Transport and the Economy - Transport Committee Contents


Written evidence from Dr David Metz (TE 56)

1.  This submission starts by considering the Committee's question: "Are the current methods for assessing proposed transport schemes satisfactory?" I argue that current methods are no longer fit for purpose and suggest a better approach which would result in different expenditure priorities.

METHODS FOR INVESTMENT APPRAISAL

2.  The conventional approach to appraising investment in schemes to improve the transport system focuses on the expected saving in travel time, which accounts for of the order of 90% of conventional monetarised benefits. Such time savings are supposed to be valuable to employers since more productive work is possible from employees, and to individuals since they are free to pursue other desirable activities. The monetarised benefits are set against the costs of a scheme in the cost-benefit analysis which plays a central role in the Department for Transport's (DfT) appraisal methodology, as employed also in the Eddington Report.

3.  The DfT's National Travel Survey (NTS) allows personal daily travel behaviour to be tracked since the early 1970s, as shown in the Figure (page 2). Over this period, the average number of trips has remained about 1,000 per person per year. Average travel time has also held steady and is currently about 370 hours per person per year, or an hour a day. It is evident that the large investment in transport infrastructure - £100 billion over the past twenty years at current prices - has not resulted in time savings. Rather, the benefit has been taken, in the long run, in the form of increased access, as seen by the greater distance travelled, from 4,500 miles per person per year in 1972-73 to 7,000 miles currently[161] (there has been a small downturn in distance travelled in the last two years, probably due to the recession). This has come about largely through private investment in more and better cars and public investment in more and better roads, permitting higher average speeds of travel and hence greater distances traversed in the same amount of time. Travel time savings are transient, and not a sound basis for estimating the benefits of investment in long-lived infrastructure.

4.  The average distance travelled has not increased since about 1995, despite the economic growth of the following decade. Moreover, car use per capita has stabilized at about 6,600 vkm pa since 2002. Travel and economic growth have thus become uncoupled, after two centuries during which they increased in parallel. It seems unlikely that the average distance travelled will increase in the future, which lessens the requirement for further investment in transport infrastructure[162].

5.  The long run benefits of investment in the transport system are access benefits which arise from bringing people and locations nearer in time, permitting more choice of destinations. In recent years, conventional transport appraisal has recognised "Wider Impacts", which are economic benefits arising over and above travel time savings benefits. Agglomeration benefits are one class of such benefits, reflecting the accessibility of firms and workers to each other. Agglomeration benefits are therefore access benefits which are appropriate to consider in appraising proposed schemes. In contrast, time saving benefits to travellers are inappropriate since, not only are they transient, but they neglect the key features of access benefits which are specificity to locations and having consequences beyond the travellers who are supposed to save time.

6.  To illustrate the argument, consider London's Docklands, once the centre of the capital's commercial life. The coming of containers displaced the port activity down river and the historic docks were abandoned. Construction of the first phase of the Docklands Light Railway in 1985-87, at a modest cost of £77 million, put Docklands on the map, demonstrating ready access to the City (currently 10 min from Bank to Canary Wharf). This prompted huge private investment in a new financial quarter, regenerating the area and relieving space pressures and high rents in the City. The Jubilee Line Extension increased public transport capacity, as did extensions to the DLR, with the result that the highest paid group of workers in Britain make minimal use of the car to travel to work (there are only 3,000 parking places for 90,000 workers at Canary Wharf).

7.  Public investment in transport in the Docklands was necessary to support private sector investment in commercial and residential property and public space. The transport investment can be seen as catalytic, making an essential contribution to the economic growth and urban regeneration outcomes. It would be pointless to attempt to compute the benefits of investment in the Jubilee Line Extension by estimating the savings of travel time to those who use this line.

8.  The recent renovation of the section of the London Overground connecting Docklands to Dalston Junction, a low income district in East London, provides a further example of the role of transport investment in urban regeneration. The 23 minute journey to the financial centre has prompted a £160 million private sector investment in residential and commercial property as part of the Dalston Junction redevelopment. The monetary value of time saved by travellers misses the point that the benefits of the transport investment depend on consequential private investment and as such are substantially specific to particular locations and accrue in part to land owners, property developers and the occupiers of new properties.

9.  The case for any particular transport investment cannot therefore be considered in isolation from the likely consequences for access, land use and private sector investment. Conventional appraisal methodology, as endorsed by the Department for Transport, largely disregards such "secondary" consequences, focussing instead on transient travel time savings. Such "silo thinking" is convenient but mistaken. It leads to the funding of schemes justified by small time savings (a few minutes) experienced by large numbers of road users. However, such schemes are unlikely to make a demonstrable contribution to economic growth. A number of transport analysts have recognised the limitations of conventional appraisal methodology and are discussing how the wider consequences of new schemes might best be included; at present, the feasibility of alternative approaches remains unclear.

10.  To assess the case for proposed transport investment financed from public funds, one approach worth considering is to adopt the methodology employed by other Departments, which is to assess the relative cost-effectiveness of different means of achieving a particular policy objective. Although the Treasury's Green Book on Appraisal and Evaluation in Central Government recommends cost-benefit analysis in preference to cost-effectiveness analysis, in practice it seems only the DfT that routinely attempts cost-benefit analysis for the generality of its schemes. Central Government programmes of investment in health and education facilities, in social housing, prisons, defence establishments, etc, are appraised in terms of the cost effectiveness in achieving desired outcomes. I consider next some of the main desired outcomes of transport investment relevant to the wider economy (there are others, such as improved safety, which could be analysed in a similar way).

OBJECTIVES OF TRANSPORT INVESTMENT

11.  One important objective of transport investment is to support economic growth directly. Here the need is to identify schemes having a strong likelihood that they will contribute to economic growth by catalysing substantial private sector investment in commercial and residential property. Ideally, the public sector investment should be conditional on private sector commitment. There is likely to be greatest confidence that this can be achieved where the main benefit is expected at a particular geographic location.

12.  A second objective of transport investment is to improve the operation of the transport system, thereby indirectly assisting economic growth. A common type of scheme in this context is the widening of a trunk road where the motivation is to reduce congestion. However, in practice, the benefits of such investment are taken in the long run in the form of increased access, as road users take advantage of the higher speeds from reduced congestion to travel further, the additional vehicle-kilometres adding to traffic - known as "induced traffic" - so that the amount of congestion and the resulting time delays are not much affected (although the location of congestion is likely to change). This is the origin of the maxim that we can't build our way out of congestion.

13.  Road pricing is advocated as a means of reducing congestion (not discussed here, given the small likelihood of adoption in the near future). The rationale of road pricing is to deter those road users who attach relatively low value to travelling at times of peak usage. There are, however, other means of achieving this outcome. When asked in surveys, road users say that the main problem with congestion is the uncertainty of journey time and that their main means for minimising such uncertainty is to vary the starting time to avoid peak traffic. Decisions on when to start out are largely based on past experience of traffic conditions. Real time traffic information linked to GPS navigation systems is increasingly becoming available to facilitate such decisions, with predictive algorithms being introduced that will further assist the road user. Given that the main perceived problem with road traffic congestion is the uncertainty of arrival time, advice on probable journey time, based on good predictions of traffic conditions, is a relatively low cost, uncontroversial means of meeting the objective of improving the operation of the road network[163].

14.  A third objective is to cope with the projected growth of the population, from the current 62 million to about 70 million by 2030. As noted earlier, per capita daily travel has held steady since 1995 at about 1,000 journeys and 7,000 miles per person per year. Heavy goods vehicle traffic has also not grown over the past decade. There has, however, been growth in light goods vehicle traffic, for reasons which are not well understood (but may be connected with the growth of the service sector of the economy), hence future growth is uncertain.

15.  Accordingly, the main known factor determining future growth of traffic is population increase. However, as regards investment in the transport system to respond to such demographic change, much depends on where the additional people will live and work. If additional homes are build on green field sites, on the edge of existing settlements, then the residents will want car-based mobility and there will be a need for further road capacity. On the other hand, if the additional homes come into being within existing urban areas - on brown field sites or through more intensive use of existing properties - where the opportunities for additional road capacity are very limited, then investment in public transport is the more attractive response.

16.  The population of London has increased by about a million over the past twenty years, during which time the proportion of journeys by car has declined (50% in 1993, 41% in 2008) while the proportion of journeys by public transport has risen (24% and 33% respectively). This decline goes against the historic trend for car use to rise with increasing incomes. The population of London is forecast to grow by a further 1.25 million by 2031, involving an additional 750,000 jobs, mainly in the inner boroughs, and accordingly car use is projected to decline further to 37%. Considerable investment in public transport in London is planned, both to cope with population growth and to relieving overcrowding, subject to finance being available[164].

17.  A fourth objective for investment is to reduce carbon emissions from the transport sector. This involves the support of electric and hybrid vehicle technologies and their deployment, support for electric charging infrastructure, and support for the decarbonisation of the electricity supply system to power electric road and rail vehicles (although the latter is usually not seen as being for the Department for Transport). A helpful way of assessing the relative attractiveness of technologies to reduce carbon emissions is to estimate Marginal Abatements Costs, which are the cost per tonne of carbon dioxide saved by the candidate technologies[165]. This is evidently a measure of cost-effectiveness.

18.  These four objectives for transport investment are distinct. There is no appraisal methodology which allows projects meeting such different objectives to be compared one with another, nor with projects with multiple objectives (such as High Speed Rail) There needs therefore to be high level judgements about the relative importance of these objectives, taking account of the attractiveness of the schemes ready for investment, with financial resources allocated accordingly.

19.  Given the present climate of financial stringency, and given the relatively mature transport infrastructure that exists, high levels of new investment in the transport system are probably not the biggest priority at present. Nevertheless, it is important to plan for both population growth and carbon reduction over the medium term, as well as to maintain and better utilise the existing road and rail networks.

CONCLUSIONS

20.  Travel time savings are not a sound basis for appraising the value of a proposed transport investment. Time savings are transient. In the long run, the benefits are taken as enhanced access.

21.  Per capita daily travel has been stable in Britain since 1995 and is not likely to increase in the future. Travel demand and economic growth have become uncoupled. Future travel growth will be due to population increase, although the form this will take will depend on whether the additional inhabitants are housed on green- or brown-field housing developments. The experience of London demonstrates that dynamic growth is compatible with declining per capita car use.

22.  Transport investments will contribute to economic growth when they catalyse private sector investment at particular locations. Transport schemes that are publicly funded in the hope of stimulating economic regeneration, but which are nor conditional on private investment in commercial property, risk yielding poor value for money compared with other possible uses of the funds.

23.  The best means to deal with road congestion is to deploy technologies that supply reasonably good estimates of predicted trip times to road users in advance of their journeys, to help them avoid unanticipated delays.

24.  The best way of appraising the value of potential investments is to assess likely cost effectiveness in meeting policy objectives.

Dr David Metz,
visiting professor,
Centre for Transport Studies, University College London; formerly Chief Scientist, Department for Transport.

September 2010


161   The NTS excludes international travel by air.  Back

162   See D. Metz, "Saturation of demand for daily travel", Transport Reviews, 30(5), 659-674, 2010. Back

163   See http://www.limitstotravel.org.uk/documents/Metz_PN_draft_22-10-09.pdf  Back

164   Mayor's Transport Strategy http://www.london.gov.uk/publication/mayors-transport-strategy
Institutional arrangements outside London are less favourable for the strategic planning of transport investment in the light of expected demographic change and economic growth. 
Back

165   The Committee on Climate Change uses this approach, see
http://www.theccc.org.uk/other_docs/Tech%20paper%20supply%20side%20FINAL.pdf  
Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 2 March 2011