Examination of Witnesses (Questions 1-122)
SIR
NICHOLAS MACPHERSON,
TOM SCHOLAR,
AND ANDREW
BAILEY
8 FEBRUARY 2011
Q1 Chair: Welcome
to you all. This is becoming a regular occurrence. We are looking
today at maintaining financial stability in the UK and the support
scheme. In particular, I welcome Andrew Bailey and thank him
for giving evidence to us this morning. Our focusand we
will try and keep it as suchis whether the interests of
the taxpayer have been protected in this array of interventions
and whether value for money has been secured. I am going to start
off on a very specific point, which is RBS and Lloyds, and we
will then move to the general. According to our ReportI
have not looked at the latest share pricewe would still
be losing billions were we to sell our shares today. The £12.5 billion
figure probably has not shifted much. Indeed, it has probably
gone in the wrong direction, has it not? It has gone down?
John Ellard: It
was £8.4 billion as of yesterday evening.
Chair: Slightly better,
but it is still £8.4 billion. That represents a movement
since we wrote the Report. How confident are you that we are
going to be able to extricate ourselves without loss to the taxpayer
or, furthermore, with any profit to the taxpayer?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
As I think I have told the Committee before, I remain confident
that the taxpayer will make a profit on these shareholdings.
The share price obviously varies from day to day and week to week.
There have been brief periods even in the last 18 months where
the taxpayer has been in profit. I would expect that to happen
again in future, mainly because I think both banks are making
progress in terms of returning to underlying profitability. Lloyds
is clearly further ahead of the curve than RBS, but the share
price is moving in the right direction and profit is moving in
the right direction. There is a lot of uncertainty in the market
at present because of the Independent Commission on Banking.
As this Committee has discussed, on the one hand we want to make
a profit, while on the other hand we want a well-functioning economy,
and sometimes these things do trade off against each other. Nevertheless,
even taking into account all those factors, I still think we will
make a profit.
Q2 Chair: What
is your priority? I know you have to balance the two, but where
would you prioritise: protecting the taxpayer's interest in getting
our money back or looking at the longer term health of the two
institutions?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I think you are targeting both, and you are trying to optimise
along the curve of possibilities. As accounting officer, the
issue of value for money is very important. In terms of the future,
were a decision taken that clearly reduced the value of shares
in the interest of the wider public good, as accounting officer
I would want to look very hard at that judgment. It is easy to
make assertions about wider benefits to the economy, but as the
accounting officer I will need to look very hard and form an assessment.
Q3 Chair: I
take from that the priority really is your accounting officer
priority.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
The Treasury has wider interestit is an economics ministry
and a finance ministry. We really want the economy to recover.
Banking is critical to that and the revenue gains of a successful,
functioning banking system are potentially very big indeed. Nevertheless,
as accounting officer I have to weigh these things up. At this
stage, no decision has been taken to sell any of the shares, but
I am just giving you an indication of what I am going to have
to do in future.
Q4 Chair: And
as accounting officer, would you be prepared to put more money
into both banks if that became necessary?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Well at the present time I do not see any immediate prospect of
having to put more money into the banks.
Q5 Chair: But
can you see circumstances
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Well obviously if conditions deteriorated, you cannot rule anything
out, but again, you have to make a hardheaded assessment
at the time. I think it is fair to say that looking at the interventions
over the last few years, it has been striking that successive
Governments have generally taken decisions that did not raise
issues for me as accounting officer or were inconsistent with
the principles of managing public money. There were two occasionswe
discussed one of them last week; the other related to the Iceland
bank interventions, on which I had to seek a directionbut
those were very small decisions against the background of very
largescale interventions elsewhere.
Q6 Chair: You
alluded to it, but if the Independent Commission on Banking were
to come up with a proposal for breaking up the banks, would that
have an impact on our financial interest? It could depress the
share price, ensuring that we got less back for our money.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I do not want to prejudge the commission, but inevitably in looking
at possible policy options, some may help the economy at the expense
of the share price, just as other interventions might help the
share price at the expense of the economy. It is the job of the
Treasury to try to reconcile the two objectives.
Q7 Chair: But
your aim is to get a profit back? You are being a bit evasive.
I understand the difficulties.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
No, I am not being evasive. I do not think the Government's stated
objective is to make a profit. I am sure there are certain circumstances
the Government could foresee where in a wider public interest
it would be worth taking a loss. Nevertheless, I remain reasonably
confident on broadly unchanged policies that we will make a profit.
Q8 Chair: One
final thing, then I want to go to Jo. These are nationalised
institutions, to all intents and purposes. In previous privatisations,
we have tended, I think, to affect what we have got for our money
by flooding the market with most of the equity on day one. Are
you sensitive to this issue? Will you therefore be watching how
you actually sell the shares back into the market? Doesn't that
mean that we will probably be here in two years' time talking
about our shares in both RBS and Lloyds?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
That is a very good point. One of the reasons why UK Financial
Investments was set up at arm's length was to advise on these
issues. The Treasury will need to advise the Chancellor, who
ultimately will take the decision on this in the light of UKFI's
advice, but as and when these shares are sold into the market,
the sheer scale of the holdings will I think make this the biggest
share sale ever.
Q9 Chair: There
is an amazing graph here. You saw it?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Yes. And that will be the case by a very long way, which suggests
to meagain, I do not want to prejudge the futureor
leads me to guess that you would do it in a series of tranches
and you would be very much trying to test the market. I expect
to see very many PAC hearings in the future over whether the Government
makes a good job of privatisation or not. We have actually been
in touch with the NAO, which has drawn lessons from previous privatisations,
and we will be poring over its guidance and advice.
Q10 Joseph Johnson:
Nice to see you again. I want to go straight to the point you
made about the revenue gains from having a functioning banking
system being very great indeed. Have you quantified them?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
No, we have not quantified them in those terms, simply because
there is a huge spectrum of what represents a well performing
banking system. One of the reasons why we have a massive deficit
right now is because we have a revenue problem rather than a spending
problem, and the revenue problem reflects the fact that the British
economy became extremely dependent on financial services and banking
in particular. So we are acutely aware of how critical this is
for public finances.
Q11 Joseph Johnson:
All right, but the Bank of England has quantified the cost of
having very large systemic banks to the UK taxpayer, and it has
done so to the tune of £100 billion a year. So it would
be good to get a sense of what we are getting in return for that
implicit subsidy that the UK taxpayer is giving to the banking
system every year.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Well I am perhaps not as well acquainted with the Bank of England's
analysis as my colleagues here, who may want to comment.
Andrew Bailey:
I think the other reason for putting that analysis forward is
from the point of view that actually, it is not an appropriate
situation to be in. So you are right to say, "What is the
calculation on the other side of the balance sheet?" Frankly,
from my perspective, the big lesson out of all of this that is
captured in this Report is we should have a banking system that
is not, either explicitly or implicitly, dependent on public money.
Q12 Chair:
Can I just ask you to speak up a bit, because the acoustics are
really poor?
Andrew Bailey:
We should not have a banking system that is either explicitly
or implicitly dependent on that figure that you just quoted, or
indeed any other figure. That must be the objective. So we want
to get away from that.
Q13 Joseph Johnson:
A zero subsidy?
Andrew Bailey:
Yes.
Q14 Joseph Johnson:
The IMF has done some research that suggests that if we are to
move away from the current system, where the taxpayer is subsidising
the cost of capital to the large systemic banks to the tune of
£100 billion a year, to an environment where there is
no subsidy at all, the size of bank balance sheets would need
to be less than £100 billion. That is significantly
smaller than they are at present. I think RBS's balance sheet
is well over £1 trillion still, ditto Barclays and certainly
HSBC. So how are we going to get to that environment where there
is no subsidy from the taxpayer to the banking system?
Andrew Bailey:
Well let me just step back a moment and put it in context. We
introduced a couple of years ago a resolution regime for banks
in this country, which gave legal powers to the Bank of England.
That regime has worked effectively for small banks. I believe
it can work for small and medium sized banks and indeed there
was a predecessor regime for a period of time that followed the
nationalisation of Northern Rock, which did the same thing. But
let us be absolutely honest: it is not a regime that could work
in its current form for the very largest banks. That is why there
is still further to go. To come back to your question and the
IMF's point, the reason why I started with that point is that
if we moved to a world where the costs, as you put them, are borne
not by public money but by those who invest in the capital and,
if necessary, the creditors of banks, then they have to take decisions
on the extent to which they are prepared to fund the balance sheets
of banks. So the conclusion that the IMF draws comes out of that.
It is not Godgiven that a bank's balance sheet will be
smaller by x. It would then be a product of people who
would be at risktruly at risk, as opposed to the public
purse being at risktaking decisions on what they are prepared
to fund and at what price they are prepared to fund it, clearly
because of the risk element involved.
Q15 Joseph Johnson:
What I am not getting very clearly is a sense that you have done
a cost benefit analysis of having large systemic banks of the
size of Barclays, RBS and Lloyds. I just do not think it is coming
through very clearly that you have weighed up the taxpayer subsidy
versus the advantages we are getting from it.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
The banking commission is looking at this in very great detail
as we speak. It will report later this year.
Q16 Joseph Johnson:
But you have done no independent work of your own?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
No, the Government will then have to take a decision on where
it wants to go and that will be based, I suspect, on extremely
heavy-duty cost benefit analysis.
Q17 Joseph Johnson:
But you have done no research or thinking of any sort on this
point?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
No, we do research and thinking about it. What I am not in a
position to do is give you a definitive answer on the effective
subsidy; the Bank of England has done an estimate, but I dare
say if it had done an estimate five years ago, it would have come
up with a very different answer. In a sense we are still dealing
with the consequences of the crisis. The time to do the analysis,
you suggest in definitive terms, is when the Government seeks
to create, in a sense, a new settlement for the banks, which will
come out of the banking commission.
Q18 Joseph Johnson:
The Report does a brilliant job, as I said right at the start,
at capturing the explicit taxpayer exposure to the various schemes
that you have put in place. As I said, I still think it only
captures the tip of the iceberg. On one of the points in particular,
I think it is fair to say that the taxpayer is still implicitly
standing behind all retail deposits in the banking system: £3 trillion.
The last official word we have had from any Government official
on this subject was I think from Alistair Darling at some point
in 200708, when he said that all depositors in similar situations
would be treated in the same way as those in, I think, Northern
Rock and Bradford & Bingley. Has that position
changed?
Tom Scholar: One
thing that has changed since the start of the crisis of course
is that we have a resolution regime for banks now in the Banking
Act 2009, with the Bank of England responsible for resolving banks.
Q19 Chair:
But the Treasury stands behind that resolution scheme as well.
Joseph Johnson: Exactly.
Yes or no? Are we standing behind the £3 trillion
of retail deposits in the banking system? It is a yes or no.
Tom Scholar: Well
I am not sure that it is in fact a yes or no, because I think
it has to be assessed on its merits in each particular case.
So for example, in a world in which markets were stable, confidence
in the banking sector was high and there was an idiosyncratic
shock of some sort affecting just one bank and not others, I think
in those circumstances it would be safe to let a bank fail, and
we have seen examples of that in the past. The circumstances
in 2008 and 2009 arose when markets were extremely fragile and
confidence was very weak. In those circumstances, not just in
the UK but in any country in the world, there was potentially
a very great systemic risk from the failure of even a small institution
that in other circumstances would not be considered systemic.
So that may be a more nuanced answer, but I think it is an accurate
reflection.
Q20 Chair:
I just want to pursue Jo's point. You now judge, at the present
time, that we are still in that systemic environment. So at present,
are we or are we not standing behind the £3 trillion
deposits, at this point in time?
Tom Scholar: Well
I think again, even at this point in time, it would be case by
case. For example, you may have seen that there was a failure
of a small bank in Denmark over the weekend. That has been resolvedI
do not know at what cost to the Danish taxpayerbut clearly
if that had happened in the autumn of 2008, even a small bank
in Denmark could have had a ripple effect across the whole European
banking sector. I do not think we are in that position today,
but that said, the sector is still vulnerable. Of course, any
operation would have to be a decision for the Chancellor and that
would be a decision where he would have to weigh up the public
interest: financial stability on the one hand and the taxpayer
exposure on the other.
Q21 Chair:
And the Bank of England, in our Report, suggests that we
have optimistic views on the ability of banks to raise their own
finance at present.
Andrew Bailey:
We do in the current context, but if I could finish off the answer
to the point that was just being made, I do think that as Tom
says it is case-specific and that with the current set of tools
that we have to deal with banks, I do not think any of us should
be confident that we could deal with a major bank in any case.
That is why there is a great deal of work going on, both within
the Banking Commission, as Nick has said, but also internationally
in the Financial Stability Board, to tackle this question. This
is the socalled "Too big to fail" problem. It
is the big outstanding question and until we actually nail that
oneI have to be honestthere is no confident answer
to that question that you have just posed.
Q22 Mr Bacon:
Mr Bailey, the alternative, of course, to too big to fail is a
large number of smaller institutions and more competition. Do
you think increased competition promotes stability in the banking
system? Does it promote financial stability? Or do you agree
with Charles Goodhart that it increases financial instability?
Andrew Bailey:
Well I think we have to have a system where we can deal with bank
failures in a way that supports competition in an industry, because
I think if you are in a world where you have an industry where
entry and exit is stymied, that is bad for all sorts of reasons.
It is bad for the economy and it is bad for consumers. So there
are very good reasons to get out of that world and not to try
to say, "Let's have less competition".
Q23 Mr Bacon:
My question wasn't about the economy or about consumers; it was
about financial stability. Do you think increased competition
is good for financial stability?
Andrew Bailey:
My point was that if we can have a system where we can allow banks
to fail without threatening financial stability, then we can get
the benefits that I was just talking about, which are, in my mind,
very real ones that we should seek. That is the point about financial
stability. Now, at this stage, regarding splitting banks up,
I come at this from a resolution point of view, having been running
resolution in the Bank of England. If you were to say to me,
"Let's just reduce the size of banks to the point where you
can resolve them all over the weekend," I am afraid my answer
to you would be with the current toolsI keep coming back
to this point about the current toolswe would have to do
so much splitting that I think you would regard that as both very
disruptive and probably suboptimal, which is why I come back to
this point that we have not yet finished the toolkit. Not because
I am defending big banks as they are, but this is a very dichotomous
world at the moment; we either have lots of very small banks or
the world we are in, and we do not want to be in either of those.
Q24 Chair:
So what is missing from your toolkit?
Andrew Bailey:
The ability to pass the cost of a bank failure not to the public
purse but through the capital structure and frankly, if necessary,
through to senior creditors. That, let me say, has to be done
on the basis that everybody understands the rules of the game
well in advance. So we cannot wake up one weekend, see a bank
is failing and say, "I have just had an idea, guess what
I am going to do"; this all has to be very well telegraphed.
Q25 Joseph Johnson:
On my analysis, we would need 10 times as many banks as we have
at the moment if the maximum size were to be £100 billion.
I think we have £7 trillion assets in our banking system
at the moment, so we need 70 as opposed to seven big ones.
Andrew Bailey:
I would not put any great weight on a precise number. I think
that is plucking numbers heroically, frankly.
Q26 Joseph Johnson:
But in that order?
Andrew Bailey:
I do not know. Let us use that as a rule of thumb.
Q27 Matthew Hancock:
On this point, is the lack of the adequate tools, as you put it,
for resolution one of the reasons why there has been so little
entry into the market as well? What other reasons would you give
for why there has been so little entry into the market, not only
postcrisis but also over the last 20odd years?
Andrew Bailey:
Well I am not an expert on what I might call the consumer aspects
of it, but one of the big lessons of this crisis is we arelet's
hopecoming out of it with a more concentrated banking industry.
That is one of the consequences of what we have seen happen.
We have seen essentially the middle tier of the banking industry
disappear, so it is a more concentrated industry in that sense.
Q28 Chair:
But that is a bad thing you have just told us.
Mr Bacon: The mutual building
societies have not disappeared, apart from those that demutualised
and then crashed. I hate to use the word "rock" in
this particular context, but the mutual building societies that
remain are what Alistair Darling used to call traditional boring
institutions and they are fairly stable and they are middle tier.
Andrew Bailey:
That is right, but from a competition point of view, we have lost
all the demutualised building societies.
Q29 Matthew Hancock:
So why has there been so little entry?
Andrew Bailey:
I think it is quite hard in the current environment to enter on
any scale, and I think this is an issue that the Banking Commission
is looking at very closely, so I do not want to in any sense guess
what its views will be on that.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
The history of British banking is that everybody wants more competition
in British bankingeverybody is in favour of it; it is a
very good thingbut it is striking that despite numerous
attempts over the years to get more big players into the market,
you always seem to end up with the Big Four dominating it. So
this is not simple or easy. Some of the biggest competition was
around the sort of people who read the Sunday Times best
interest rate tables and those were the classic Icelandic banks.
It is not just big banks that failed in this crisis; at the start,
it was very much the middle tier banks that got into difficulty
and the niche banks like Icesave. So we are waiting on the results
of the commission and we need to take decisions in the light of
that.
Q30 Stella Creasy:
You are in a difficult position now, though, are you not, because
unlike previous generations you have a substantial shareholding
in these banks, so you could influence some of the future direction
on this? If you have identified a lack of competition and a lack
of the middle players as a challenge, where does that leave the
decisions that the Treasury will have to make and the advice it
might give the Chancellor about either the sale of shares or when
to sell or some of the issues we have already talked about? It
is a different scenario, having set out all those things, to previous
generations and how they dealt with the banks, is it not?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
In one sense it is, but UKFI, which is effectively taking the
shareholder role, will give advice to the Chancellor purely from
the shareholder perspective in terms of maximising value to the
shareholder. The Treasury will then advise the Chancellor, taking
those issues into account but also taking into account the wider
economic and competition issues. In due course, we will need
to account to this Committee that whatever decisions are taken
were the right ones.
Q31 Ian Swales:
I would just like to build on that and talk about the role of
the Treasury. The Treasury, as you said earlier, has Treasury
responsibilities and responsibilities to the wider economy. As
Stella has just said, you have also now got responsibilities as
an investor in the banking system. You are also there behind
regulation in the system. So it would seem that there is a potential
conflict of interest in all of this. A support regime has been
put in place for banking. If I were in the banking industry,
I would feel very comforted by the fact that the Government appeared
to be standing behind most of what I do, and that would encourage
certain kinds of behaviours in me. I suppose the job of this
Committee is to convince ourselves on the very narrow definition
of value for money for the taxpayer. How do we convince the man
in the street that the sum total of all this activity is going
to produce the optimum result for them? I think that is what
we are all struggling with.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
To pick up on one of the first points you made, I think if I were
a shareholder in Northern Rock, which I am glad to say I was not,
this idea that somehow I got some massive subsidy from the taxpayer
would not really ring true. If I was a shareholder in Bradford
& Bingley, I wouldn't feel too happy either. Even if I was
a shareholder in RBS, funnily enough, I would have seen my shareholding
very severely diluted indeed. I think sometimes some of the statements
about being too big to fail can be a bit simplistic. Some of
the people who have been sacked from those banks may have walked
away with money, but their reputations are pretty severely trashed
and, by all accounts, their lives within their communities are
not that fun. So I just want to make that point. But coming
on to your wider point, I think this is going to be a big challenge.
We have gone through a crisis of a nature which this country
has not experienced for well over 100 years. It has been damaging.
Financial services and banking are something that this country
has a comparative advantage in. In taking decisions, it will
be really important that we do not throw the baby out with the
bathwater. It is tempting to think that this country can thrive
economically without a successful and thriving banking system.
I happen to think it is something that is potentially vital to
Britain's economic success. Taking decisions in the coming period,
whether on the shareholding or on the structure of banking, is
going to require some pretty advanced analysis. I think we can
do that. Coming back to your point about the Treasury, it is
important that the Treasury does not seek to take every decision
and interfere in every part of its decision making process, which
is one reason why we have tried to divest some of our responsibilities.
For example, on the banking resolution, initially the Treasury
did the resolution of Northern Rock, Bradford & Bingley and
the Icelandic banks. It did not have to, but that is how it ended
up. But the Bank of England is now firmly responsible for resolution.
The forthcoming legislation that the Government are going to
introduce is going to give the Bank wider responsibilities still.
I think this makes sense, because it is quite dangerous if you
concentrate all decisions in one institution. The critical thing
in terms of designing the governance of banking legislation, regulation
and so on is to get the balance right.
Q32 Chair:
I think that has pushed me into asking you the inevitable question.
If you are the taxpayer and you hear from this morning a theoretical
subsidy of £100 billionwe know from the Report
just on the credit guarantee scheme about a subsidy of £1 billionsquaring
that with the bonuses on the other hand is completely impossible.
I do not know what we are talking about nowadays, but RBS in
particular has 200 staff earning £1 million or more. The
FT yesterday talked about Bob Diamond on his £9.5 million.
All this risk for the taxpayer£100 billion potential
subsidy and £1 billion on the credit guarantee scheme,
which has kept its costs downand you have got this complete
lack of control from anybody of the bonus structures that individuals
get through work in the bank. That is what the taxpayer can't
get. I suppose it is the inevitable question.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
It is the inevitable question and I have considerable sympathy
for the taxpayer. Indeed, I am one myself. The orders of magnitude
are occasionally disturbing. First, just dealing with our shareholding
issue, we are interested in securing value for money, and sometimes
that means rewarding people within the banks in which the Government
has shareholdings perhaps rather more than we would normally feel
comfortable with.
Q33 Chair:
Well we are interested in value for money and if you look through
our proceedings, we Members of this Committee ask about salary
levels of various civil servants if they exceed the Prime Minister's
salary. We've managed on the whole to get quite a lot right at
reasonable salary levels. RBS has not got a lot right yet and
there are 200 staff who are getting £1 million or more,
with Stephen Hester on a reputed £2.5 million.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Tom was involved in some of the discussions around trying to recruit
Stephen Hester. RBS was in a complete mess, so we did actually
have to get a credible chief executive.
Q34 Chair:
Maybe you should have sent Tom off to do it.
Tom Scholar: No
thanks.
Chair: At a cost of what?
Tom Scholar: As
the Report says, value for money for the taxpayer in all of the
interventions will ultimately be overwhelmingly dominated by the
proceeds of the eventual sale of the shares in Lloyds and in particular
in RBS. The price at which we can sell those shares is what will
determine what the taxpayer gets back. So maintaining value of
the shareholding is critical for value for money for the taxpayer.
Unfortunately, given the world in which these banks operate,
that gives rise to tensions of exactly the kind that you describe,
which are very difficult to explain and very difficult in some
cases to accept. But basically, if we want to sell our shareholding
and make a decent return on it, we need top-quality management
running the banks, we need people working in the banks who are
able to generate income for them, and because of the market in
which these people operate, I am afraid we have to pay them more
than the Prime Minister's salary.
Q35 Chair:
I think we understand that, but in the market out there, if you
are losing money and you are not viable and you cannot raise your
finance unless you are backed by the taxpayer, it does not seem
the appropriate circumstance in which you dole out £1 million
to 200 of you and £2.5 million to yourself. We could
go beyond, because in the Bank of England analysis, it is not
just the ones that we own; it is all the banks that are benefiting
from taxpayer backing. I could understand if they were making
billions and they were fantastically successful and contributing
to our economy. That would be great. But they are not. When
they are, then maybe we can start talking about those sorts of
bonuses. That is what is wrong about the argument. Of course
we want skilled people, but skilled people should only be rewarded
when they do a job.
Matthew Hancock: As a
point of detail, Margaret, we all know that Stephen Hester arrived
after the crash at RBS, because we all know the knight of the
realm who was in charge at the time. But when the contract was
put in place, I understand it was a two-year contract. Is that
right, for RBS?
Tom Scholar: The
contract
Matthew Hancock: The contract
that covered the bonuses that are paid this year and were paid
last year was a two-year contract?
Tom Scholar: When
the asset protection scheme was agreed, there was a provision
in there that said for the first year UKFI would have a right
of refusal or right to approve the overall bonus pool.
Q36 Matthew Hancock:
Yes. And then for the second year, they should be paid at market
rates.
Tom Scholar: I
do not think it says anything about the second year. It simply
says that for the first year, UKFI have that.
Q37 Matthew Hancock:
So if you could do that for one year, why could you not do it
for longer? Because by doing it for one year, you are taking
on the argument you made just then that actually you need to pay
these people, because for a year UKFI had a veto.
Tom Scholar: Well
again, that was one element of a whole negotiation around the
asset protection scheme. The judgment at the time was that there
were in fact some value implications in signalling to the market,
including of course the staff of RBS, that there would be a tougher
regime on bonuses there
Q38 Matthew Hancock:
But if you had linked it to something like the taxpayer being
in profit, it might have been easier to swallow. As it was, for
the year before the election there were no bonuses and then after
the election the contract did not have a constraint on bonuses.
Tom Scholar: The
general policy framework that the previous Government adopted
and the current Government have also adopted for UKFI and these
shareholdings in general is that the decisions on running the
banks, including on remuneration, should be for the boards of
those banks.
Q39 Matthew Hancock:
Hold on. But for the first year of this arrangement, there was
a constraint, as you have just set out, on bonuses.
Tom Scholar: There
was. So this was a specific
Q40 Matthew Hancock:
Why wasn't that for longer?
Tom Scholar: This
was a specific exception to that general policy.
Q41 Matthew Hancock:
So if you have had an exception, then why was the exception only
written in for such a short period of time?
Tom Scholar: It
would have been possible to have sought a provision for the second
year along the same lines as for the first year. When the decision
was taken, certainly RBS management were very resistant to that,
because they were afraid that they would lose a lot of people.
Q42 Matthew Hancock:
I can see why management might be resistant.
Tom Scholar: They
did lose quite a number of people and that is a concern to them
in maintaining the value of the shareholding. So the decision
was on value for money grounds that it would be damaging to the
value of the shareholding to send this signal about remuneration.
Q43 Matthew Hancock:
So the previous administration could have allowed the Government
to have more constraint over the bonuses being paid this year?
Tom Scholar: They
could have sought it in the negotiation. Whether it would have
been agreed I cannot say. That is the counterfactual. But they
could have sought it; that is true.
Q44 Austin Mitchell:
First, I would like to express my gratitude to Mr Bailey for clearing
up the Icelandic payments situation in 2008. The Grimsby fish
trade and I are very grateful.
Andrew Bailey:
I remember it well.
Austin Mitchell: I was
at a meeting with Icelandic owners last Thursday and they were
gibbering with gratitude. In fact, I had to suggest to them that
their proposal to erect a statue of me in Reykjavik would be better
with a statue of Andrew Bailey.
Andrew Bailey:
You did offer me trips to fish and chip shops.
Q45 Austin Mitchell:
Fish and chip shops are grateful too. But it means that I shall
not be asking you any critical questions about the Bank of England
today, so I want to turn to the Treasury.
Andrew Bailey:
You can if you want.
Austin Mitchell: I want
to ask three simple questions. One is why are we charging the
banks a 4.1% rate of interest but charging Ireland 5.9% for that
loan? How much are we paying on the money we are borrowing to
give those rates of interest to the banks?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Sorry, what does your 4.1% refer to?
Austin Mitchell: It is
in the briefing here. I can turn to it.
John Ellard: It
is an estimate of the gilts rate on the investments in the banks,
I think.
Austin Mitchell: "Lower
than longterm gilts (4.2%)".
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Is this the gilt rate?
Austin Mitchell: Yes.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
That is the rate that the NAO is using to calculate the opportunity
cost of the financial interventions. It is not the rate we have
charged anybody; it is the rate that implicitly we have charged
gilts holders.
Q46 Austin Mitchell:
What rate are we charging the banks? Is it lower than the rate
we are paying to borrow?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
We are charging the banks extensive fees for any intervention
we have made, whether it is the credit guarantee scheme, the special
liquidity scheme and so on. So we are notand I think this
Report bears this outsubsidising the banks in terms of
the actual return we are seeking from them[1].
Q47 Austin Mitchell:
Are they paying less than Ireland?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Ireland's rate reflects European circumstances, the length of
the loan and so on. If we were lending long to banks, I am quite
certain we would be paying something reasonably in that territory.
Tom, do you want to add to that?
Tom Scholar: Yes,
my colleague is absolutely right. For all of our guarantees and
other support operations we charge fees, and as the Report says,
we have already collected £10 billion in fees. There
are three principal loans: one to Northern Rock and one to Bradford
& Bingley. Those banks are entirely in public ownership so,
in a sense, the loan is from one part of the public sector to
another. The third loan is to the Financial Services Compensation
scheme. That was a very short-term loan agreed in the crisis
that now needs to be extended, and so of course we will be looking
at the rate as part of that.
Chair: I want to bring
Stephen in.
Austin Mitchell: Well,
hang on.
Chair: Can you come back
a bit later, Austin, because Stephen wanted to come in on the
previous issue before we lose it? I will come back to you, I
promise you.
Q48 Stephen Barclay:
We had just moved on to bonuses, so could I just clarify what
representations the Treasury made to UKFI regarding the pay of
the new chief executive of Lloyds?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
The new chief executive of Lloyds?
Stephen Barclay: Yes.
What representations Treasury made to UKFI.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Tom?
Tom Scholar: Well
under the general policy framework that I described earlier, hiring
the chief executive and everything that goes with that is a decision
for the board of Lloyds. Obviously in doing so they consulted
UKFI as their largest shareholder. I cannot recall precisely
who said what to whom and when, but it was very clear that the
Government wanted to see somebody hired who would run the business
well.
Q49 Stephen Barclay:
No, I get all that, but at the recent Treasury Select Committee
hearing, the head of UKFI said that Treasury officials made representations
to him regarding the pay of the new chief executive of Lloyds.
Now what I am trying to understand is, as the two senior civil
servants of the Treasury, what were the representations you made?
Tom Scholar: Well
the board and UKFI were very keen to hire Mr Horta-Osrio, who
indeed was hired. That was a very good choice and we are very
comfortable with it. We said to them that we would like them
to hire him on the lowest possible overall package and clearly
a negotiation had to happen. We were not having that negotiation,
but the parameters were very reflective of what the Prime Minister
has said: that he wants to see pay and remuneration in these banks
as a backmarker of the market, rather than at the forefront.
Q50 Stephen Barclay:
What I am trying to understand is how independent UKFI is. So
was the Treasury happy with the £8.3 million package
he received?
Tom Scholar: Well
UKFI as an independent body does not take instructions from us
on this. I think the Government welcomed the appointment of Mr
Horta-Osório as the right person for the job.
Q51 Stephen Barclay:
Do you make representations to other major shareholders or just
to UKFI?
Tom Scholar: The
comments I am referring to I think have been public comments by
the Prime Minister, the Chancellor and others and so all shareholders
are very well aware of what the Government's position on remuneration
in general is.
Q52 Stephen Barclay:
Sure. What I am confused about is you seem to be facing both
ways. Either UKFI is independentin which case why is the
Treasury making representations?or it is not independent,
in which case I would have thought you would be making representations
to other major shareholders regarding your stake in RBS, Lloyds
and other publicly funded banks.
Tom Scholar: As
I said, we did not negotiate the package
Q53 Stephen Barclay:
But you did make representations.
Tom Scholar: Well
we pointed to the public comments of the Prime Minster and the
Chancellor and others.
Q54 Joseph Johnson:
I would like to go back to the point Sir Nicholas was making about
us having a comparative advantage in financial services. We have
certainly got a comparative advantage and investors continually
supply capital to the sector, which suggests we do have a comparative
advantage there. But is it one that generates wealth for those
in society as a wholetaxpayers foremost among themas
opposed to just those investors who are continually underwritten
by the state? I guess it would be preferable from a taxpayer
perspective to have a comparative advantage in a sector that generated
wealth for everybody, not just for the people who supply capital
to the industry. I wondered whether you think we genuinely do
have a comparative advantage in financial services from a taxpayer
perspective.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I think from a taxpayer perspective we do, because there are huge
sections of the financial services sector, in particular in the
City of London but also in Edinburgh and elsewhere, that are not
subsidised, even on the Bank of England's definition of subsidy,
and are generating income and wealth. Now there is a separate
question about whether that trickles down to the rest of the population.
On the whole, I think it does. It creates demand and it creates
income and wealth across the economy. But coming back to your
point, clearly none of us wants to see a protected banking system
underwritten by the taxpayer where absurd salaries are paid.
Coming back to the Vickers commission, I think this is why you
have to look at the structure of the industry. If there are monopoly
rents that somehow the workers can cream off just like professional
footballers cream off economic rent from the Premier League, then
you may think that the competition authorities should do something
about it.
Q55 Joseph Johnson:
I guess that leads me on to the followon point, which is
that banks are global in life, as they say, but national in death.
In order for Britain to have this thriving financial services
industry operating here and generating wealth in the economy,
do we actually have to have the UK taxpayer standing behind them,
or could we not move to a system whereby the City of London was
effectively more like Wimbledon, where we have lots of foreign
players operating here and creating wealth and jobs in the economy,
but without the UK taxpayer having to stand behind large universal
banks with trillion-pound-plus balance sheets of the likes of
RBS, Lloyds, HSBC and Barclays? Can we not let foreign governments
take responsibility for underwriting all their balance sheets
and just allow the tiny British banks to dart in and out like
minnows as they would?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
That is an interesting point of view and you may want to make
that representation to the banking commission. I think these
are precisely the tradeoffs. My experience with the Icelandic
banks is that if you are going to have foreign banks operating
here, you certainly want to ensure that they are properly regulated.
There is a tradeoff. There are some economies of scale
in banking that might be a cause of regret if we just ended up
with very small banks indeed across the sector.
Q56 Joseph Johnson:
But in your view does the City of London, to remain a preeminent
financial centre, certainly in Europe, need to have large British
taxpayerbacked banks or could it retain its competitive
advantage as a financial centre just in offering a playing field
to the world's banks? Do we need Britishbacked banks?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I think there probably are some benefits in having some British
banks, but if the price is that the taxpayer continually has to
put his hand in his pocket, then I would question that.
Q57 Stella Creasy:
I just wanted to come back to Tom's comments about the bankers'
bonuses and some of the challenges that you face in terms of attracting
people to the industry to deal with some of the issues that we
are talking about. How do you square that with the announcement
this morning that we have seen in the press about the increase
in the bankers' levy? What impact do you think that is going
to have?
Tom Scholar: Well
you have seen the announcement this morning. The Government had
said that the intention back in June in the Budget in introducing
the banking levy was to raise £2.5 billion a year from
the banking sector through the levy, but given the uncertainties
at the time, it was a transitional rate for the first year. What
the Government have concluded, having looked at events since then,
in particular with a clearer outlook on the regulatory side and
a strengthening banking sector, is that it is now possible and
indeed safe to introduce the full levy this year without the transitional
period and that is what has been announced this morning.
Q58 Stella Creasy:
But what impact do you think that is going to have? You said,
"Look, the reason we have to pay these people the kind of
bonuses we do is that we do not want them to walk away,"
and yet you are now slapping the banks with another £800 million
bill to pay. It does seem slightly disingenuous.
Tom Scholar: Clearly
an extra tax will reduce post-tax profits by the amount of the
extra tax. Also, I think if taxes were increased ever further,
there would come a point at which that would affect the competitiveness
of the sector compared to other countries. I do not think we
are at that point.
Q59 Stella Creasy:
So this isn't a long term solution then; this is just a short-term
fix because of some of the problems with the Project Merlin negotiations?
Tom Scholar: No,
the bank levy is a permanent feature of the system and will raise
£2.5 billion a year.
Q60 Stella Creasy:
From our perspective as shareholders, we have seen this morning
that there has been a selloff of shares as a result of this.
How is that going to square with some of the decisions that you
say the Treasury is going to make about what is good for the public
purse?
Tom Scholar: I
do not think that the measure announced this morning would have
a long-term impact on share prices across the whole sector.
Q61 Stella Creasy:
But you have said it could have an impact on the competitiveness
of these banks, which obviously will have an impact on some of
the issues that Mr Bacon was raising about the competitiveness
of the banking industry and some of the concerns that we might
have as public taxpayers.
Tom Scholar: Well
what the Treasury needs to decideand the Chancellor needs
to make this judgment in successive Budgets in looking where to
raise tax to finance public servicesis what is both the
fairest and the most efficient way of doing that. That is a very
difficult question, which is repeated in every budget.
Q62 Stella Creasy:
How should we judge the value for money of this decision that
has been press-released this morning?
Tom Scholar: Well
the Government have said that their intention is to raise the
maximum sustainable amount of revenue from the banking sector.
That was said back in the Budget in June and that is very clear
policy. Within that policy, it was judged that it would be possible
not to have this transitional first year.
Q63 Stella Creasy:
But your colleague said obviously there was a tradeoff for
us in terms of what we would get from the share pricesand
as I say, this has now made the share price runversus what
we would get for longer term banking stability and some of the
issues Mr Bailey was raising about long term competitiveness in
the banking market.
Tom Scholar: You
are of course right that in reaching taxation decisions the Chancellor
needs to consider what the impact is. Clearly, other things equal,
raising the tax on the banking sector is not going to be something
that will in general be supporting the share price of banks.
But that is a judgment that has to be made.
Q64 Chair:
Can I move us on and get you back to the schemes we are considering?
If I take just the credit guarantee scheme first, you said earlier,
Sir Nicholas, that there was not any subsidy. As I read the ReportI
may have read it wronglythe scheme has effectively subsidised
the banks to the tune of £1 billion. Page 17, paragraph
1.8. I am assuming that you agree with that.
Stephen Barclay: Market
prices.
Chair: "We estimate
this latter benefit is," and so on; it appears at paragraph
1.8. Can you see?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I can see it.
Chair: Do you accept that?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Yes I do accept that. To that extent, I want to correct what
I said earlier.
Q65 Chair:
Thank you for that. In those circumstances, are you thinking
of increasing chargesthis is all back to protecting the
taxpayer's interestif there is £1 billion playing
around here that we are subsidising them? Or is there a way in
which you are looking at recouping that subsidy? Reading further
into the Report, this scheme is going to go on, because they are
not going to be able to raise their money, so they are going to
have to refinance through the scheme.
Ian Swales: And paragraph
1.7 says, "The fees
were designed to be on a commercial
basis". Those words are there in paragraph 1.7.
Tom Scholar: Let
me answer this. The fee was set and announced in October 2008,
right at the height of the crisis. At that point, the overriding
imperative was to avoid the collapse of confidence and provide
certainty to banks in the market that they could fund themselves.
It was very difficult to know exactly what fee to set. We set
one that was both stronger than the minimum conditions set internationally
and in fact at the higher end of the spectrum internationally,
so we charged more than people did, in general, in other countries.
If you look at what subsequently happened to the commercial price
of providing a similar guarantee, yes it is true, as the Report
says, that the commercial price remained higher for longer than
people were expecting. We will certainly lookand are lookingat
this issue as we go forward.
Q66 Chair:
What does that mean? Be more explicit. Are you going to raise
fees? What are you actually doing to recoup?
Tom Scholar: Let
me refer the Committee to the chart on page 26, which shows the
evolution of the scheme. Most of the paper issued in this scheme
has been three-year paper and the scheme closed at the end of
February last year, so nothing new has been issued since then.
As you see from the chart, gradually this paper is maturing.
Now the question that you raised, Chair, is whether we would
expect banks to roll over that. They are only allowed to roll
over up to onethird within the rules of the scheme, so that
is why you see even the maximum possible coming down. My guess,
though, is that banks will seek not to renew their funding with
a Government guarantee. There is a great interest for the banks
themselves in returning to the market, as they are doing. The
Report talks about the progress that they are making in funding
themselves in the market without Government support and the market
is certainly distinguishing between those banks that need Government
support and those that do not, so I think it is in the interest
of the banks not to roll over that funding.
Q67 Chair:
I understand that that is clearly what they do not want to do,
but if you look at the Bank of England's views on this, that is
where I think there might be some tension. Do you believe that
that view is overoptimistic? Then back to you, Tom: if
it is overoptimistic, are you going to raise the charges
so we don't lose a billion quid on it?
Andrew Bailey:
We made that comment because frankly we felt that it was important
to make it clear to the banks that we thought they had more to
do to get themselves into a position where their funding positions
were sustainable. We looked, with the Treasury, across all the
banks at the assumptions that they were making looking forwards
for the next two or three years. We aggregated them as far as
we could and we said, "We think you have more to do than
your projections would assume." That is the important message
in that. I should say that I think to dateand we made
this point in the Financial Stability Report that we published
just before Christmasover the course of last year, the
banks did what they needed to do to stay on track to come off
these schemes and get themselves in the market, funding as they
should be.
Q68 Chair:
So your view now is that they would not want to roll over and
carry on having that guarantee?
Andrew Bailey:
I am very clear that they do not want to do that.
Q69 Chair:
No, of course they do not want to, but they will not have to?
Andrew Bailey:
I think it is just a case of so far, so good. They have been
encouraged to get themselves into this position. I use that word
"encouraged" advisedly. They have done that, but they
have to keep going. This is not over by any means.
Q70 Chair:
And then if they come back to us for more guarantee, as they can
do, will you ensure that the taxpayer's interest is protected
by raising charges?
Tom Scholar: We
will certainly ensure that the taxpayer's interest is protected.
I would not want to say now what the fee would be.
Chair: It is a lot of
money.
Tom Scholar: That
would depend.
Chair: It is a lot of
money we have lost.
Tom Scholar: But
if they come back for roll-overs, we will certainly re-examine
the fee; the circumstances of today are very different from the
circumstances of October 2008.
Q71 Stephen Barclay:
Can I just clarify: are any of the banks benefiting from these
taxpayer schemes now paying dividends?
Tom Scholar: I
believe that Barclays has paid a dividend and Barclays is certainly
one of the banks in the scheme.
Q72 Stephen Barclay:
So if a bank has rebuilt its capital base and has sufficient money
to be giving away back to its shareholders, should it not be speeding
up the point at which it pays back the taxpayer?
Tom Scholar: The
two schemes that we are talking about here have slightly different
rules. Under the special liquidity scheme operated by the Bank
of England, the banks do have the option of early redemption.
Under the credit guarantee scheme operated by the Government,
they do not have that that option; the paper is out there and
that is because it is a marketbased instrument rather than
the Bank of England scheme, which is offmarket. So a bank
that has CGS paper does not have the option to repay earlier,
but what I think all banks are doing is looking at how to get
their funding in earlier so that they do not run into the kind
of problems that the Report envisages as possible.
Q73 Stephen Barclay:
So are you satisfied that there is nothing further those banks
could do to extricate themselves from Treasury support that they
are not doing because they are paying dividends?
Tom Scholar: As
I say, with regard to the credit guarantee scheme, they cannot
repay it earlier. The question then will be, as and when their
paper matures, whether they will be able to fund themselves without
further recourse to the Treasury. Clearly that will depend in
part on market circumstances, but I think that banks in general
are very keen to get themselves off state support.
Q74 Ian Swales:
They will have the option to roll over still. Despite what Mr
Barclay is saying about them paying dividends, they will still
have the option to roll over in the scheme, will they?
Tom Scholar: They
have the option to request a roll over of up to one third of what
they currently have and of course that would be for discussion
with the Treasury at the time and that discussion would include
the question of the fee.
Q75 Ian Swales:
And would the Treasury have the power to prevent them rolling
over, or is it part of the original agreement?
Tom Scholar: No,
it is at the Treasury's discretion.
Q76 Stephen Barclay:
Can I just clarify, where the taxpayersupported banksRBS
and Lloydsare prohibited from paying a dividend for the
five-year period, which they cannot do unilaterally, have there
been any discussions between the Treasury or Bank of England and
any of those taxpayersupported banks about a dividend being
paid for any period within those five years?
Tom Scholar: They
are prohibited under the state aid agreement.
Q77 Stephen Barclay:
But that is not to say, for example, they could pay a dividend
for 2011 in 2012.
Tom Scholar: They
are prohibited until, I think, the end of April 2012.
Q78 Stephen Barclay:
I guess what I am driving at is that unilaterally they cannot
do it, but have there been any discussions? Eric Daniels was
quoted at some point in terms of making suggestive comments as
to the fact that they cannot unilaterally make the decision to
pay a dividend. What I am just getting confirmation from you
on is, from your point of view in the Treasury, there is no potential
for RBS or Lloyds to pay a dividend in terms of business for that
five-year period.
Tom Scholar: That
is my understanding; it is not an option.
Q79 Austin Mitchell:
Sir Nicholas said just in passing that he likes to be sure that
foreign banks are properly regulated. Now if that is the case,
I would refer him to this article in Vanity Fair.
Chair: We all read Vanity
Fair.
Austin Mitchell: It can
be taken into the Treasury under plain cover, Sir Nicholas. What
it shows is that all of the Irish banks were run as a gigantic
Ponzi scheme to diddle not only foreign markets but the Irish
investors as well. I think you should read that article; it is
fascinating. But my question is different. The possible threat
to stability that most concerns us is instability in the euro
and the threat to the Mediterranean economies, primarily, of having
some kind of breakdown. Now one wonders what we are doing to
stop UK taxpayers having to finance other breakdowns in Eurozone
countries. I see that figure 5 on page 19, which actually is
not a figure at allI like pictures in a Report, but this
is just dense typesays that there is a financial stability
facility with the power to guarantee up to 440 billion
and we do not have to contribute to that, because we are not a
euro member. But is there not also a requirementclause
122 in the Lisbon treatythat we will have to contribute
in the event of a breakdown caused by a natural disaster? When
our outgoing Chancellor Alistair Darling went to the last meeting
after the election, he was told that we would not only have to
contribute, but that the decisions there were taken by majority
voting. Now that referred to natural disasters, but it has been
extended to include disasters within the euro. So isn't there
still an obligation to contribute to disasters in the Eurozone
under clause 122?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Well I do not think clause 122 would apply in future to
Q80 Austin Mitchell:
It applies up to May 2013.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I think that was using money within the existing spending ceilings
of the European Union, which, if it had not been spent on that,
could have been spend on something else. But that was a oneoff.
The Eurozone has developed this facility, which is now
Q81 Austin Mitchell:
So it is not connected with the funding to Ireland?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I think the European Union has made it clear that it will use
the facility in the future, and the facility is financed by the
Eurozone countries and we are not liable for it.
Q82 Austin Mitchell:
We contributed to the loan to Ireland.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Well we contributed a loan to Ireland because the Irish economy
is inextricably linked with the economy of
Q83 Austin Mitchell:
So is the Portuguese.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Well no, it is not. Not to the same degree. Ireland is one of
our biggest export markets and I think our national interest is
tied up with a stable and successful Ireland in a way where, important
though Portugal is, it is not.
Q84 Austin Mitchell:
I would be grateful if you could give us a note on 122 and whether
it applies and what it applies to, because it is a complex issue.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I am very happy to give you a note on it, but I am confident that
Q85 Austin Mitchell:
Thank you. Second question. I was attracted by an article in
The Guardian this morning by George Monbiot. I read his
name as Monoblot because I am very short sighted, but it says
that the Treasury is going to change the Tax Acts of 1988 and
2009. This information comes from Richard Brooks of Private
Eye, who is a very good source. It is going to change it
so that large institutionsthat means banks primarilywhen
remitting profits home from overseas operations, will not now
be charged the difference between the corporation tax rate they
pay in the country where the subsidiaries operate and our higher
corporation tax rates. So they will not be charged for that difference
in the way they have been up to now. Now this is a massive bonus
for the banks and also for multinationals headquartered in Britain.
Isn't there an implication that the Treasury has now become so
stuck into to the banks and so determined to see them prosper
that it is influencing its judgment in respect of tax legislation
on the banks? That inference can be made, surely.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I simply do not agree with that. Only this morning, the Chancellor
of the Exchequer has announced an increase in tax on the banks
and let me assure you that the Treasury
Q86 Austin Mitchell:
But he is giving them this large loophole on the advice of Treasury.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
So intent was I on getting here on time that unlike you I have
failed to read my copy of The Guardian this morning.
Chair: Did you read Vanity
Fair?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Vanity Fair I shall definitely read.
Austin Mitchell: I recommend
that you read this, but I think we should have an answer on that.
Q87 Jackie Doyle-Price:
I just want to come back to this issue of refinancing maturing
debts, because I am getting more and more alarmed that the taxpayer
is going to have to stand behind the banking system for much longer
than we would all like them to. In particular, the Report, at
paragraph 3.9, actually highlights that we still have a global
problem with the lack of wholesale funding. It actually quotes
the IMF as saying that "exits from extraordinary financial
system support, including the removal of government guarantees
of bank debt, will have to be carefully sequenced and planned".
What do you think that means in terms of the time scale of these
projects? Obviously your individual schemes have lifespans, but
clearly with the ongoing global problem of contraction in credit,
we are going to have to be in there longer, aren't we?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
This is something that we identified as an issue well in advance
and the Bank of England has been playing a critical role in encouraging
the banks to, in a sense, line up their refinancing in a way that
will smooth the exit from the various schemes. Andrew, do you
want to expand on that?
Andrew Bailey:
Yes. There is also a critical point about the way our schemes
work, which is different from a number of other major economies.
I will take the Special Liquidity Scheme, because that is the
one we deal with. It is not a money lending scheme; it is a scheme
by which we have, in effect, with the assistance of the Treasury
and the Debt Management Office, swapped assets that the banks
held on their balance sheets that were (a) difficult to value
at the time and (b) difficult to use to finance themselves with,
for Government securities. The reason I say that is that when
we unwind that scheme, as we are now doing, we are not withdrawing
money from the economy; we are in effect unwinding that facility
and saying in simple terms to the banks, "You now go out
and finance yourself using your assets rather than HMG's assets".
That is a rather different process from taking money out. We
are not taking money out. However, as I said earlier, we spent
a lot of time in the early part of last summer with the banks
going through, in the context of the Special Liquidity Scheme,
what was a sensible profile to come out of this thing by the end
point, which is actually just under a year from now. We encouraged
them to smooth that profile, because frankly the profileand
it has been publishedlooked too what I would call clifflike;
too much was left to the end. So we encouraged them to do more
sooner; that is what has been going on for the last seven or eight
months. So far so good, and there is a need to keep doing it.
Q88 Jackie Doyle-Price:
Ultimately, however, where are RBS and Lloyds going to get these
higher deposits from? If they want to reduce their dependence
on wholesale funding and want to withdraw from taxpayer support,
is it really realistic for that extra capital to come from customer
deposits? Where else is it going to come from?
Andrew Bailey:
Well there are a number of things going on there. First, as I
said, we are not withdrawing money out of the economy; they have
to raise the same deposits using their security rather than ours.
Secondly, they are both in the process of running down what they
term non-core assets, which is frankly the stuff that should never
have been on their balance sheets and we certainly do not want
on their balance sheets in the future. Of course, when they do
that, they reduce the need to fund those assets, so they reduce
the balance sheet and that reduces the funding need. The third
question is a good one, because there is clearly pressure in this
country on retail deposits, in the sense that there is more competition
to attract retail deposits. If you look at the rates on retail
deposits relative to the riskfree rates, you can see that.
Now in one sense that is a good thing in an era of low interest
rates for savers. But we do, as you rightly say, have to be very
carefulit goes back to the warning we issued that the Chair
referred tothat this is not unsustainable competition.
That is why we look very carefully at their funding positions
constantly.
Q89 Jackie Doyle-Price:
How is it that America has been able to divest its shareholding
of Citigroup so quickly and what can we learn from that?
Tom Scholar: Perhaps
I can say something about that. There were two features of the
Citi shareholding that are quite different from the situation
that we have here. First of all, the Citi share price recovered
rapidly from the very low level at which the shares were bought,
so that since the summer of 2009 the Citi share price has consistently
been above the inprice that the US Treasury paid. So they
have had an extended period where it has been possible. Secondly,
the actual size of the shareholding was much smaller than either
in Lloyds or RBS, so it was possible to do it more quickly.
Q90 Joseph Johnson:
I just want to go back to the Special Liquidity Scheme and the
credit guarantee scheme that Jackie was asking about. What is
Barclays' use of these two schemes?
Andrew Bailey:
We have not published anybody's use of those schemes. One or
two banks have published their own use of the Special Liquidity
Scheme in the context of prospectuses to raise debt. I do not
think Barclays is one of them. I think you can infer from that
and actually you can infer from one or two of the numbers that
other banks have used that it is a relatively smaller use of the
scheme.
Q91 Joseph Johnson:
In the absence of these schemes, would Barclays be able to stand
on its own two feet in the wholesale funding market, in your opinion?
Andrew Bailey:
Are you asking that question today, or when the scheme was introduced?
Joseph Johnson: Today.
Andrew Bailey:
I think there is every reason to believe, because they are on
track to withdraw these schemes smoothly, that they are able to
do that.
Q92 Joseph Johnson:
They are self-funding? They do not need taxpayersupported
schemes?
Andrew Bailey:
Well, they are coming off those schemes.
Q93 Joseph Johnson:
But today? Bob Diamond the other day told the Treasury Select
Committee that the time for remorse was over. If he is still
using these schemes, is that not premature?
Andrew Bailey:
Well we have said that we want, certainly in the context of the
SLS, for the scheme to be removed smoothly. So we do not want
all the banks to just come off it today, because the wider implications
could be disruptive for the overall funding position. So we want
them to do it smoothly. I should say also in the context of the
SLS that, as the Report says, there is no subsidy in the SLS.
They are paying a rate above the relevant reference rate in the
market for their continuing use of those.
Q94 Stephen Barclay:
But also, in terms of the moving on, Barclays took huge amounts
from the Fed as well. Barclays took the single biggest loan from
the Fed: $47.9 billion in 2008. Barclays was the biggest
cumulative borrower from the TAF as well.
Joseph Johnson: And when
you say small, what are we talking about? Tens of billions?
Hundreds of billions? Tens of billions, presumably.
Andrew Bailey:
Yes.
Q95 Joseph Johnson:
Sir Nicholas, when you heard Bob Diamond, the chief executive
of Barclays, say that the time for remorse was over, what was
your reaction as the head of the Treasury and as a taxpayer, as
you told us?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I think remorse is a difficult concept and I do not want to get
into some great morality discussion, but I think there are still
a lot of lessons to learn from this crisis.
Chair: That is a very
civil service answer.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I think all our institution have shown remorse. - I have shown
remorse and I would like to think that the FSA and the Bank of
England have shown remorse.
Q96 Joseph Johnson:
Has Bob Diamond shown remorse, do you think?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I think some of these institutions should be remorseful too.
Q97 Joseph Johnson:
Can you think of any way to make him more appreciative of the
extent to which the taxpayer continues to subsidise Barclays'
cost of capital and his stonking bonuses?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Well I am always open to suggestions.
Tom Scholar: I
think the work of the Vickers commission will very directly address
the question of implicit subsidy that you have rightly raised.
Q98 Stella Creasy:
So we have to wait until September before there is any contrition?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Well you will wait until September to see the Report and I do
not know precisely when the Government will take decisions, but
decisions there will be.
Q99 Matthew Hancock:
I just want to come back to the issue of wholesale funding, because
Andrew, you said clearly that some assets are being disposed of
that perhaps should not have been bought in the first place.
But then I would like to bring you back to figure 8 on page 24,
which shows the very broadly defined liabilities side of the balance
sheet. It shows that senior debt and securities have remained
at 44% of RBS's balance sheet from June 2009 to June 2010.
Would you not have hoped that in getting rid of some of the assets
that allowed RBS to shrink the balance sheet they could have shrunk
that bit of the other side of their balance sheet?
Andrew Bailey:
I think, frankly, this is a process of several stages. The first
stageand this was absolutely critical, given where RBS
got themselves to in October 2008is to lengthen the maturity
of the funding. As we know, they were not just at the cliff edge;
they went over it. So the first stage is to lengthen the maturity
of the funding. That is critical, because that gets them back
from the edge of the cliff. Then as you rightly say the next
question is what the right mix of funding is for the balance sheet
that they will have in the future once the APS works through and
they adjust their balance sheet to what is a sustainable balance
sheet. So I would see it as two stages. There is a term issue
of funding, which is critical because that is what killed them,
and then there is a mix of funding question.
Q100 Matthew Hancock:
This chart implies that the mix of funding question has not been
addressed at all. Is that right?
Andrew Bailey:
Yes, and I do not think there is a single objective right answer
to that at the moment; we really have to sort out what a sustainable
RBS is for the future and therefore what the funding of that sustainable
RBS would look like.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Just to pick up on that, we all want to see their balance sheets
become stronger and they are. But I think implicit in what you
were saying is that you might want to see the balance sheet shrink
even faster, and there are risks in that.
Q101 Matthew Hancock:
I was talking about the mix, because I totally understand the
macroeconomic risks of trying to reduce the balance sheet too
fast, but the mix on this side of the balance sheet. Are you
therefore disappointed that the customer deposits, which many
regard as a more stable source of funding, have fallen so sharply?
We can see that the wholesale funding has fallen; the problem
is it has not fallen as a proportion.
Andrew Bailey:
Well as I was saying earlier, there is very stiff competition
for customer deposits out there at the moment. It is also worth
saying, of course, that when you define customer, you may be thinking
of man in the street, whereas that is all their customers. So
as their balance sheet shrinks and they go to a smaller, more
sustainable form, it does of course affect the definition of their
customer, so you have to bear that in mind.
Q102 Matthew Hancock:
You mean if they sell off assets, then some of the liabilities
will go with it?
Andrew Bailey:
Yes. So you have to bear that in mind. It is not man in the
street stuff entirely here.
Q103 Stephen Barclay:
Just coming in on the bonus point, I think one of the drivers
for the high bonuses, we are told, is the fear that people will
exit the UK. I was just wondering whether the Treasury has asked
the banks for any data about the number of senior executives leaving
the UK.
Chair: Those earning over
£1 million a year, you mean?
Stephen Barclay: Whatever
level. Just to understand the problem with the banks.
Tom Scholar: We
have had quite a lot of examples and anecdotal evidence. We have
not got a systematic study.
Q104 Stephen Barclay:
We know HMRC is not tracking it, in response to FoI questions.
I was just wondering whether you had done any actual analysis
to see what the trend is and how real a problem it is.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
There is a wider set of issues around the incidence of taxation
and the impact of tax rates on labour mobility. We have had a
series of tax changes over the last year or two and I think it
is going to be very important to monitor the effects. Are they
actually going to raise revenue or is it going to displace labour,
which is inevitably more footloose at the high end than it was?
It is something we have to pay attention to.
Q105 Stephen Barclay:
It would just be good to have data on that. I think what flows
from that is one of the points that sometimes can be made to constituents:
if someone is getting a very high bonus, they are paying a high
rate of tax. But were you very concerned given the UBS caseand
not least that the current head of UKFI was at UBS at the timefor
which they have just paid a big fine for tax avoidance? Are you
satisfied that HMRC, which reports into a Treasury Minister, has
the right resources focused on potential tax avoidance?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I cannot give you chapter and verse around how HMRC is managed,
but I think Dave Hartnett, the Permanent Secretary for Tax
at HMRC, is fully appraised of the challenge here and we do have
a regular dialogue with him.
Q106 Chair:
I want to move us on a little bit, if I can, to the annual financing
costs, which is another issue raised. The Report claims that
the cost to us of just financing all this investment is about
£5 billion. There does not appear to be transparency of
it in terms of showing it as a cost for the stabilisation programme.
I just wondered whether you were thinking of putting that right.
The Report also says that in the coming year, it will not be
covered by the income you get from fees and charges, so what are
you doing to try to ensure at least that that is covered?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
We are certainly open to suggestions on this. We have tried to
be very transparent about the direct cost of the interventions,
and I think that is reflected in this Report. Making a calculation
of the implicit interest rate paid on the borrowing to finance
this does require a certain amount of estimation; there are not
a certain amount of gilts out there about which we can say, "Yes,
those are the bits that were financing the banking interventions".
So I think the NAO acknowledges that this is a by-and-large estimate.
Normally when the Treasury spends money on something else, we
do not add on the implicit interest rate charge, but I do take
the point that we have had to borrow more as a result of these
interventions and I would be happy to take away that point. No
doubt we will need to respond to your Report in due course.
Q107 Chair:
Can I ask you another general question? We have a lot of schemes
here. We have one scheme that you were thinking of launching
called the assetbacked securities guarantee scheme, whatever
that was, and it never got off the ground. Did we need that many?
Did we need them all? Are there some that you feel on reflection
you might not have bothered with? Are there some that worked
better than others?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Well I think these reports are very helpful and inevitablythis
is the point I made last weeksome of the interventions
we had to come up with very quickly indeed. The credit guarantee
scheme was invented really over the course of a weekend. On some
interventions like the special liquidity scheme you had invested
more time in before they were announced. But we were responding
to a very severe crisis and inevitably you were testing the market.
Your point about the mortgage scheme where take-up was zero is
a very good case in point. There was this view that there was
a market failure out there and that banks could not raise finance
for supplying mortgages. The Treasury came up with a scheme,
no doubt influenced by the work of this Committee and others.
We did not want to provide this service for free, and then the
banks obviously took a look at it and decided they could raise
the money elsewhere more cheaply, which is why they did not resort
to us. Now coming back to the earlier part of the conversation,
the dust has not settled yet. We are not out of these schemes;
we are reviewing them as we go along. But when it is all over,
I hopethis may fall to my successorswe will produce
a manual about what works and what does not work in a banking
crisis. Some of this is still in our collective heads, but we
need to save it for posterity. Inevitably, the next banking crisis
will not be like this. One of the risks in the coming period
is that we all spend our time trying to refight the last war,
doing lots of things that make perfectly good sense in relation
to the last crisis, but actually make no sense whatsoever in relation
to future crises. One thing is for certain: there will be future
bubbles. Fear is in the market at the moment, but greed usually
wins out in the end. So we need to be ready for whatever lies
ahead.
Andrew Bailey:
I do not think I can say anything as eloquent as that. I do think
the point is right about being prepared for other wars than the
one we have just fought. I must have done something wrong in
a past life, because I have been involved in bank resolution for
about 20 years now and although we did not, of course, support
Barings, we were involved behind the scenes. If you take a Barings
thing, it is a completely different scenario from the one we have
been going through for the last three and a half years. So that
is a fairly stark illustration of Nick's point, which is that
we must be ready to fight a different war next time because it
will not be alike.
Q108 Stella Creasy:
Surely the best form of defence is attack. What are you doing
to avoid the next banking crisis? If we have seen the impact
on taxpayers so far in some of the costs we are talking about
today, it is quite worrying that you are already saying, "Well,
this will happen again." It will happen in a different format,
I accept, but what are you doing to avoid some of those problems?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
We are doing an extraordinary amount. Huge swathes of officials,
both in the UK and elsewhere, are doing little else other than
designing new systems and there is a lot of international co-operation
going on. The Government is going to introduce a pretty big Bill
reforming financial regulation. It is always tempting to think
that this is going to solve it this time, but
Q109 Stella Creasy:
That is good to hear; it is just that it stands slightly against
some of the measures you are talking about now as the resolution
for this financial crisis. For example, you are looking primarily
at selling the shares and at what point you sell them. Some of
us who come from a co-operative background would like to see the
Government exploring mutualisation and perhaps looking at some
of the longer, more substantial stabilising measures that you
could put in that would answer some of the concerns that Mr Bailey
put about the tension between recouping the public purse and a
more stable situation. What work have you done on those kind
of ideas?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Well we have looked quite extensively at mutualisation and we
certainly do not want to rule it out.
Q110 Stella Creasy:
Well obviously selling the shares and being concerned about the
share price, as the UKFI is primarily, as you said earlier, would
rather preclude it.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
That is one consideration. If we concluded that turning the RBS
into a giant co-operative was a sensible way forward, we would
no doubt recommend it. We have looked at it, because we have
received a lot of representations, in particular in relation to
Northern Rock, about options around mutualisation and I certainly
do not want to rule it out. There have been some pretty ropey
mutuals. Indeed, Andrew had to deal with one of them fairly recently.
Q111 Stella Creasy:
But they have on the whole performed better over the course of
the last
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Some have. We have a real interest in diversity in the sector
and we want to see strong mutuals just as we want to see strong
plcs. Ideally, none of them should depend either explicitly or
implicitly on the taxpayer.
Q112 Stella Creasy:
So there would be a case, therefore, for perhaps widening the
remit of what the UKFI is looking at to take into account that
point about public benefit?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I think your point should apply to the Treasury. The Treasury
needs to look at that. I think the risk about diluting UKFI's
focus is that it does need clarity. If they are focusing on the
shareholders' interest, we can then rely on the Treasury, no doubt
consulting the Bank of England, to look at the bigger picture.
Q113 Stella Creasy:
But we are all shareholders.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
We are all shareholders and that is why it is very important.
Q114 Chair:
Amyas wanted to come in quickly.
Amyas Morse: Despite
all the things about not fighting the last war and all that sort
of stuff, there has been some very valuable experience garnered
and we are now beginning to see a bit of a changing of the guard.
So I hope we are going to do things about capturing and preserving
knowledge. That is a question but also a statement.
Andrew Bailey:
We certainly are, if I could start on that one. One of the very
good, key things that has been started in the last year is what
I think was originally called living wills for banks and is now
called recovery and resolution plans, rather more prosaically
but probably a bit more accurately. This is now being embedded
into the system of supervising banks, because it is very important
when we supervise banks, as a number of us have said, that this
must not be a no-failure regime. This comes back to where we
started this session this morning. It is important that the system
of supervision embeds into it how you deal with a bank when it
gets into trouble. That is one of the big lessons out of this
crisis. It is rather obvious in a way, but it is a very big lesson.
As Nick said earlier, we have got a resolution regime that we
did not have when Northern Rock happened and that was a big part
of the Northern Rock problem, but we are now busy designing a
system of supervision that embeds into it how you deal with a
bank when it gets itself into serious trouble.
Amyas Morse: Forgive
me, but just to press for a second, it is a bit wider waterfront
than that in the experiences. That is important, but what about
the experience that the Treasury team has had of living through
this alongside yourselves? Are you going to transfer that knowledge
in some sustainable way?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I have always been very focused on how the Treasury can retain
knowledge. One of the challenges for the Treasury is that there
is fairly rapid staff turnover. That is part of the Treasury's
business model; you want to attract young, enthusiastic, bright
people whom you probably are not going to be able to retain in
the medium term, because we cannot pay the wages, and you need
to retain enough people who have a bit of a folk memory. I am
very lucky; I think we were, Andrew, working together at the time
of the Barings crisis, so I can remember that. I can also remember
working through previous recessions. But there are not huge numbers
of people who have that experience, so we are working very hard
to instil deeper knowledge management. Indeed, one of the reasons
why the quality of the papers you have has improved with each
successive Report is that we have an extremely effective knowledge
manager, who I think is sitting behind me. There are lessons
there. We are getting better and we need to distil this for
future generations.
Q115 Joseph Johnson:
A bit on the knowledge management and corporate memory in the
Treasury point. In the late 1980s, when Nigel Lawson lowered
the top rate of tax to 40p, he found that yields went up, ironically.
We have gone in the other direction and we have raised the top
rate of tax to 50p again. Have you changed, or are you in the
process of changing, your estimate of what the marginal increase
in the top rate of tax from 40 to 50 will yield this tax year?
I think Labour scored £2.7 billion against it.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
That is a very interesting point. Indeed, I co-ordinated the
Budget during the Nigel Lawson era. Now costing is a matter for
the independent Office for Budget Responsibility and so we will
be ultimately relying on its estimates, but I would expect the
evidence base to expand as we go through this year, because bear
in mind these changes are only beginning to take effect. Even
compared to 1988, global integration has increased considerably
and there are risks with tax rates that as you push them up, you
get behavioural responses.
Q116 Joseph Johnson:
And of the 230,000 or so 50p rate payers, how many are bankers
and working in financial services? How effectively have we targeted
the community that got us into this problem with this higher rate?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I cannot give you the answer off hand, but I think quite a lot
of these people are in the financial sector.
Q117 Chair:
That is a really interesting question. Have you got that?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I would be happy to see if we have data on the occupations of
top-rate taxpayers.
Chair: Which would enable
us to look at that? That would be really interesting.
Q118 Austin Mitchell:
If you are going to consider remutualisation, you should look
at the Halifax. It would be good to have all those signs saying
"Lloyds Banking Group" taken down around Halifax. However,
that is not my question. The question is as follows. You have
passed these interest shares over to UK Financial Investments
Limited, which is presumably another quango. Very naughty, but
having done that, you want it to behave like an institutional
investor. Now institutional investors, like the big pension funds,
can influence bonus policy, for instance, by voting against the
remuneration report. Is it envisaged that UK Investments will
be enabled by the Treasury to vote against the remuneration reports
of any of the banks it is invested in?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Yes, it certainly can, and my understanding is that it has been
quite active in this particular market. If you are as big an
investor as UKFI, in a sense to get to the point where there is
an open vote at an annual general meeting is a sign of failure,
because you ought to be able to exert your influence before you
get there. Tom, do you want to expand on that?
Tom Scholar: UKFI
did in fact vote against the remuneration report of RBS in 2009
because it did not agree with what had been done in relation to
the pension of the departing chief executive.
Q119 Austin Mitchell:
So they are not emasculated?
Tom Scholar: No.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
No.
Q120 Chair:
Did that change the remuneration package, then?
Tom Scholar: I
am afraid not.
Q121 Chair:
They are emasculated. Thank you very much indeed. That was a
really helpful session, so my thanks to all of you. I just wanted
to end on this. Amyas asked you about getting the lessons and
you said you were looking at that. Have you a time frame in which
you will be able to publish a document or report on what you think
we have captured out of the interventions we have done so far?
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
I haven't got a time frame. It would be nice to do it when we
have sold the shares, but I recognise that could still be some
time off, so there may be a case for an interim report.
Q122 Stephen Barclay:
Paragraph 19.3 refers to an interim and then the formal.
Sir Nicholas Macpherson:
Yes. We are thinking very hard about this and in light of this
discussion, I would be happy to expedite our decision on that
point.
Chair: Thank you very
much indeed.
1 See response to Q64 below and para 1.8 & 1.14
of the NAO report Maintaining the financial stability of UK banks:
update on the support schemes (HC667) Back
|