Transport and the economy - Transport Committee Contents


Written evidence from Chris Riley (TE 108)

1.  The Committee has invited evidence on five issues relevant to its inquiry on Transport and the Economy. This paper considers each in turn.

Have the UK's Economic Conditions Materially changed since the Eddington Transport Study and, if so, does this affect the relationship between transport spending and UK Economic Growth?

2.  Since the Eddington Study was completed in 2006, estimates of sustainable growth and the productive potential of the economy have been reduced in light of the recession and the impact of the financial crisis. Estimates by the OBR in June suggest that trend GDP is 9% below the estimates made immediately before the recession, and is likely to grow less rapidly in the future. This means that both the level and the growth rate of transport demand will be lower in the medium and longer term than previously thought. The recession has depressed demand for all transport modes, and while demand will recover it cannot be expected to reach the path assumed in 2006.

3.  This means that pressure on existing transport capacity will be less than if the economy had remained on its previous track, and hence the need for investment in capacity will be correspondingly reduced. Rates of return and Benefit-Cost Ratios (BCRs) for transport schemes in all modes will be lower than otherwise.

4.  Looking at causation the other way invites the question: could more or better transport spending help boost economic growth and offset some of the recent deterioration in economic prospects? The answer in principle is yes, given the kind of economic impacts identified in transport appraisals and other sources of evidence. A DfT working paper on wider economic benefits in 2005 set out how appraisal effects translate into effects on GDP.[113]

5.  But Eddington concluded that:

  1. ¾  in mature economies like the UK, with well-developed transport networks, transport improvements can help primarily by relaxing constraints on growth, for example by reducing congestion, journey times and other transport costs, increasing the effective size of local labour markets, removing obstacles to development and agglomeration; and
  2. ¾  improving connectivity by making new destinations available, and thus previously inaccessible places accessible, could in principle have substantial effects, but that is less likely to be important in the UK than in countries with less well developed transport systems.

6.  These conclusions still seem valid. Improved transport is unlikely to boost growth much in areas of the economy where the underlying growth conditions are not favourable. The two-way-road argument[114] means that improved transport can in some circumstances reduce economic activity in places which become better connected.

7.  A key question for policy makers is whether transport improvements are more effective in boosting growth than other forms of spending, such as education and skills, lower taxes etc. The available literature does not provide clear cut answers to this question.

What type of Transport Spending should be prioritised, in the context of an overall spending reduction, in order best to support regional and national economic growth?

8.  Eddington argued that the priority for transport policy in the UK should be improving the performance of existing transport networks: especially congested urban areas, key inter-urban corridors and key international gateways. That still seems right. This is where the constraints on growth are likely to be greatest. Many commentators stress the key importance of improving urban transport systems.

9.  Eddington also argued that it was vital to "get prices right". That too is still correct; we should focus on pricing for roads as well as public transport, and it's far from clear that prices are currently right. Some road users currently pay less than the social costs they impose - including congestion and climate change.

10.  If the aim is to make the greatest possible contribution to economic growth, transport spending should focus on schemes which offer the greatest economic returns. This would mean adopting a narrower criterion than the BCR currently used in appraisal, omitting for example environmental and social impacts. Ranking transport options by their contribution to the economy would not correspond to a ranking based on the wider concept of welfare currently used, though there would be considerable overlap.

11.  The version of DfT methodology employed by Eddington would probably in general have favoured road schemes over more expensive rail schemes, and smaller schemes over more speculative grand projects. But the changes introduced in 2009 (notably to the treatment of indirect taxes) would now tip the balance more towards public transport.

12.  Phil Goodwin's evidence to the Committee discusses this in more detail. His estimates confirm the high rates of return for small schemes such as cycling and "smarter choices" - measures to influence travel behaviour, such as travel plans - but suggest a very different ordering of priorities between roads and public transport. Returns for roads are now estimated by Goodwin to be much lower, but the numbers need to be examined very carefully. Two key assumptions in particular, and hence the conclusion itself, may be questioned:

  1. ¾  that lower road traffic growth causes as large a reduction in the benefits of road investment as the introduction of road pricing would. This is not borne out by other studies, including the DfT's Road Pricing Feasibility Study in 2004;[115] and
  2. ¾  that demand for public transport, and hence investment returns, are not affected by lower growth in the economy. This too is not borne out by empirical evidence.

13.  Much depends on how well the appraisals of individual schemes - particularly large infrastructure schemes - capture the wider benefits associated with land use changes and dynamic factors which can lead to cumulative changes in the economy. The formal models used in transport appraisal are not always very good at dealing with such effects, and is desirable to use the best available evidence on this from whatever source, as discussed below.

14.  High Speed Rail is evidently a priority for the current Government, and the case for this rests on three main planks:

  1. ¾  rapidly increasing demand for rail travel, which will put increasing pressure on existing capacity (notably the West Coast Main Line);
  2. ¾  the fact that speed is very important for medium and long distance journeys, and values of time are high for some travellers who are therefore prepared to pay more for high speed services; and
  3. ¾  environmental benefits, which are likely to be significant if passengers are attracted in significant numbers from domestic air services.

15.  Extending the high speed network up to and beyond Birmingham could therefore be very worthwhile if appraisal demonstrates high BCRs by comparison with other schemes. But the numbers produced by HS2 are not particularly high. The economic benefits of additional investment in high speed rail could be substantial, but have yet to be demonstrated.

How should the balance between Revenue and Capital Expenditure be altered?

16.  It is not clear in macro terms how the overall balance between current and capital spending should be changed. Ultimately, this depends on assessments of value for money (VfM) for particular projects. But there are some general points of principle to be made.

17.  First, capital projects with a good case on VfM grounds could and should be financed by borrowing, not by current taxpayers, because the benefits accrue to future taxpayers. This is the "golden rule". Failure to invest in worthwhile projects reduces future economic growth - it reduces debt, but also reduces GDP. Investing now, when there are spare resources in the economy and cost pressures are relatively subdued, makes very good economic sense. If the projects are demonstrably good VfM, it is very unlikely that more borrowing for this purpose would lead to a loss of confidence in financial markets.

18.  Second, maintenance of existing transport assets - for example roads and the rail network - should not be neglected, because that simply stores up a need for higher capital spending in the future. Any unwarranted saving in maintenance spending may help to reduce public borrowing and debt, but it also leads to a reduction in the value of national assets.

19.  Third, existing assets should be used as efficiently as possible, especially at times of fiscal stringency when investment in new capacity has to be strictly rationed. That is clearly a priority for rail, but also for the road network.

20.  Road pricing, as championed by Eddington and others (eg the RAC Foundation), is the most economically efficient way of achieving this, and has the added advantage that it generates revenue which can be used to fund capital and current spending - whether on transport or elsewhere - while reducing the need for additional investment in road capacity. It is the politics of road pricing which appears to be the biggest obstacle to progress; the economic case is clear.

21.  There is a read across to rail fares and subsidy for the rail industry. Current rail subsidies are partly a reflection of the fact that roads are under-priced - road users don't meet the full social costs of road travel (in particular congestion, but also carbon). Simply putting up rail fares to help fund increases in capacity will discourage rail demand and push more traffic onto the roads, but with road pricing this would not be a problem and rail subsidies could be reduced.

22.  Finally, there is clear scope for better targeting of bus subsidy, as a recent Oxera study for the LGA has argued.[116] The existing concessionary fares policy is not well targeted on those in need, and Bus Service Operators Grant (BSOG) is not well designed to address local conditions and the environment. Better targeting would permit funds either to be reallocated more productively within the bus industry or to local transport more generally, or savings to be made without damaging it. But the economic case for well designed bus subsidy is strong (as Phil Goodwin's numbers suggest).

Are the current methods for assessing proposed transport schemes satisfactory?

23.  The appraisal methods used have improved in recent years, but further improvements are needed. The degree of sophistication and the type of modelling used will depend on the type of scheme or strategy to be appraised and the stage which the decision process has reached. But the basic methodology is the same.

24.  Some commentators criticise the welfare economics basis of present methods, but this approach has the great advantage of covering the full range of impacts on the public in a coherent and transparent manner. The main problems with implementing the present approach are empirical, and some impacts are very difficult to measure. But empirical improvements are being made all the time, with formal measurement and monetisation being applied to an increasing range of impacts.

25.  Where evidence on welfare impacts is incomplete, or where particular emphasis is needed on specific kinds of effect, other analyses can be used to supplement the basic welfare approach - for example analysis of distributional effects, impacts on economic growth or the environment, or other criteria. If necessary these various analyses and other factors can be combined in a more formal multi-criteria decision analysis (MCDA) approach. But a simple checklist approach, as some have advocated, or a focus solely on contributions of transport schemes to government objectives - which may or may not be sensible - are not adequate substitutes for rigorous analysis within a sound conceptual framework.

26.  Some commentators criticise the important role of time savings in transport appraisal, but this is misguided. The benefits of transport arise because of the connectivity they provide, and as a recent Oxera study has made clear, this essentially reflects the availability of potential travel destinations and the time, reliability and cost - or generalised cost - incurred in reaching them.[117] In the UK, with its highly developed transport system, the latter will be most important. Improvements in journey times, reliability and cost may of course lead to a range of wider effects on the economy, and these can and should be modelled for inclusion in the appraisal.

27.  Some argue that small time savings in particular should be ignored, because people don't appear to value them. But this makes no sense. Small changes may eventually cumulate to larger changes and cannot be ignored. To do so would introduce a wholly unjustified distinction between the overall benefits of a succession of small scale projects, each leading to incremental changes, and large scale projects delivering the same overall effect. There are no doubt some improvements that can be made to the treatment of time savings - for example the valuation of working time spent on public transport - but the basic approach is sound. It is, of course, possible to include the distribution of time savings as a supplementary analysis, as DfT proposes.

28.  Some commentators argue that environmental and some other impacts should not be monetised, because such impacts - for example on human life, or endangered species - are beyond price.[118] There is no evidence that this is so. Society is neither willing nor able to pay an infinite amount to reduce risks to human life - or to preserve tigers. Valuation helps to make judgements on these matters transparent, and should be pursued as far as our techniques allow. It has already been extended to a range of environmental and safety impacts, for example. Willingness to pay for reductions in risk or to mitigate adverse impacts is a sound measure of social preferences. Where good data are not available, or where it is not possible to design suitable studies to obtain them, informed judgements need to be made.

29.  The current approach to appraisal takes account of wider economic benefits of transport, going well beyond time savings, including agglomeration effects, higher output in imperfectly competitive markets, and labour market effects. This is an important step forward.

30.  Agglomeration benefits are potentially very significant, for example, as seen in the Crossrail appraisal. But as well as effects resulting from lower transport costs, which are included in the standard approach, it is also very important to take full account of land use changes and relocation of jobs. At the moment this doesn't necessarily happen; it is allowed only as an optional variant on the central assessment. Good land use transport interaction (LUTI) models are needed to do this properly, and this approach should be encouraged because wider benefits may otherwise be considerably understated. Such modelling is not straightforward, not least because of interaction with the planning system, but it is an important area for future development. Even when such modelling of wider benefits is available, however, it may well be desirable to utilise the results of non model-based studies to inform assessment of such effects, not all of which may be susceptible to formal modelling given the current state of knowledge.

31.  Some kinds of wider effect are omitted completely in the current methodology, such as impacts on competition, overseas trade and investment. In principle these effects could be important, and should be analysed. But the evidence base is weak in this area.

How will schemes be planned in the absence of regional bodies and following the revocation and abolition of Regional Spatial Strategies?

32.  The nature of transport planning and decision taking should be different for strategic national networks, like strategic roads and inter-urban rail systems, and local networks. The former remain the responsibility of central government, and the latter will now be the responsibility of local authorities and/or Local Enterprise Partnerships.

33.  Local authority boundaries do not necessarily relate well to the wider areas served by local transport systems. London is a very good example, and the mayor has a central role in regional transport planning. A similar regime could potentially bring benefits to other city regions, though it is generally accepted that administrative or statistical regions, as covered by the RDAs, are not the appropriate concept.

34.  In the absence of mayors for city regions, local authorities need to coordinate their planning of transport schemes, and the Government should take responsibility for facilitating this. Whether the new Local Economic Partnerships will fit the bill remains to be seen. It will depend on the way they are set up and the powers they have. In principle they could be very effective, but the scope and coverage of partnerships announced so far do not appear to obviate the need for further coordination.

35.  However local and regional transport planning is organised, central government remains responsible for allocating transport funding across the regions. In doing so it is necessary to distinguish between the overall benefits of transport spending to the country and the economy as a whole, and the benefits to individual regions and the objective of reducing regional imbalances.

36.  If the objective is to maximise benefit to the national economy, funds should be directed to where the potential returns are highest - for example where congestion and overcrowding are greatest. That may in practice mean disproportionate spending in regions which are already richer and growing fastest - for example London - and less in slower growth regions where pressures on existing infrastructure are less. This applies whether the DfT is allocating funds to lower tiers of government or prioritising improvements to strategic national networks.

37.  But insofar as the aim is to reduce regional inequalities and give greater help to less buoyant regions, transport funding can be allocated to them specifically to help stimulate growth. But it should be recognised that this would probably mean less benefit to the national economy as a whole. And the benefits to the regions concerned may be weak unless the underlying conditions for growth are favourable.

38.  It is worth noting in this context that, in the current appraisal methodology, use of common national values of time in less buoyant regions, where prices and incomes are typically lower than average, implies a bias in favour of these regions. This is difficult to justify on efficiency grounds and the overall benefits to economic growth, and has the effect of giving additional weight to the regional equity objective.

Chris Riley
Chief Economist of DfT until 2005, now working as a consultant

November 2010



113   "Transport, Wider Economic Benefits and Impacts on GDP", DfT, 2005

 Back

114   See the Appendix to Phil Goodwin's submission of evidence to this Inquiry, September 2010.  Back

115   "Feasibility Study of Road Pricing in the UK", DfT, 2004 Back

116   "Subsidising buses:how to get the best from taxpayers' money", Oxera, June 2009 Back

117   "To Timbuktu and back again: why transport connectivity is important", Oxera, October 2010 Back

118   See, for example: "Getting Transport Right", Campaign for Better Transport and Green Alliance, 2008 Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 2 March 2011