 2010 col.23 Back
21
The Coalition: Programme for Government, p.26, available at http://programmeforgovernment.hmg.gov.uk/files/2010/05/coalition-programme.pdf Back
22
E.g. Jack Straw MP, HC Deb 7 Jun 2010 col.25 Back
23
HL Deb 27 May 2010 cols.136-244 Back
24
HC Deb 5 Jul 2010 col.23. For the full quote from Nick Clegg see
chapter 6.1 Back
25
Nick Clegg MP, HC Deb 5 Jul 2010 col.29; David Howarth MP, HC
Deb 25 May 2010 col.146-7 Back
26
Agreement for Stability and Reform 21 May 2010, Introduction;
http://www.cabinetoffice.gov.uk/media/409174/stabilityreformmay2010.pdf.
Confirmed by David Heath MP, HC Deb 25 May 2010 col.147 Back
27
Lord Holme, HL Deb 22 May 1991 col.245. See also Lord Jenkins
quoted in section 5.1. Back
28
Robert Blackburn, Memorandum on Electoral Law and Administration,
Appendices to Minutes of Evidence, Select Committee on Home Affairs,
May 1998 Back
29
Electoral Commission, Election Timetables in the UK June 2003
p 3. Electoral Commission, Securing the Vote, 2005, p 53. Back
30
Electoral Commission. Report on the administration of the 2010
general election. July 2010 Back
31
HC Deb 21 February 1911 c1749 Back
32
Robert Blackburn, Memorandum on Electoral Law and Administration,
Appendices to Minutes of Evidence, Select Committee on Home Affairs,
May 1998 Back
33
http://www.justice.gov.uk/consultations/docs/election-day-weekend-voting.pdf
p6 Back
34
Minister of State, Ministry of Justice (Michael Wills) Hansard:
22 March 2010 http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200910/ldhansrd/text/100322-wms0002.htm Back
35
http://www.justice.gov.uk/consultations/docs/election-day-weekend-voting.pdf
p40 Back
36
Henry Milner, `Fixing Canada's Unfixed Election Dates: A "Political
Season" to Reduce the Democratic Deficit', Institute for
Research on Public Policy: Policy Matters, December 2005, p.18
Available at http://www.irpp.org/pm/archive/pmvol6no6.pdf Back
37
Scotland Act 1998 s.1(2); Government of Wales Act 2006 s.3(1);
Northern Ireland Act 1998 s.31(1) Back
38
Canada Elections Act 2000 s.56.1(2) Back
39
Ibid., s.56.1(1) Back
40
S.C. 2000, c.9 Back
41
Government of Canada Privy Council Office, "Canada's New
Government Proposes Fixed Election Dates", 30 May 2006. Available
at http://news.gc.ca/web/article-eng.do?crtr.sj1D=&mthd=advSrch&crtr.mnthndVl=6&nid=216599&crtr.dpt
1D=&crtr.tp1D=&crtr.lc1D=&crtr.yrStrtVl=2006&crtr.kw=&crtr.dyStrtVl=29&crtr.aud1D=&crtr.mnthStrtVl=5&c
rtr.yrndVl=2006&crtr.dyndVl=1 Back
42
E.g. at second reading, Rob Nicolson MP, HC Deb 18 Sep 2006 col.2876 Back
43
Bill C-512: An Act to provide fixed dates for the election of
members to the House of Commons and to amend the Constitution
Act, 1867 (1 April 2004) Back
44
Constitution Act 1996 s.23(2) Back
45
Ibid., s.23(1) Back
46
Election Act 1990, s.9(2) Back
47
Ibid., s9(1) Back
48
Ibid., ss.9.1(6)-(7) Back
49
Elections Act, s.49.1(2) Back
50
Legislative Assembly Act, s.2 Back
51
House of Assembly Act 1990, ss3-3.1 Back
52
Elections and Plebiscites Act 2006, s.39(5) Back
53
Election Act 1988, s.4.1 Back
54
Legislative Assembly and Executive Council Act, s.8.1 Back
55
Constitution Act 1975, ss.38-38A, as amended by the Constitution
(Parliamentary Reform) Act 2003, No.2/2003 Back
56
Ibid., s.8A Back
57
Ibid., s.65C(2) Back
58
Constitution of 1996 s.49(1) Back
59
REM Irving and WE Paterson, `The Machtwechsel of 1982-83: A Significant
Landmark in the Political and Constitutional History of West Germany',
Parliam Aff (1983) 36: 417-435 Back
60
Miskimmon, Paterson and Sloam, `Germany's Gathering Crisis', (2005)
Palgrave Macmillan Back
61
Constitution of October 4, 1958 art.12 Back
62
Lord Jenkins, HL Deb 11 March 1992 vol.536 col.1333 Back
63
Recommendations 15 and 16 Back
64
The Report of the Working Party on Electoral Systems 1993, Professor
Raymond Plant, Labour Party: 1993, Section II, 2 (i) Back
65
`The Parliamentary Elections (No. 2) Bill is designed exclusively
to put into legislative form all the recommendations in Section
2 of the 1993 Plant report...The Parliamentary Elections (No.
2) Bill, therefore, does not cover any issue which is outside
of those 37 specific issues.' Jeff Rooker, Introduction to Notes
on Clauses, May 1994. Back
66
Scotland Act 1998 s.3 Back
67
Northern Ireland Act 1998 s.31 Back
68
Government of Wales Act 1998 s.3 Back
69
P.29 Back
70
P.7, Election Timetables in the UK: Report and Recommendations,
The Electoral Commission, June 2003, available at http://www.electoralcommission.org.uk/__data/assets/electoral_commission_pdf_file/0016/16054/Timetables_10051-7977__E__N__S__W__.pdf Back
71
http://www.timesonline.co.uk/tol/news/politics/article6368275.ece Back
72
"David Cameron says that the Tories would prevent parties
from replacing a serving Prime Minister" 24 April 2010 Independent Back
73
David Howarth MP, HC Deb 16 May 2008, col.1703-1705 Back
74
David Howarth MP, HC Deb 16 May 2008, col.1706 Back
75
HL Deb 11 Mar 1999 col.1367 Back
76
HC Deb 5 Jul 2010 col. 23 Back
77
The dissolution procedure in each country is too complex to summarise
here. It is very ably summarised in Strom, Muller et al Delegation
and Accountability in Parliamentary Democracy,. Oxford University
Press, 2006 at Table 4.12. Back
78
HC deb 8 July 1998 at col 1353. Back
79
Andrew Heard, `Just What is a Vote of Confidence?'. Canadian Jnl
of Pol Science, 40:2 (2007) at 395-416. Back
80
Richard Kelly and Thomas Powell, Confidence Motions, HC Library
Standard Note SN/PC/2873, 9 July 2010. Back
81
Draft Chapter 6 on Elections and Government Formation, published
by the Cabinet Office in February 2010, http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20100416132449/http://www.cabinetoffice.gov.uk/media/343763/election-rules-chapter6-draft.pdf Back
82
Erskine May, Parliamentary Practice, 23rd ed 2004, pp 329-330. Back
83
Constitution of the 4th of October 1958, art.12 al.4 Back
84
Spanish Constitution of 1978, s.115(3) Back
85
Constitution of the Republic of South Africa, art.51(1)(b) Back
86
REM Irving and WE Paterson, "The Machtwechsel of 1982-83:
A Significant Landmark in the Political and Constitutional History
of West Germany", Parliam Aff (1983) 36: 417-435 Back
87
Miskimmon, Paterson and Sloam, "Germany's Gathering Crisis",
(2005) Palgrave Macmillan Back
88
Robert Blackburn, The Electoral System in Britain, London: Blackburn,
1995, p. 61 Back
89
David Heath MP, HC Deb 25 May 2010 col.149 Back
90
Str'm, Müller and Bergman, Delegation and Accountability
in Parliamentary Democracy,. Oxford University Press, 2006 pp
163-4 and Table 4.1.2. The countries are Austria, Belgium, Finland,
France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg,
Netherlands, Portugal. Back
91
Draft Chapter 6 on Elections and Government Formation, published
by the Cabinet Office in February 2010, http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20100416132449/http://www.cabinetoffice.gov.uk/media/343763/election-rules-chapter6-draft.pdf Back
92
Duff Conacher v PM of Canada 2010 FCA 131 Back
93
BVerfGE 62, 1 Back
94
BVerfG, 2 BvE 4/05 of Aug. 25, 2005, available at http://www.bverfg.de/entscheidungen/ Back
95
2005 UKHL 56, 2006 1 AC 262. Back
96
A House for the Future. Report of the Royal Commission on Reform
of the House of Lords. Cm 4534, 2000 at para 5.4. Back
|