Transport and the economy - Transport Committee Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 1-46)

Q1 Chair: Good morning, gentlemen. Would you like to identify yourselves for our records, please? Could I start at this end?

  Professor Henry Overman: Henry Overman from the London School of Economics.

  Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: Alan Wenban-Smith, Urban & Regional Policy, Birmingham City University.

  Professor John Tomaney: John Tomaney, Newcastle University.

Q2 Chair: Thank you very much. The last major study into transport and the economy was the Eddington report in 2006. Do you feel that that report is still relevant today?

  Professor Henry Overman: Yes, I think it is. My take on this is that we are richer than we were when Eddington was being written, even if the growth rate has been lower than during the time of Eddington. The decisions that Eddington was looking at were about the long-term impact in transport in this country, and I don't see that much has changed. I think the emphasis on gateways, inter-urban corridors, relieving congestion, still stands. I think the advice to be realistic about the benefits and not commit yourself right at the beginning to one particular mode of transport, as the solution to all your problems, is correct. So basically, I think that the recommendation still stands.

Q3 Chair: Any comments, Professor Wenban-Smith?

  Professor Wenban-Smith: I have a slightly more sceptical view, in the sense that I think Eddington's priorities were correct, dealing with the problems of conurbations, of inter-urban corridors and international gateways. But the trouble is, the actual priorities, in terms of schemes, depended on a system of cost-benefit analysis that has been very heavily criticised and I think, in many ways and respects, is quite misleading. It was also made in the context of road-user pricing being part of the package. Eddington himself would describe that as a no-brainer. Without road-user pricing, his priorities would inevitably lead to more congestion as people take advantage of the additional road space to spread themselves further over the landscape, which is what tends to happen. So I think Eddington's priorities are fine but the actual list of schemes that descends from that is much more doubtful.

Q4 Chair: So you don't think the absence of road pricing, and less economic growth than predicted, has a material effect on his recommendations?

  Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: No; on the contrary. I am saying that, without road pricing, Eddington's priorities would lead to more congestion, more dispersion, more CO2 production, and so on. It would be less good for the economy without road pricing.

Q5 Chair: Thank you. Professor Tomaney, do have any views on Eddington and how we should see it today?

  Professor John Tomaney: Yes. I largely agree with Eddington's essential analysis that there is a relationship between transport connectivity and economic growth. I think what has changed is the economic conditions, quite markedly. They have changed in terms of the lower overall level of growth—as Henry has already pointed out—and I think that is significant. Economic conditions have changed, in that there are clearly going to be less resources available for major transport investments.

In addition, I would like to draw attention to what I think may prove to be one significant development. That is that the current economic conditions have had a very distinctive geography attached to them. We've seen the recession having a bigger impact in the north and in the south. In thinking about the future of transport investments, that should obviously be part of any serious consideration, especially given that we now have a Government who are committed to rebalancing the national economy away from an alleged over-dependence on financial services in the south-east of England. The role of transport in all of that, if we take the essential premise of Eddington, is going to be critical to achieving that objective, so I think some things have changed.

Q6 Chair: So what lessons would you draw from that? Is there any particular type of transport investment that should be supported, rather than another one?

  Professor John Tomaney: There are many kinds of transport investments that ought to be supported, but I think critical would be those that support the improvement of urban transport systems and the connectivity of city regions, particularly in areas like the north of England—say, between Leeds and Manchester—which raise the possibility of the development or the agglomeration of further economic activities in the north and may play a part in rebalancing the national economy, if that's the key policy objective.

Q7 Chair: Should investment go into new schemes rather than maintaining existing ones? Is there a choice to be made there?  

Q8 Professor Henry Overman: I think there is a choice to be made. That is a question that is not sensible to try and answer in a general sense. This is one of the crucial lessons from Eddington that I just see slipping further and further away from us, which is that we need to be making these decisions on a project-by-project basis. So there will be some new investment that clearly, given where we are with public expenditure, should not be being made. There are projects that were on the books that we could easily be ditching. Likewise, there is some recurrent expenditure on existing commitments that we are compelled to get rid of. But the idea that somehow we can—in the abstract—make a decision between the balance of these two things I think is just impossible. We need people who know what the projects are delivering to be making these decisions on a project-by-project basis, not on an overall broad abstract basis.

  Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: I might be able to add a bit to that. I should say I'm not a proper professor; I'm not an academic, I'm not an economist. My credentials are very much having been a local government officer responsible for exactly the sorts of things you have been talking about: transport planning in places like Birmingham and Newcastle, as it happens. This kind of question, the balance between new projects and maintaining what you have is very difficult and very important. It deals with one of your questions later on about the balance between revenue and capital projects. There is a huge volume of revenue spending necessary to keep the existing stock in good heart and doing its job. At the margin, the question of whether you can better spend the money by investing in a new project, that has capital charges spent over a long period of time, is something that, as I think Henry said, is not something for a general judgment. It's something you need to make as a judgment in the circumstances of your particular patch.

  I used to be chairman of the Chief Engineers and Planning Officers Group of the West Midlands and what we did was to put together our programme of balance, small, large and revenue schemes, and it cannot be done from Whitehall would be my view.

  

Q9 Kwasi Kwarteng: This is a double-barrelled question. We have all read the Eddington report and my understanding is that he is very, as you say, focused on project-by-project and looking at where the difficulties are, and then trying to solve those, as opposed to having these blue sky grand projects. Surely there is scope for these big projects that the Government have. I take an extreme example. Before we had aeroplanes. Once aeroplanes were invented, clearly, there would be a decision to build an airport. There is no way you can do a cost-benefit analysis of that, if you haven't had any experience of what aeroplanes could do. That's an extreme case. I am not saying something like that is going to happen any time soon. But surely there is some scope for thinking outside this sort of project-by-project, what I might call a nodal focus on particular problems and solving those in a book-keeping kind of way. Do you have any thoughts on that?

  Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: Sorry; you may have misunderstood what I said. I didn't mean that every decision must be done on a sort of—

  

Q10 Kwasi Kwarteng: No, sorry, I am not asking a question on what you said. I'm asking a general question.

  Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: Okay, perhaps some of my colleagues would like to—

  Professor John Tomaney: I think there is international evidence that strategic investments in big transport infrastructure can have economic development impacts. We can find that sort of evidence around the world. We're finding it particularly in the newly industrialising countries at the moment. There is plenty of evidence of that. These arguments are certainly being deployed in the north of England, for instance. The future of Teesport and its disconnection from national transport networks; the relative difficulty of getting goods in and out of the port to markets in other parts of the UK has been emphasised as a lost opportunity, in that sense. There are opportunities to make investments in that port, which potentially relieve burdens on infrastructure in the south, but they're not going to be justified probably using traditional cost-benefit analysis. On the contrary, when those methods are applied, then these sorts of investments are shown not to have a sufficient return. I think your point is a fair one but, nevertheless, there is no general rule I think; that would be my view on this. The decisions that are taken in the end are often strategic, political ones rather than narrowly economic ones, in that sense.

  Professor Henry Overman: One of the problems is that people tend to take their pet project and basically try to justify support for it, on the basis that it will be transformational, and many of these claims for projects that will be transformational do not materialise once we go ahead and invest large amounts of money. I was in Hull; the Humber Bridge was supposed to transform the economy of that part of the world. If you go back and look at the narrative, that is what it was going to do and it didn't. I still think there is a strong argument for thinking about the main benefits of transport being from: how many people are going to use it, how much faster, safer and environmentally friendly their journeys are going to be. Sometimes that might be terribly hard to predict for something new but, at the end of the day, the benefits of the airports do come from people who use them.

  Kwasi Kwarteng: You could not possibly model that; that is my point. At some level, you have to have a strategic decision.

  Professor Henry Overman: I think this is right. In the time I have been on Eddington, advising DfT and High Speed 2 afterwards, the point I have consistently made to them is that our understanding of those wider economic benefits is still limited. The rush to bolt it all into the traditional cost-benefit analysis rather misses the point that, at some level, we need to be making strategic decisions about this, and then using the cost-benefit analysis to help inform those strategic decisions, plus other forms of evidence on those things. I do think a mistake that DfT made was to rush to try and incorporate all of those things into its formal appraisal process, which I believe has probably added more noise than signal in the process.

Q11 Chair: So what you are saying is that you are agreeing there is a need for strategic decisions and they need some provision, but that can't always be accommodated in the formula that we have?

  Professor Henry Overman: I think formal cost-benefit analysis remains a good check on the extent of the claims that are being made for things. We may well then decide that other evidence that we have—particularly for some big decisions—says, "Well look, we're just going to overrule this". But still, looking at how many people we think are going to use it, how much faster their journey is going to be, how much more environmentally friendly and how much safer, is still a useful cross-check to be done. We then may want some process for making strategic decisions where that is one part of the information set that we use.

Q12 Kwasi Kwarteng: Just to clarify, what you are saying is that we shouldn't solely use cost-benefit analysis nor should we solely go on this sort of big picture, strategic decision making, but we should somehow use them in tandem. Is that what you are saying?

  Professor Henry Overman: I think, particularly for larger schemes that are going to be very expensive, cost-benefit analysis forms part of the set of information that you would gather to make a strategic decision.

  Chair: Is it on this?

Q13 Angela Smith: It is on that question. The statement you have just made, I think helps clarify things a little, because I was beginning to think that perhaps you were recommending an approach that is reactive in many ways, which will continue to intensify the regional disparities that we suffer from in this country in terms of economic performance. Perhaps you would like to comment on that, Professor Overman.

  Professor Henry Overman: I take it this way. Let's take High Speed 2; let's take a concrete example to motivate the discussion here. I think, broadly speaking, the evidence that High Speed 2 will lead to a reduction in disparity is pretty limited. Taking the evidence that we have, which is the cost-benefit analysis—which delivers pretty low benefits to costs for High Speed 2—plus the wider evidence that people bring to bear, which seems to me to make a series of claims about benefits of High Speed that I don't think stack up. So then, let's offset that against going to Manchester, Leeds, Newcastle, Bristol and doing investments in those cities, so focusing on identifying a whole group of intra-urban transport. I think, if we looked at that carefully, we would find that the broad suite of evidence that we bring to bear would be much more favourable to those intra-urban projects than it would be to High Speed 2. You set out your objective—

  

Q14 Chair: You are illustrating that, which is helpful to us, but you're also making an assumption about choices there. Professor Tomaney, do you want to comment on this?

Professor John Tomaney: I broadly agree with Henry on the point that the evidence that HS2 will have a positive impact on rebalancing the national economy, to use the current jargon, is not really there. I think the international evidence suggests that, where you make these big investments in this kind of infrastructure—particularly high speed train networks—as important to the investment in the infrastructure itself is investment in the conditions of the nodes around the lines that stimulate economic benefit and economic development. There is some evidence from European high speed train systems, and from Asian high speed train systems, that this is a critical ingredient, and in the debates around HS2 I haven't really seen that discussed. This points to the need for understanding transport in a wider economic development context, rather than just simply a single investment designed to have an immediate impact.

Q15 <Julian Sturdy: My point is following on from what we have been talking about. I agree with the comments about pet projects. I have been a local councillor and seen that in action in the Department for Transport. So I think you make some very good points there. In the wider context, is it possible to say what types of transport schemes have the largest benefit on the economy? I am not talking regionally; I'm talking nationally here as well to try and get away from this pet project argument.

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: I think the important thing is to get away from the proposition that transport benefits are the only benefit that matters. We tend to talk in terms of user time savings, accident savings, operating costs, that kind of thing. The important effects on the economy are knock-ons from that, or indeed quite independent of that in some ways.

To my mind, one of the things that would make the biggest difference to the national economy, in terms of transport, would be investing heavily in public transport systems in our big cities, because it is strikingly clear that we've failed to do that for 50 years now. If you look at continental Europe, and cities of similar size to Birmingham and Newcastle—cities I've done a lot of work in—their productivity, relative to the national level, is streets above our UK experience. I think it is down to the failure to take advantage of a lot of people in a relatively limited space, which good public transport is absolutely critical to. You don't need to look further than London to see the productivity benefits of having good public transport. To my mind, that is something truly transformational that we could and should do and we've failed to do.

Q16 <Kelvin Hopkins: This is interesting because I thought I was in a tiny minority of HS2 sceptics. The opportunity costs of producing this railway line, which would save a tiny amount of time between major cities, as opposed to investing in improvements elsewhere, I think is considerable and I am glad to hear what you have had to say. Is it not the case, that if we could get some of the freight off the existing main lines, dedicate them to fast rather than high speed passenger, we would do much better? I am thinking of 140 mile an hour working on the east coast main line, with a couple of loops and quadrupling the track at Welwyn, to solve the problem on that side of the country; 135 mile an hour working on west coast main line with, again, some improvements to overcome those problems, and a dedicated freight line that takes all the freight off. That seems to me a much more sensible approach than HS2.

Professor John Tomaney: I'm not a railway engineer so I'm going to pass on that.

Q17 <Chair: We're not having an inquiry today into HS2 but it is relevant to some of these issues. Can we consider the general issue—which I think you have answered—about looking at local improvements as well the major schemes? In today's situation, with all the economic problems here, how important do you think it is to look at local improvements on schemes, whether they be rail schemes or other schemes? How significant are they in terms of the economy? That is the question that we are looking at here.

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: My view, having had the responsibility of bringing together transport, economic planning and spatial planning in real places, is: it is absolutely crucial that those things are joined together. It is a real problem achieving that level of integration. We did it for a while in the West Midlands but sadly it petered away because there are separate cultures, separate Whitehall silos that each department relates to, and it is very difficult to get that connection. We did, in fact, produce an integrated transport policy. We had it agreed in government that we would have one bag of money, not six different bags. It didn't survive the onslaught of the civil servants, I'm afraid. They took the view that these are separate pockets of money, even though they are in one pair of trousers, worn by the Minister.

Q18 <Paul Maynard: Professor Overman was mentioning earlier about the need to make strategic decisions, to look not just on cost-benefit analyses but on additional measures. What role do you think national policy statements could have in improving the quality of decision making, and how would the national policy statements themselves need to be improved as a tool of good public policy? Following on from that, given they are national policy statements and given the abolition of the regional development agencies and the statutory functions of the regional local government leaders boards, how do you see the regional voice of transport priority making now taking place? How is that going to occur or how could it occur, given we seem to have a blank sheet at the moment?

Professor John Tomaney: If I take the last point first, I think you've identified a really big issue. We're replacing the regional spatial strategies, which were an attempt to integrate some of these questions, which Alan has just mentioned: land use, transport, economic development planning. They were flawed in some ways but they were an effort to do that. We have certainly seen the end of those but we're potentially facing a situation of the creation of Local Enterprise Partnerships, of which I think, at the latest count, there are some 56 proposed. I think that there are some big issues about how they're going to operate, because, in principle, they are entitled to bid for transport powers for their local area. My reading is that very few of the Local Enterprise Partnership proposals contain very specific suggestions, in relation to transport and in relation to the kinds of powers that they would like to exercise, although the Secretary of State, Mr Pickles, says that they potentially can have whatever powers they want.

Taking my region, one scenario would be that you would have a multiplicity of small Local Enterprise Partnerships covering part of the region where you can very readily identify the spillovers, in terms of transport planning, from one place to the next. At the moment there is no mechanism for resolving the potential tensions. So, for instance, in Tyne and Wear you have potentially three Local Enterprise Partnerships and yet the urban transport system—the Tyne and Wear Metro—running through all three of those. What will the mechanisms be for ensuring a rational use of resources in relation to public transport in these areas? These are huge open questions. You have identified an important issue but I don't know the answer to them, I'm afraid.

Professor Henry Overman: I broadly support the move to LEPs but I think there are two things they are not set up to do very well: the inter-urban transport schemes that have impacts on the wider environment, and housing decisions. I think in many circumstances, with the larger inter-urban schemes, it's hard to see—in areas where the LEPs are fragmented across the area that is going to be affected by the scheme—how they will reach a decision on this. I think it will have to go back to the DFT with input from the Local Enterprise Partnerships.

Q19 <Chair: It doesn't seem to quite fit with the localism agenda, does it?

Professor Henry Overman: There are a bunch of decisions that you will be able to push down to LEPs, which will be the perfectly appropriately vehicle for making them. But LEPs are not the vehicle for making decisions about inter-urban corridor investments, for example. Those will just have to come back to the centre with input from the affected Local Enterprise Partnership.

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: It is absolutely right. Subsidiarity cuts two ways. Certainly it is very important to devolve appropriate decisions, so that things can be joined up better, but there are some decisions that necessarily have to be taken at national level: national corridors, the balance between regions, for example. It's very bad for the UK, as a whole, for regions to be grossly unequal and that's something that is absolutely inalienably a national responsibility.

Q20 <Paul Maynard: I have a specific question, about whether national policy statements were an appropriate vehicle to achieve that regional rebalancing and whether they are working well at the moment and, if not, how they could be improved?

Chair:> We have had a national policy statement on ports and it is very unclear quite where that is going. We are waiting for national policy statements on national networks. No mention has been made of that since May, so we don't know what is happening with that one. Do you think this is an important concept in developing transport and for the economy?

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: It potentially could be and should be. The only example I have is the national policy statements on energy but these were missing any kind of sub-national dimension at all. I remember asking Ed Miliband, when he was Secretary of State, "If generation is going to be wherever it needs to be, because that is where the wind and the tide is and the structure of industry is changing, so consumption is going to be wherever that ends up, how come you can have a national policy statement that doesn't say anything about the potential of the mismatch between these things?" He said, "Good question. I don't know the answer".

Professor Henry Overman: At the very minimum, I think what they will need to do is to set out the rules of the game for all these LEPs that are going to be making decisions. That will be an important role for national policy, to make it clear to the Local Enterprise Partnerships, or whoever is making these decisions, what the framework is within which they are going to be making them. So I do think that national guidelines here will need to move away from saying, "We think you should do that" to, "Here is the broad framework within which we think you should be making these decisions". So we tell people what we are going to do about carbon pricing, so that they know how they need to be taking that into account when they are making their local decisions.

I would see us moving towards those things, trying to set the frameworks within which decisions are made, rather than saying, "We think we're going to do this port here and that port there". Although there will still need to be some decisions along those lines where these are big national decisions. But generally speaking, I think they are about the framework, setting the framework within which these decisions need to be made, rather than giving very explicit guidance for the decisions.

Q21 <Chair: Professor Tomaney, do you have any views on this?

Professor John Tomaney: I think what we're talking about is where the limits to localism lie and the extent to which central Government are prepared to draw limits around what localism can do. The rhetoric from Government at the moment is that there will be no limit to localism, as I understand it—reading the speeches from Ministers—but, as my colleagues are pointing out, there are practical limits to localism. One is that Local Enterprise Partnerships are very small but don't represent functional economic regions. Some of them do but many of them don't. There will inevitably be a situation where Government have to come in and resolve difficulties, spillovers between different jurisdictions, if you like. Then there are big questions; carbon pricing is a good example, or about investment in capacity in renewable energies, and so on, that Government will have to be clear about. I think at the moment that isn't part of what we're hearing from Government, but I suspect that perhaps dragged kicking and screaming it will have to be part of Government policy.

Q22 <Iain Stewart: In a way you've touched on the question I wanted to ask, and that is to introduce the "who pays" element into who shapes the strategic objectives and prioritises the specific schemes? What is your view of the mix between public investment from general taxation, business-led private investment and the user contribution? From those three broad categories, who should be the one that drives the choices that we have to make?

Professor John Tomaney: It would seem to me that the likely mix of these is going to differ quite radically around the country. There are already significant private contributions to big infrastructures in London, for instance, or at least resources raised at a local level. It is very much more difficult to see how significant private investments in major infrastructure will occur in, say, the north of England. There may be possibilities in relation to, for example, Manchester, but in many other northern cities the scope for significant private investment seems to me to be much more limited than it would be in the south of England. So I think that is a crucial point.

The same would also be true of user charges. The capacity of northern towns to generate significant user charges, I think, is obviously going to be a lot less than is the case in the south. If we're moving in the direction of more user contributions, a greater role for private investment in this process, then we're probably going to see very increased regional differences in the provision of the transport infrastructure.

Chair:> Mr Stewart, do you want add anything?

Iain Stewart: No. I'm interested in the other panellists' views.

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: I think it is very important that there is a connection between who pays and who makes decisions. It is a bit artificial saying, "We are going to localise decision making but all the money is going to come from centre". That doesn't work in my opinion. You have to find some way of raising the money more locally, whether or not it's from users—and that is obviously potentially a major target if you move towards road user pricing in all sorts of different forms. But there are other means—such as tax increment financing; land value taxation—of supporting local infrastructure investment. Those would all make a lot of sense, and it would give a lot more muscle and purpose to the whole spatial planning system if those were part and parcel of it.

At present, the ways of getting money out of developers are pretty accidental in their incidence. Some local authorities are very good at it; some are very bad at it. It is almost a lottery and you get a lot of free riders. There are real problems about that. As John Tomaney said, it means that parts of the country that may need infrastructure at least are able to get the money from that kind of source to support it. It's a mess. I think we'd be much better off moving towards local sources of finance of the sort I have mentioned, and much more responsibility for local raising as well as spending of that money.

Q23 <Chair: Professor Overman, would you like to comment on this?

Professor Henry Overman: Broadly speaking, I agree that we need to have the people who are making the decision on this more closely connected to the financing of it. Inter-urban versus intra-urban has always been an issue. To use High Speed 2 as an example again, if you are—

Q24 <Chair: Can we have another example as well?

Professor Henry Overman: If you are Manchester, Leeds and Birmingham local authorities I can see why you think that High Speed 2 is a fantastically good idea. If we think about where the benefits of that are going to be, they are going to be in those areas, whereas at the moment how we are going to pay for it is left rather vague. I assume potentially quite a lot of this will come from public expenditure; whereas, if you think about the intra-urban schemes, a much larger chunk of this potentially falls on the local authorities affected. That provides a skew on decision making that is more general. This is always the claim that was made for buses over light rail, for example. Financing things does create rather large distortions in the decision-making process.

Q25 <Chair: What conclusions do you reach then, in answer to the question, on the implications of methods of financing for decision making on investment?

Professor Henry Overman: I think I am in line with what the others have said. We have to try and extract the user benefits as much as possible. That includes people who get uplift on their land values, but also the people using it, so those seem to be two ready sources that we'd need to be extracting from. This is why I'm in favour of road pricing. Then we need to make the decision on the balance depending on the context of the project.

Q26 <Kelvin Hopkins: Isn't there a striking contrast between Britain and continental Europe in all transport, in that we have privatised and fragmented our railway system; we have privatised and deregulated our buses? Organising integrated, planned transport systems, when that is the situation, is much more difficult.

  Wasn't it the case that in Tyne and Wear, for example, they were just about to get an effective integrated bus and local rail system and it was all privatised and it fell apart? Isn't there a lesson for us all in this? Indeed if we looked at the one project where major private finance was involved, the PPP on the Tube, this turned out to be an expensive disaster. Indeed on a recent visit to SNCF, SNCF has said, "Yes in France when we say 'PPP', we mean public, public, public".

Chair:> So what is the role of private funding for economically beneficial transport schemes?

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: I would step back a little bit further from Mr Hopkins' question, because I think what he is saying—maybe I am misinterpreting here—is that you need transport to be part of a bigger story about what we're trying to do. Tyne and Wear is very much a case in point. I was in charge of strategic planning in Tyne and Wear at the time and I remember it well. There is a problem there. When you fragment these things, you don't get the benefit.

What is interesting, I think, when you compare with continental Europe, they spend a lot more money on transport generally, both public and private transport: it is not either/or. I think it is no accident that they treat transport as part of the whole business of building their cities or building their countries, not as something separate, which is what we do. So they get a lot more support for transport spending, because it is much more broadly based. I think there is a lesson for us in that.

Q27 <Chair: Does the current thinking encompass wide enough benefits? Is it looking beyond the specific scheme?

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: Yes. It is about the question we started with, about the difference in the cost benefit of particular schemes, the bigger picture. I think what is critical of the bigger picture—and Henry has made the point very well—you get pet schemes supported for their transformational effects. It is like the iconic buildings that make me reach for a gun, I have to say. There is a need to have a line of logic connecting what you are going to do with the transport field, with the wider effect you are producing, and to adduce evidence about how those effects will work out. That is a much broader, more strategic kind of thing than cost-benefit analysis.

Q28 <Kwasi Kwarteng: I just wanted to clarify something. You are saying we should have a more strategic approach, as they have in continental Europe?

Professor John Tomaney: Can I just give an explanation on this? Privatisation and fragmentation are not necessarily the same thing. There is a great diversity in the mix of public and private in the provision of transport infrastructures across Europe and around the world. Privatisation can exist with integrated transport planning. There are many examples of that. Significant parts of the transport infrastructure in Sweden are privatised but there is a highly integrated transport planning system. The same could be said in Germany and the same could be said in Japan. So privatisation does not preclude integrated transport planning. It has done in this country but it is not the inevitable outcome.

Q29 <Julian Sturdy: Professor Wenban-Smith, you said something a few moments ago regarding developer contributions not working. I would just be interested in your views on that within your previous profession within local government and a local authority. It is something that I have seen regularly and it frustrates me. Personally, I think local authorities need to think longer term over section 106 funding and things like that, but do you think there should be any more powers for them to try and use the money better? Quite often there are time constraints over how they can use it, so they think short term rather than long term and that is causing problems.

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: It is a very bitty source of finance. It is almost accidental. All kinds of local site factors come in; it is about what you need to do to develop the site at all, and things of that nature. It is so constrained. I tried in Birmingham to get, for example, a levy from section 106 into a fund for building light rail.

Julian Sturdy: Absolutely, yes.

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: The legal advice was, "Yes, you can do it but it's going to be blooming difficult and you'll have to have some way of spending it in a much shorter term than you are likely to accumulate the relevant amounts of money". So there are real major difficulties about that.

I think there is a need for a different form of local finance. A community infrastructure levy was one such. I hold no candle for that in particular. Land value planning taxation seems an obvious one. It is very local and very specific. Various forms of development levy could be erected. There is always a difficulty about that, in that some places are enormously profitable to develop and other places struggle to develop at all; the incidence of the value you can get does not match the needs in any particular way. So it needs a serious look on a broader basis, and some equalising between places with different potential.

Professor Henry Overman: My feeling on section 106 is that a big part of the problem is that these are negotiated on a project-by-project, site-by-site basis. If you look in the area of housing, which has some interesting parallels here, a large number of local authorities raise zero effectively from section 106 agreements with developers. If you speak to housing developers the interesting thing is most of them are in favour of section 106 over anything else. I have always thought that should tell you pretty well everything you want to know about how well section 106 extracts development gains from the developers. So I think that a move to something that is more systematic, and relies less on the individual negotiating skills of the local authorities, probably is the thing that we will have to do if we want to extract more of this benefit. Again, I am not tied to one particular model. It seems to me there are many difficulties as you start to do that, but it does seem to me that section 106 has not achieved either in housing or in infrastructure development.

Q30 <Julian Sturdy: So there has to be some changing of the system?

Professor Henry Overman: I think generally we need to move away from the section 106. I think that it was nice, in the sense that it gave flexibility to negotiate locally what you might want to achieve but, in practice, it hasn't ended up extracting from developers the windfall benefits that they are accumulating as a result of planning decisions.

Q31 <Julian Sturdy: For the major projects?

Professor Henry Overman: I think for most projects. So I think there is a serious—

Julian Sturdy: Yes. It goes back probably to what you said about the pet projects, because it tends to go on to pet projects rather than major projects that can benefit the areas.

Q32 <Paul Maynard: You were speaking earlier about comparisons with Europe, which sounded quite interesting, and particularly the amount of extra money they are spending over there. Is that occurring at a sub-national level of government, those spending decisions and spending activities? Secondly, do the economic and social benefits derived from that extra transport spending match up to the amount of extra spending? Is it delivering value for money in your view?

  If you could take the example of the AVE network in Spain, my understanding was the decision was only taken to build that network, on the proviso that the Spanish regional governments constructed economic development plans that were considered to be credible by central Government before a decision was made to then go ahead with that network. How important do you believe the existence of credible economic development plans are before any decision is taken to go ahead with a project? Would it be wrong to wait and say, "Let's decide to go ahead with a project" and then, "Oh can we have an economic development plan too?" Is it not the case that one needs to precede the other for the full benefit of the transport spending to be obtained? That is a very long question, sorry.

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: Just starting with the continental experience, I think the level of decision making is very important. The German system, I think is particularly interesting, in that any particular major project is likely to have funding from the federal government, the Laender, the regional government and the locality. They negotiate a funding package between them, each of them having the objectives they want to see reflected in the final scheme. It is a very collaborative way of working.

  I'm particularly familiar with the system in Hanover that I visited a couple of times and it's enormously impressive. I've not seen any formal cost-benefit analysis of it but they spent a lot of money. It is an integrated exercise with rebuilding the city. To answer an earlier question, they did it with a thing called the Verkehrsverbund, which is a partnership of providers, who are usually private sector, who agree to operate it as an integrated system. All you can say is it works; it is enormously impressive. If you look at the German productivity per head of major cities, it is streets above the equivalent figures relative to the national productivity of UK cities and, I must say, I associate the two. I can't give you evidence to that effect but that is my opinion.

  You had a second question, which I have now lost.

  Professor John Tomaney: I think the first point to make is there is considerable variation in the structures of regional governments across Europe, so there isn't a continental model as such that we can point to. In your Spanish case, the powers of the Spanish regions are very extensive and have grown quite markedly over a relatively short period of time of about 20 or 30 years. It is quite correct to say that the major Spanish cities and regions did develop economic development plans in association with the arrival of the high speed train network, but it's also true to say that not all of them succeeded. A very good example—which Henry's colleague, Andrés Rodriguez-Pose, has written about—is the case of Seville, in which a huge amount of investment went into very large-scale developments that were intended to derive benefits from the arrival of the high speed train, and that hasn't been very successful.

  There are other examples around Europe where you could point to greater success. A good example would be southern Sweden, particular Malmo, which is, by Swedish standards, a disadvantaged region but it is also another region that is connected directly to the Copenhagen region by the Oresund bridge. Slowly, the economic benefits of that are becoming apparent in Malmo and there is a slow integration of the labour markets between prosperous Copenhagen and less prosperous Malmo using this transport link. For instance, Copenhagen airport becomes the airport for Malmo and the connectivity of Malmo, in that sense, is improved. You can find evidence both ways in Europe. There isn't a golden rule, I think, but in principle regional and local authorities have played a very key role in trying to develop structures that potentially extract the benefits of having these major infrastructures developed in their regions.

  You could point to some of the French cities as well, like Lyon, which could make the case that it has benefited from this as well.

Q33 <Chair: Professor Overman, do you want to add anything to those comments?

Professor Henry Overman: I'm always a sceptic on these things. I think part of the problem is that we look at these places; we see they're high density, living in flats and using lots of public transport, and we'd like our cities to be like that, despite the fact that the vast majority of our population want exactly the opposite from those things. There is a sense in which we want a transport system that delivers what people want, consistent with the other objectives around global warming, around carbon, and so on. I do think there is a tendency to look at continental Europe, look at it all being high density and public transport, thinking, "This is a fantastically good thing" and then imagining, "If only we could be like this".

  Chair: I think the issue behind this particular question is about economic development plans in the area concerned, so it is rather bigger than that.

  

Q34 <Iain Stewart: A thought came to me. The discussion we have been having is primarily about the traditional modes of transport that, as a country, we want to make. Looking into the medium and long term, how is technology going to change that, with fast broadband and video conferencing and all the developments that are going to happen? Are we still going to need, as a population, to move vast sections of us from home to work between 7.00 am and 9.00 am and then back home in the late afternoon, early evening? Are we going to have a complete step change in how we think about our transport planning as a result of new technology?

  Professor Henry Overman: For sure, we have a great track record of failing to predict the large shifts that are going to come, but I don't have any claim to be about to improve that track record for you. The thing we have consistently seen is that these claims about the fact that we will have flexible working and people will commute from home, and so on, those claims so far have proved to be broadly unfounded and the demand for transport has increased over time.

  The crucial thing it does highlight—which is something that I consistently push— is that, as much as possible, the sensible strategy is not to make the large, sunk, fixed cost things that Government do unless we absolutely have to. Something that we often see is this feeling that we have to make a decision one way or the other on these things. For example, this is why some people argue that designated bus routes may well be a better way of going, in a world of uncertainty, than fixed light rail. Those arguments are quite interesting. Of course, the problem is that they also highlight the car and personal forms of transport as being the ultimate in flexibility.

Q35 Chair: So are you saying you do not think that these technological changes are going to make a significant difference to transport needs?

  Professor Henry Overman: I'm just saying I don't know—

  Chair: You don't know?

Professor Henry Overman: No, I'm saying in a world where you don't know—

Q36 Chair: Does anybody else have any view on that? You don't have to say anything if you don't want to on that. Is this going to make a major difference to transport needs?

  Professor John Tomaney: I think these technologies contain the potential to transform the way we live and work but—as Henry says—the very least you could say is that progress, in the direction that you have just described, is very slow indeed, because there's lots of path dependency and sunk costs involved in the way we live our lives. In particular, one of the most difficult things to do, of course, is to change people's behaviours. Policy levers to do that are much more difficult to develop than the traditional kinds of policy levers, which involve providing infrastructure, and so on. It's possible that these things will have the impacts you are suggesting but there was that famous front page of The Economist, from a few years ago, that stated that "Lunch still matters". There is this propulsion for people to continue to work in the ways that they always have done. To bank on the kinds of changes that you are talking about, I think would be a big risk. Nevertheless, it could be that changes do move in those directions.

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: A lot of information is embodied in people and things and won't go down wires. We do, at higher levels, need to make face-to-face contact with people; there seems to be something about the human condition involved there. I should say I think technology change may be forced because oil prices are going to go very much higher in the not too distant future, leaving aside any questions of carbon output and all of that kind of thing. I think we are going to have to find some other ways of dealing with things. One of the things that seems to have gone away, and maybe it will come back again, is smart roads, roads that are much more wired up to interact with the vehicles on them, for example.

Q37 <Iain Stewart: I just want to come in, in terms of, particularly at the moment when we have significant pressure on public funds, to what extent should the Government choose—if there is a choice—between investing in increasing the transport capacity and perhaps investing in technology, rolling out superfast broadband, that might diminish the need to travel?

  Professor John Tomaney: There may be economic advantages to superfast broadband but it's not clear that, among them, is that it will diminish the propensity of people to travel. For instance, there is quite a large amount of fairly convincing academic evidence that information and communications technologies accelerate processes of agglomeration at a national scale. The technology is only as useful as the people who have the skills to use it and if those skills are concentrated in certain regions or cities, the introduction of these kinds of technologies can accelerate the growth of regional disparities. So there are lots of unintended consequences at work here that we need to very carefully consider.

Q38 <Kelvin Hopkins: The focus of transport discussion in Britain is always, it seems to me, on passengers. If we are talking about economic development, freight is a major component, or should be, and yet rail freight, in particular, the volume of freight, the proportion of freight that goes by rail is pathetic in Britain, simply because the capacity is not there. The capacity is not just about track; it's about gauge as well. We can't get road trailers on trains and we can't get full scale containers through many of our bridges and tunnels. I have a specific scheme I am involved with, but isn't there a case for significant investment in dedicated rail freight that would take freight off the motorways, off the north-south tracks and link all the conurbations with the Channel Tunnel?

  Professor John Tomaney: That sounds like a pet scheme.

  Kelvin Hopkins: I have the details if you want.

Q39 <Chair: Does anybody want to comment on rail freight?

  Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: I think it is partly a question of the distances. We're just a little twig of a rail network. In continental Europe, there's much longer distances and that suits rail haulage, the penalties of offloading and on loading at either end are much less severe, relative to the distances hauled. The real thing for rail freight would be to connect up our little twig better with the continental tree. Again, you're right, you have the gauge issue.

Q40 <Kelvin Hopkins: You have to have capacity to put trailers on trains and also put full size containers on trains.

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: The gauge issue, that's right. I agree.

Q41 <Chair: Does anyone else want to comment on rail freight?

  Professor Henry Overman: It is a good example of where I can refer you back to the very conversation we had at the beginning, which is that I would not want to say either way what I think, without looking at the specifics of the schemes and what the analysis says about the benefits of the cost ratio of it. The Northern Way, in its portfolio of projects that it has pushed on to its transport compact, does identify some expenditure targeted at freight that seems to deliver quite large benefit-cost ratios and we clearly should be doing those. Again, it is just so dangerous to go down this route of saying, "The issue is freight or the issue is high speed". I think there will be a number of freight investments that will be basically being supported, on the basis of being transformational, and very few of them will turn out to be so, whereas there will be some that look very good on the basis of reasonable projections about what we think would happen. I think we should be doing those.

  

Q42 <Angela Smith: I am not interested in the transformational but I am interested in dealing with what Eddington described in 2006, which is an analysis that suggests that the rise in cost of congestion will cost the UK economy something in the region of £22 billion by 2025. Isn't the overriding strategic objective, when it comes to transport, the need to ensure that we tackle that congestion effectively, that whatever we do is designed to make sure that we move goods and people as efficiently as possible to their markets? In order to do that, we have to sometimes understand that transport is not just reactive and based on users and cost ratios but also sometimes factors, such as the impact on congestion, and the impact on markets and labour and movement of goods—as Kelvin pointed out——is incredibly important.

  Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: There is a basic problem here, which is that if you put in new investment, particularly in roads where there's no price mechanism to counter that, it simply brings forth more demand, which may be producing perfectly worthwhile things but it is not a cure for congestion.

Q43 <Angela Smith: I am not talking about just roads. I am talking about public transport primarily, to be honest.

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: No indeed. It is a particular problem in roads because there isn't a price mechanism for controlling demand.

Q44 <Angela Smith: But I think Eddington was talking about dealing with road congestion and understanding that railways and bus networks have an important part to play in dealing with that congestion.

Q45 Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: The thing that always strikes me about rail congestion is that we carry round great chunks of fresh air called the first class section of trains. Half the train this morning was first class that had about three people in it. Why do we do that?

Professor Henry Overman: We do it because it allows the rail companies to make more money and reduces the public subsidy that we pay them, so let's be a bit careful here. These pricing structures do play some role in ensuring that we extract money from the users.

Chair:> We are looking at the importance of transport investment in the economy. Ms Smith has raised an issue. Does anyone want to answer that question?

Angela Smith: I am not talking about empty carriages. I am talking about the investment policy, the policy on the investment that we need to put in place, as UK plc, to ensure that goods and markets are as connected as possible, as efficiently as possible, and that labour is able to get to its place of work in order to improve productivity in the UK.

Chair: >Could I ask each of you then for your final comments, in response to Ms Smith's important question: what do you see as the key areas for transport investment to improve the economy, apart from looking strictly at cost-benefit analysis in the way that it has been put forward? Are there any specific things?

Professor John Tomaney: I think that the point that was raised by Mr Maynard, earlier on, about the way we think about the connections between transport infrastructure and economic development planning is critical. In the current environment of austerity there will be a real danger that we stop thinking about that connection, and that would be something that I would urge the Committee to consider.

Q46 <Chair: Thank you. What is the most important thing to you, Professor?

Professor Alan Wenban-Smith: I would agree entirely with that comment, and my view of that would lead you to the proposition that increasing productivity in the big cities is a major concern for regional balance, as well as output; public transport that makes them work properly.

Professor Henry Overman: Reducing congestion. Eddington identified it: reducing congestion in urban areas. It's absolutely clear that this is where the largest benefits are.

Chair:> Thank you very much for coming and answering so many questions.



 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 2 March 2011