Examination of Witnesses (Questions 684-764)
Q684 <Chair:
Good morning to both of you.
Lord Turner: Good
morning.
Mr Sants: Good
morning.
Chair: >Thank
you very much for coming along at this time of considerable change
in financial regulation. Can I begin by asking you, Lord Turner,
whether you think that it is right that so much power should be
transferred to the Bank of England?
Lord Turner: I
think that the
Chair: >That
was a very long pause before a response. Were you deciding to
be yes or no at that point?
Lord Turner: Chairman,
the pause was not, if you are into the business of interpreting
my pauses, about what I want to say in general to that but exactly
how I would say it. Overall my answer is, no, I don't think there
is a problem. I do think it makes sense certainly for there to
exist a macro-prudential capability, which is within the Financial
Policy Committee. In my own review last year I argued that that
was a crucial missing bit of the existing tripartite structure.
So I have been a very strong supporter of that. Although I don't
personally think it was necessary to break up the FSA and move
the PRA into the Bank, I think it is certainly a feasible solution.
Indeed, I have been on the record of saying that if I was starting
with a greenfield site, that is what I would have done and it
is now going to happen. Insofar as I did not agree with the plans,
it was solely that I thought we didn't need to have the change
to get the benefit.
Chair:> So we
are getting to first best via second best, which you would have
stuck with because we had got used to it? An unusual chain of
arguments there but we'll go with it.
Lord Turner: I
personally had the point of view that the first best is a separation
between prudential regulation and consumer protection, with prudential
combined with the central bank. I do think that is the first best.
My belief was that it wasn't necessarily worth the restructuring
costs of getting there, but the Government having decided that
we are going to face the restructuring complexity of getting there,
the key is to get to what at the end I think will be a better
system.
But to return to your problem of is there too much
power in the Bank of England, I don't think so because I think,
in the two crucial areas of the Monetary Policy Committee with
the interest rate decision, and the Financial Policy Committee
with the macro-prudential levers, there will be a significant
external representation on those and there will be high visibility
of the analysis and decisions that are made. I think that's the
check and balance to what might otherwise be too much executive
power.
Q685 <Chair:
And all those people who are bleating about the over-mighty Governor
have it wrong?
Lord Turner: I
think there will be a challenge for the Governor, simply in the
management of his time, or in some future case her time, or whoever
is the Governor, because when you now look at the sheer workload
of the Monetary Policy Committee, the Financial Policy Committee,
the chairmanship of the PRA and the vice-chairmanshipas
it's likely to beof the European Systemic Risk Board, this
is simply a huge diary management challenge that the Bank will
have to think about, how to effectively use the Governor's time
and effectively delegate other decisions. But in terms of the
institution of the Bank, I think these are a reasonable set of
powers to have been brought together.
Q686 <Chair:
Setting aside the management of the Governor's diary, how do you
feel about the problem of democratic accountability with this
institution having so much power?
Lord Turner: Well,
I think there is a reasonable accountability. The way, as we know,
it has been set up on the monetary policy side is through the
fact that it is the Government and Parliament that set the inflation
target and the Monetary Policy Committee and the Bank deliver
within that. So I think that is a clear separation.
I think on the financial policy side it is more complicated
because it is much more difficult in relation to the issues of
macro-stability and macro-prudential to set down a policy guideline
equivalent to a 2% inflation target. Therefore, one of the crucial
things will be how, within the details of the forthcoming Act,
one clearly defines what are the powers, what is the remit and
what is the objective of the Financial Policy Committee.
Q687 <Chair:
What about accountability to Parliament? How do you think that
should be done?
Lord Turner: I
think that the accountability will come through the reports to
you, the publicity of the probably semi-annual financial stability
reviews, which will set out the analysis and the clear justification
for the actions that have been taken. But I do think there is
an important aim here, which is tricky to get right, of giving
to an authority like the FPC the ability to take decisions that
Governments might not make at times in the electoral cycle. What
we are trying to do is have a mechanism where a trusted independent
authority can slow down a credit boom even if the elected Government
at that time, with a majority in Parliament, rather likes the
good feelings, positive feelings, among society being generated
by that credit boom. I do think we need to create mechanisms that
enable a trusted authority to do that. I think, therefore, the
challenge will be for the Bank of England to earn that trust over
time. But I think there is a role in society for us to have institutions
that have power, that are trusted to exercise power, rather than
us necessarily defining precisely under what constraints they
operate.
Q688 <Chair:
I would like to ask Hector Sants one question before handing over
to Chuka Umunna. I think everyone is agreed that the FSA made
an effort to own up to the mistakes that it had made in the run-up
to this crisis. We are giving the bank a great deal more power
now. Do you think the Bank of England has owned up to all its
mistakes?
Mr Sants: I think
that
Chair: >Another
very long pause.
Mr Sants: Well,
I think that the central Bank's involvement in the crisis was
of a rather different nature to the micro-prudential regulator.
It is perhaps easier for a micro-prudential regulator to identify
specific actions in relation to individual firms that it might
have taken, and if it had taken events might then have followed
a different course. So, in that sense I think it was right and
proper that the FSA should be more forensic in its examination
of what it had and had not done and it was right and proper that
it then made, as you say, significant changes to the way that
it went about supervising firms. I do expect those changes, may
I say, to be carried over into the PRA and the CPMA. It's very
important that we don't fail to learn from the past.
Chair:> I was
asking about the Bank.
Mr Sants: I think
in relation to the central Bank it has demonstrated, by its actions
that it's now very much supporting the creation of the FPC and
the clear consensus that a central bank needs to be involved and
should be in the lead of overseeing financial stability
Q689 <Chair:
Those are Government decisions about structure. I am asking you
whether the Bank, as an institution, owned up to mistakes it made
during the financial crisis.
Mr Sants: From
my perspective, if you take in the round everything that it has
said, including its most recent pronouncements on the new structure,
yes. Was that a more elaborate and lengthy process than the very
straightforward approach that the FSA took? Yes.
Chair:> So,
lots of little snippets of remarks. If we join them all together
and sew them up, we can get to the point that amounts to a comprehensive
analysis and admission of mistakes.
Mr Sants: I think
that would be the way I see it, while the FSA had a cleaner, more
straightforward approach.
Chair:> To 'fessing
up?
Mr Sants: Yes.
Q690 <Mr
Umunna: Thank you, Chair. I would like to follow
up on one of the Chair's questions to you, Lord Turner, but I
just want to first of all revisit a very interesting interview
that you did in Prospect last year. I was quite struck
by a number of the responses that you gave when the reform to
the tripartite regime was put to you. You said that the institutional
architecture is the least important issue. You went on to say,
"There's a spectrum of activities from the monetary policies
of central banks through macro-prudential analysis, micro-prudential
supervision and customer protection issues and whenever you divide
it up you will create interface problems and you will have to
manage them." Is that still your view?
Lord Turner: Yes,
it is. That is why my overall tendency with many organisational
challenges is to be a small "c" conservative and to
believe that whenever you go for organisational structure change
you will create new problems even as you solve old ones. I think
if you look around the world on the organisation structures that
different countries use to deal with this spectrum of activities,
there are pros and cons of different ones, and indeed there is
no real correlation through this crisis.
Q691 <Mr
Umunna: So we are still going to have problems
with the new structure?
Lord Turner: Now,
having said that, within this spectrumand it relates to
the answer I gave to the Chairif I were to work out where
I would do the divide, I do think the new divide will be a somewhat
better divide than we had before. In particular it will help to
close this gap in relation to the crucial area of looking in an
integrated fashion at financial stability and macro-prudential.
But we have to recognise that like any organisational change of
this form, it will deal with one set of interfaces, it will make
that work better, and it will create some new problems. We will
undoubtedly have, between prudential regulation and customer protection
regulation, some complex issues which span that divide. Let me
give you an example. The issue of with-profits policies in the
insurance area and whether with-profits funds, the balance with
which they belong to shareholders or policyholders and the treatment
of those, is simultaneously an issue which has certain prudential
aspects and an issue which has certain fair treatment of consumers
and policyholders aspects.
In future, we will have toonce we have two
separate organisationscreate some mechanisms that enable
us to discuss and co-ordinate that issue. We will also, by splitting
up the prudential authority and the consumer protection authority,
have two separate teams of supervisors visiting the same bank
or insurance company. That will, to a degree, create some duplication;
there will simply be more meetings. My own judgment is that the
benefits of making sure that there is an integrated approach to
these fundamental issues of financial stability and macro-prudential
balance are more important than these problems, but I do think
we have to recognise that as we make one interface better we are
bound to create new problems of interface. That is simply a fact
of life.
Q692 <Mr
Umunna: I suppose what I was getting at is that
one of the problems was, of course, that the crisis demonstrated
that the three bodiesthe Bank of England, the Treasury
and the FSAin some senses were not always talking as closely
as we would have liked them to. In the interview you pointed to
this as being a problem and said that you believe that the closeness
of the links required could be achieved by intelligent working
relationships across the existing institutional divide. I got
the strong impression from the comments you have already made
in answer to the Chair that in some senses you give the impression
that you think this regulatory overhaul is a bit of a waste of
time. You said it is not necessary to make the change to get the
benefit of the reforms and I am just left wondering, given that
I think the transition costs of this reform are going to be in
the order of something like £50 million, whether it is really
worth it, given the comments you have already made about being
able to refine and improve the existing arrangements.
Lord Turner: Let
me be crystal clear, because I think I have been crystal clear
and consistent on my point of view. I believe that, in theory,
if one was starting anew to design a system, I am more in favour
of the new planned system than the previous one. I am a supporter
of a twin peaks approach, in theory, and I think it will, when
we get there, have certain advantages over the present situation.
I also, however, believedand I argued this point, but I
lost this argument, you sometimes lose arguments in lifethat
we could get the vast majority of the benefits of the new system
by doing two things. One is by separating the internal organisation
of the FSA between a consumer protection side and a prudential
side, and the other is by creating a financial policy committee
that bridged the Bank of England to the FSA. Indeed, had there
been a different result of the general election, it was my intention
to argueand, indeed, I was already arguingthat if
the FSA was going to stay as it was, we should make that division
and we should make that bridge.
Mr Umunna:>
So you think it is £50 million well spent?
Lord Turner:
So that is what I argued for, but Governments have to make decisions
and we will now go through this process and, as I think the Chairman
correctly put it, my own belief is that once we go through the
transitional pain of this transition the new system will be a
better system than we have at the moment. I think that is a clear
position that I have set out.
Mr Sants: Could
I maybe make a more general point here, which is no organisational
structure is going to be perfect. There is no way organisational
change alone is the solution to learning everything that needs
to be learned from what has happened in the last few years. There
is a need to co-ordinate across the entire spectrum of regulation;
conduct risk can become prudential. So, in theory, you either
have to have one monolithic organisation, which avoids the problem
of institutional gaps but raises the question of focus, which
was an issue that was rightly raised about the FSA in the past,
or you make divisions. Wherever you place the divisions, you will
have a co-ordination problem. Organisational structure is not
the substantive point here.
Q693 <Mr
Umunna: My last question is to Lord Turner. You
are the leading authority in these matters but you are absent
from the field once we've completed the transition to the new
arrangements. Are you surprised that there has not been a place
found for you in the new regulatory structure once it is put in
place? Some might think it is a bit like having a striker on the
subs bench. Do you feel you should be back on the field once all
these new arrangements have been put in place?
Lord Turner: It
is going to take us about two years from now to put these arrangements
in place and I am very happy concentrating at the moment on delivering
that. When that is done, I am going to be very happy to do something
else.
Q694 <Chair:
You have no idea what you think that might be?
Lord Turner: I have really no
idea.
Chair: It took a moment
or two to get to that answer as well.
Lord Turner: Mr
Chairman, are we going to continue analysing pause length throughout
this?
Chair:> Depends
how long the pauses are. George had a quick rejoinder to an earlier
question.
Q695 Mr Mudie: How you
answer questions here, does that affect what you're going to do
in the future, do you think?
Lord Turner: Does
what?
Mr Mudie: How you answer
questions here, does that affect
Lord Turner: I
have to say I do not spend time thinking about this. I am very
happy concentrating on the job we have in hand.
Q696 Mr Mudie: Hector,
when you and the Chairman had that very polite, coded exchange
about the FSA openly admitting their mistakes but the Bank of
England dropping them in little hints here and there and you had
to join the dots to see, you left us all in the dark. What was
the biggest mistake the Bank of England made in the last three
years? At least we would have something to start our search.
Lord Turner: I
will let Hector answer.
Mr Mudie: I am giving
him time to think so it is not a pause.
Mr Sants: That
is appreciated. Of course, the word "mistake" is always
emotive, isn't it? I think maybe a better way of thinking about
these things is what would we like to learn from in the future.
I think that two points come to mind as I look back over the period.
First of all, to pick up the earlier exchange, it was rightly
pointed out that the level of communication, and the level of
interest, from the central Bank in financial stability issues
was recognised by all to have been very low, to say the least,
in the pre-2007 period. As the crisis began to buildrecognising,
of course, it went through a number of phases, maybe of a more
domestic nature pre-Lehman Brothers and of a more global nature
post-Lehman BrothersI think it would be fair to say, and
that everybody would recognise, that the central Bank was slow
to recognise the need to really engage with the financial stability
question. So that, of course, takes us back to why it is right,
and I fully support and have been on record as supporting, as
Adair has as well, the creation of the FPC and the fact the central
Bank must lead on financial stability matters, i.e. must be in
charge of the oversight of the system. It is absolutely not right
that the micro-prudential regulator should have such a responsibility.
The FSA never was, never should have been, in charge of the stability
of the system. The central Bank should be and, in my view, should
have shown more interest in that issue even under the previous
remit. So that, I think, is one point I would make.
I think the other point I would make is relating
to the fact that in a crisis the traditional, conventional wisdom
of the interaction between the provision of liquidity support
and solvent institutions becomes a very difficult judgment to
make. There are times when in the round that very much becomes
a forward-looking judgment that needs to be made early to avoid
the situation compounding itself. As events demonstrated, significant
liquidity support did end up being put into the system through
the SLS and other measures and that could have been done earlier.
So, I think the importance of that judgment around liquidity support
and the importance of a central bank taking a clear responsibility
for financial stability were the two issues. The current proposal
clearly shows that those lessons have been learnt. Then there
is this very interesting question around a series of tactical
decisions, but I think they're now lost in the mists of time and
not really relevant.
Chair:> Lord
Turner wanted to add something. If you could be very brief.
Lord Turner: I
just wanted to say that I think the most crucial mistakes were
not, I think, a set of tactical issues but an entire philosophy
that goes back over the last couple of decades, and which was
shared by finance ministries and central banks across the world,
which was a belief that monetary stability defined by the inflation
rate alone was a sufficient condition for a stable economy.
Chair:>We have
had your evidence on that before.
Lord Turner: There
was a belief that you didn't have to focus on financial stability
as an activity in itself. That was the dominant intellectual belief
of central banking and of the economics profession throughout
the world. I think any tactical mistakes have to be understood
in terms of that, I think, quite fundamental philosophical mistake.
Mr Sants: And the
final point you'd make, of course, is about the Basel regime.
The Bank of England sat around the Basel regime table along with
the FSA, so insofar as the rules undoubtedly have been proved
to be flawed, that was a joint responsibility and I guess if you
looked at the media at the time that probably wasn't as clear.
Chair:> I've
not met anybody who is prepared to stand up for Basel, but there
we are. Jesse Norman.
Q697 <Jesse
Norman: Thank you very much, indeed, Mr Chairman.
Before I ask my question, I must say what you have said in coded
Mandarinese, Mr Sants, is extraordinary. The Bank of England could
have shown more interest in stability before 2008
Mr Sants: 2007.
Jesse Norman:>
2007. This is a central bank whose principal job is to watch these
billowing monetary aggregates and bank lending, and keep an eye
on the stability of the system. I think it is extraordinary that
that should have been allowed to occur, and I am grateful to you
for clarifying that issue.
The question I want to ask now goes back to the issue
of the power of the Governor of the Bank of England itself. If
you look at the Governor's current situation, he sits on every
major committee, and a series of new powers and committees have
been added to the remit of the bank. He is surrounded by a team,
all of whom have been created or brought in through his own office
and patronage, broadly speaking. The court of the Bank of England
is not an enormously effective institution, it appears, in holding
him to account. What forms of accountability are going to be exercised
on him over and above periodic disclosure?
Lord Turner: I
think there are different forms of accountability you have. In
relation to things to do with the internal operational cost-effectiveness
of the Bank, I think the court process is fairly effective, but
it really has nothing to do with challenging the actual decisions
that are made. To that extent the court is in a very different
position from the board of the FSA, which does get involved in
substantive decisions about actual policy. That is not the role
of the court at the Bank. I think in relation to the policy decisions,
it does derive from the fact that crucial decisions are made by
committees of which the Governor is the chair but where his say-so
does not always sway. The fact is that on the Monetary Policy
Committee, which has been defined as the single most important
thing that the bank has donethat will change with the Financial
Policy Committeethe Governor does not always get his way.
There have been times when he is outvoted on that committee. The
votes are clear; the votes are public; the arguments are public;
and the analysis is public. The inflation report provides a clear
understanding of the intellectual basis on which the MPC has made
its decisions.
So, in relation to monetary policy, I don't think
we do have a problem of accountability. I think the challenge,
as I said, is going to be on the financial policy side where one
could be pulling different levers with somewhat different objectivescountercyclical
capital in order to slow down a credit boom. It is less easy to
reduce it to a clear set of votes and it is less easy to define
the objective as, "Parliament has said the objective shall
be 2%". But I still think it is possible in that area to
set up a process that will be seen as one where while the Governor
is clearly leading that process intellectually and analytically,
there are checks and balances through the external members of
that committee and the visibility. I think the challenge is simply
to make that visibility and openness and sense of potential challenge
work on the financial policy side in exactly the same way that
it has, I think, effectively worked on the MPC side. I don't think
on the MPC side people have said that we have an unaccountable,
over-powerful Governor. In fact, it's a much more open system
than if you look at the Federal Reserve in the US, where there
has in the past been a feeling that people will not oppose the
point of view of the chairman, whereas we do have a process where
people are willing to oppose the point of view of the Governor.
Q698 <Jesse
Norman: On the monetary side, it is very striking
that inflation has been above the target now for a long period
of time, for many well known reasons, and the Governor has been
writing letters to the Chancellor like confetti. Given the power
of the Bank and the increasing power of the Bank, do you think
this failure to hit the inflation target reflects its powerlessness
or its insubordination to the will of Government, since Government
has set a 2% target?
Lord Turner: I
think on the inflation target we have the process working. The
reason why the inflation target was set not as an absolute, but
as an absolute with a range around it and a trigger point of a
letter, was precisely to recognise the fact that there can be
certain circumstances where a reasonable judgment is that inflation,
either up or down, has gone beyond the bounds for exceptional
reasons, but is expected to come back in future. There are, as
you know, a set of reasonable explanations, particularly in terms
of the impact of the depreciation but also the impact, for instance,
of VAT changes and so on, which can help explain what has occurred.
It is really for the Treasury and you to question the Bank about
that, but I don't think the fact that there has been this overshoot
in any way suggests that the process is wrong. I think the process
is working and requires the discipline of the Governor having
to write a letter setting out why he and the committee believe
that this overshoot is temporary. There are some reasonable prima
facie reasons for believing that that is a good argument.
Q699 <Jesse
Norman: That's very helpful. Thank you. Just changing
the subject to the position of Ireland where we are met together
with it in great crisis. Do you think that the exposure of the
banks to the Irish situation, and therefore in some sense our
bailout, is the result of a failure of regulation and, if so,
how would that be corrected by the new system?
Lord Turner: I
think it's very important to understand the nature of the exposure
of the UK banking system to Ireland, and it is useful for me to
take this opportunity to clarify the situation because there has
been
Chair:>If you
can manage to do it briefly.
Lord Turner: I
will do it as quickly as possible.
Chair:>I know
it is a very big subject that has been opened up.
Lord Turner: There
has been some commentary that we are, as it were, significantly
exposed to the Irish state or the Irish banks. That is broadly
speaking not the case. The holdings of Irish Government bonds
by the UK banks are not at all worrying in their scale; we are
well aware of the figures, we look at it, we think about any consequences
that will follow. That is not a true issue. Nor, indeed, is the
direct exposure of the UK banks to the Irish banks out of line
with what you would expect or at a worrying level. The reason
why the UK banking system has some significant exposure to the
Irish economy is that there are two of our major banks, RBS and
HBOS, which have significant businesses in Ireland. Most obviously
in the case of RBS, it owns Ulster Bank, which has been there
for decades. It was owned by NatWest, which was then bought by
RBS a long time back. So what you have there is an exposure, which
seemed to be a perfectly sensible thing to do: why wouldn't a
bank own another bank in a closely linked, nearby economy? It's
not the product of a sudden splurge or an irresponsible entry.
Ulster Bank is a large bank, both in north and south
in Ireland. Inevitably, therefore, it is exposed not to the Irish
state or to the Irish banks but to the general conditions of the
Irish economy. What we do, therefore, when we run our stress tests
on RBS or on Lloyds to determine their capital adequacy, the tests
cover assumptions about how bad it could be in the Irish economy,
exactly as we do in the UK economy. So, the processes that we
are using to make sure that those exposures are understood by
us, and are adequately allowed for in our capital adequacy, are
exactly the same when we are looking at a residential mortgage
extended in Dublin as a residential mortgage extended in London.
But the crucial point I want to make is that the fundamental exposures
of the British banking system are to the Irish economy, not to
the Irish state or to the Irish banks.
Q700 <Jesse
Norman: Except you haven't quite answered the question,
which is about why the failure occurred. I take it we don't want
to be writing checks for £7 billion or whatever our total
exposure is going to bemore than that even. Some failure
has occurred. It was modelled in the stress test; what has happened?
Lord Turner: There
was a failure, as Hector has already mentioned, of our entire
capital adequacy regime. We have been running banking systems
across the world with far too light capital requirements, with
insufficient shock absorbers in the system to deal with the bumps
on the road. In addition we had, both in the UK and in Ireland,
in some cases some very poor extension of lending to, for instance
in particular, commercial real estate. We have that problem in
the UK as well as in Ireland. A regulator can only to a degree
keep control of that. The key controls on that should be either
the ongoing capital rules or the macro-prudential rules. Indeed,
the Irish situation illustrates above all the desperate need for
macro-prudential rules. What ought to have been happening back
in 2005, 2006 and 2007 is a mechanism that would have enabled
the Central Bank of Ireland to impose countercyclical capital
requirements on the Irish banks. That is what was really needed.
Chair: >We will
come on to that in a moment.
Mr Sants: You have
to remember the Irish banks are regulated by the Irish regulator
and therefore we're talking about European standards.
Chair:> Hector,
I'm bringing in John and we can come back to this subject in a
moment.
Q701 <John
Thurso: Let me ask you, Lord Turner, the question.
You said in a speech, I think in March, that we need some new
combination of macro-prudential tools. What tools, what will be
most effective and what can we put in that doesn't need international
agreement?
Lord Turner: This,
of course, is going to be the crucial issue for the interim FPC
when it is established. In preparation for that, there are people
in the relevant bit of the Bank already producing papers that
will be before the interim FPC when it first meets. Clearly the
debate about what those tools should be is important. I think
we know some of the tools. One of the tools is a countercyclical
capital requirement, the abilityin addition to the consistent
continuous capital requirements in Basel IIIto impose additional
capital requirements on the banks when credit conditions are expanding
rapidly. That is clearly set out in the Basel III regime where
it talks about an extra layer of capital of up to 2.5% of risk-weighted
assets, thoughalmost certainlywith freedom for national
authorities to go beyond that. That, in itself, will be a powerful
tool. It is not a tool that one would imagine switching on every
six months or so. I think it is a tool that would highly likely
not to be applied at all for five or six years and then would
be brought in when there is a major credit boom emergingas
a very important tool.
Q702 <John
Thurso: Can I just ask you on that one: five years,
seven years goes by, suddenly the assets bubble appears, the tool
is brought in, there is a squeeze and suddenly nobody can get
mortgages. Have we thought through whether this is a realistic
proposition?
Lord Turner: The
answer is that I think it is. It is obviously the case that the
impact of this is to constrain the supply of credit that would
otherwise exist. But I think we all recognise now that if in 2005,
2006 or 2007, before the crisis, we had had a mechanism to slow
down the supply, both of residential mortgages and commercial
real estate lending, we might not have the increases in public
debt and recession that we face at the moment. Would that mean
that if we had done that in 2005, 2006 or 2007 somebody would
have had less mortgage availability than they otherwise would
have, that they would have had to borrow with only an 80% loan
to value ratio not a 90% loan to value ration? Well, obviously.
But we have realised that the process of credit expansions, booms
and busts, is one of the most destructive things in the economy,
and we cannot create macro levers that slow that down without
that meaning that at the margin somebody in those specific circumstances
is prevented from getting credit that they otherwise want. That
is the consequence of that.
Q703 <John
Thurso: Do you think it is important that we make
it clear what the consequence is? We are talking now about this
wonderful thing of macro-prudential tools. The average guy in
the street hasn't a clue what we're on about, but when the mortgage
doubles or they can't get the mortgage, then they will and that
will translate back to Parliament. So we need to be robust about
this.
Lord Turner: That
is absolutely right and other countries are familiar with this.
At the moment there is, for instance, a very significant property
price boom going on in Hong Kong. Hong Kong is unable to move
an interest rate lever because, of course, it has a currency board
system where it is fully pegged to the dollar and therefore its
monetary policy is essentially that of the US. It is, therefore,
trying to slow down that property price boom by, for instance,
and I was going to get to this, variations of maximum loan to
value ratios. Many other countries like Hong Kong, like India,
like Singapore are used to the idea that these levers are pulled.
Of course, when they are pulled, somebody who would rather have
liked to borrow a whole load of money to buy a house that they
thought would have gone up in value is unable to do that. We do
need to be honest with people. This is, in the famous phrase,
mechanisms to take away the punchbowl before the party gets out
of hand and that is not always a popular thing to do.
Q704 <John
Thurso: Coming down off the very high macro level,
as Hector said earlier, organisational change of itself doesn't
really achieve a great deal, it is what you do with it. The macro-prudential
tools are an important part of the toolkit. The other side of
the equation is behaviour, and one of the behavioural sides of
the banking crisis was broadly around the whole question of remuneration.
Can we have regulation of banking without addressing remuneration
and the bonus culture?
Lord Turner: Well,
we are addressing it and I think we are addressing it in a way
that is appropriate for a regulator. I don't think you can expect
a regulator to be the authority that expresses, as it were, society's
preferences for how much people are paid. If society has a point
of view about inequality, the relevant tools and the degree of
progressivity of the income tax system, all things like that,
what you can ask a regulator to do is focus on whether the structure
of how people are being paid is creating incentives for excessive
risk taking. Before this crisis, it was the case that people were
being paid cash bonuses at the end of a year for what looked in
that year to be fantastically profitable trading activity, well
before we knew whether this was what looked profitable but had
simply left a trail of toxic waste for people to look after in
the next couple of years. That is why our focus has not been on
the level of pay, but on things that require a certain proportion
of it to be deferred and that require that getting that deferred
element is then subject to looking at the performance over the
two or three years to make sure that it still looks as if that
was a profitable, sensible activity. That is what we have done.
We played a major role in the development of the
international Financial Stability Board code, which was agreed
at the Pittsburgh Summit in September 2009, and we have been as
forceful as any authority in the world at implementing that. I
don't think this will be transformational, but I think it will
play a useful role. If I can just illustrate why I think it will
be a useful role: I have sat on the remuneration committee of
a major bank, and it is true to say that before the crisis when
we were deciding the structure of remuneration, we did not, I
think, adequately think about, "Does that have some consequences
for the riskiness or otherwise of behaviour?". We focused
almost entirely on, "What do we have to pay to get this person
in order that the competition doesn't get them?" I think
we have provided in this regulation a set of rules and guidelines
that will change the behaviour of good remuneration committees
so that they will be focusing on and integrating risk considerations
into remuneration considerations. I think that will be a step
forward.
Q705 <John
Thurso: You neatly sidestepped what society thinks.
I think society has a very clear idea that people getting £12
million or £15 million a year for no capital invested of
their own is bonkers, but the evidence we've had is that if we
try and change it in this country all the bankers will go elsewhere.
Are we just stuck with paying ludicrous amounts of money in a
way that completely devalues the concept of capitalism, or can
we do anything on our own?
Lord Turner: As
you know, I think those are important issues for us to think about
and they are issues that concern me but they are not ones that
I think a regulator can directly address. I think we can indirectly
address it through, for instance, adequate capital requirements.
It is my belief that some of the trading activity that occurred
was blown up to a level that was not required by the economy and
did not serve an economically useful purpose, partly because we
allowed it to because we set far too low capital requirements
for trading activity. We have already very significantly increased
the capital requirements for trading activity and we are now engaged,
through the Basel Committee, in a fundamental review of capital
requirements for trading activity, which could produce further
major changes next year. From a regulatory point of view, that
is the relevant tool that we have available. Will it be transformational?
Not necessarily. I think there is something about the financial
system that means that at the end of it there will still be high
pay for things which many people in society will not believe are
useful to them, but that is not something that we have the power
to entirely fix.
Q706 <Andrea
Leadsom: Thank you, Chairman. Just going back slightly,
back in 2007 I was working for a major UK funds management company
whose senior fund managersaward-winning fund managers,
I should sayfor two years had not been buying bank equities,
specifically and very openly saying that there was a credit bubble
going on; money was too cheap; the Bank of England needed to raise
interest rates; don't touch bank debt; and particularly don't
touch building societies. And yet the FSA completely failed to
see Northern Rock coming, or at least completely failed to do
anything about it. What about the new structure is going to make
that any different? There were all the signs out there for at
least a couple of years. Why will the new system enable us to
avoid that kind of problem in the future?
Mr Sants: I think
we need to come back to the points that Adair has already covered
to some degree. We do need to distinguish between the role and
the effectiveness of firm-specific supervision, and the role and
effectiveness of overall oversight and intervention in the system
as a whole. As everybody, I think, is in general agreementthe
Committee, ourselves and othersthere was no process in
the then tripartite system to invest in any one body responsibility
for looking at the overall system and the degree of risk in the
overall system. The FSA, as we have said repeatedly, did not believe
it wasand was notcharged with financial stability
responsibility and was not looking at the overall risk in the
system, and nor was the Bank. I have already observed that is
the central bank's role going forward and fully support the creation
of the FPC in consequence.
Within that, however, even if you do have a system
that then develops too high a degree of risk, which then potentially
puts individual institutions at risk through the systemic issue,
there is the question of the degree to which those institutions
might be able to isolate themselves from that systemic risk in
terms of their own particular circumstances; business model and
capital liquidity management. I think we've also been through
in this Committee more than once namely that the firm-specific
rules of capital and liquidity were the responsibility of the
Basel Committee and then subsequently interpreted in Europe through
the European regime. The Bank of England and the FSA were jointly
involved in this process as part of the international collective.
Those rules have been proved to be fundamentally wrong. There
was an intellectual failure of the international regulatory community
in respect of that global set of rules that the UK and the FSA
applied. On top of that, the FSA had a supervisory approach, which
was to intervene only when things had gone wrong, so it was not
doing any great business model analysis, which compounded the
problem. But the individual supervisory actions are the least
important in that chain of events.
Q707 <Andrea
Leadsom: So, going forward, under the PRA, surely
when it all boils down it's about personal accountability, isn't
it? So, in the event of a failure of a firm in the future, or
the suspected failure of a firm or a set of firms, who will be
accountable? Will it be you or will it be the Governor? Obviously
you will be chief executive of the PRA. So whose role will it
be to take responsibility for that failure?
Mr Sants: If it
is a systemic failure of the overall system and it is deemed in
hindsightpresumably we'll assume those people in those
roles in the future have been doing their best to make sure these
failures do not occurthat they could have made an intervention
using one or many of the tools we've just been touching on through
the FPC, then obviously the FPC and the central Bank would be
held to account. Of course, we have just observed in the debate
on accountability that the FPC is a committeeit is not
one personbut it would be the FPC and the central Bank
accountable for systemic failure.
Andrea Leadsom:>
So you're saying that there isn't
Mr Sants: If it
was a firm-specific event, then you would look to the PRA and
the chief executive of the PRA. But could I just make one point
here in passing, which is a really important point in terms of
the philosophy of the PRA? The philosophy of the PRA, its intention
and the way it should be judged should be different to the way
that in general the FSA has been judged. It should not be judged
on stopping firms failing for idiosyncratic, firm-specific reasons:
it should be judged on whether those failures then carry costs
to the system. If you look back on actually what went wrong, arguably
there were three main failures in the tripartite system. The first
was the lack of a bank resolution system and the second was a
poor financial compensation scheme. The third was probably the
absence of a financial stability oversight mechanism. If Northern
Rock had been resolvable over a weekend in a way that did not
create cost to taxpayers, did not create detriment to society
and did not cause a problem for users of the banking system, then
I would say going forward the PRA would consider that a reasonable
solution.
We are not trying to take idiosyncratic failure out
of the system. If you do that, you do not get innovation and you
do not get economic growth and a vibrant economy. So, the PRA
should be judged by whether it can avoid failure which comes with
a cost to the system, not whether it can avoid failure. Orderly
failure should not be seen as poor performance by the PRA.
Q708 <Andrea
Leadsom: But, Mr Sants, my question is about accountability
and you're telling me that this remains spread amongst FPC and
the bank and the PRA. I am asking about individual
Mr Sants: No, micro-prudential
is with the PRA.
Andrea Leadsom:>
Is it your problem in future if an individual bank goes bust?
Because, let's face it, if a large bank goes bust there are automatically
systemic risks. They don't go bust in isolation; we've just discovered
that. So, who will be accountable? Is it you or is it the Governor?
Mr Sants: For individual
banks failing it would be the PRA and I, as the chief executive,
would take responsibility for that, no doubt accountable to the
board with the Governor as the chair. But it is normal practice,
which I subscribe to, for chief executives to take responsibility
for their organisations. I'm just making the point, however, that
failure of a bank is not necessarily to be deemed a failure by
the PRA; you need to look at the circumstances of that failure
and the consequences. I am trying to wean people off an expectation
that you operate a no failure regime and explain that, going forward,
if you can have failure without cost to the system that would
not be a failure from the PRA's point of view.
Q709 <Andrea
Leadsom: What worries you about the next failure?
Where is that going to come from? Is that going to come from off-balance
sheet risk, is it going to come from shadow banking? What do you
worry about most?
Mr Sants: Clearly,
history tells us that crises tend not to repeat themselves in
the precise nature of the crisis and the precise drivers, so the
next one is likely to be different in nature from the last one.
Hopefully it will also be some way off and hopefully also less
detrimental in impact, but undoubtedly at some point there will
be another crisis. Where is that likely to come from? I'll tell
you that what worries me in the generality is that effectively
where we saw the build-up in risk over the last 20 or so years,
and particularly in the key period pre-2007, was within the banks
and also within the shadow banking system, but basically within
the managers of risk. And because those institutions, both off
balance sheet and on balance sheet, were inadequately capitalised
and the liquidity regime was poor, when the shock occurred they
weren't able to absorb it. That's what we're now addressing through
the regulatory actions Adair has referred to earlier. But one
of the consequences of that could well be to push risk out of
that aspect of the system, not just into the shadow system but
out of the system altogether. So, you can then push risk effectively
into the consumerinto the user of product and out of the
manufacturer of product.
So, for example, if you have something like an ETF,
you can put leverage in an ETF and then consumers themselves buy
the product with the leverage. So I think the risk is the leverage
moves out of the visibility of the regulator from the point of
view of regulating the manufacturers of product into the consumers
of product. So this is kind of a long-term issue. I don't think
it is happening to a significant degree at the moment, but logically
I think that is a potential area of future risk that we need to
very careful about, which is why I think we need to make sure
that we are reforming the trading environment and the market environmentthe
central counterparty environmentat the same time as reforming
the capital and liquidity regime of the banks and the shadow banks.
So, it will be something to do with risk occurring away from the
core banking system.
Q710 <Andrea
Leadsom: So just very quickly, if it were your
example of exchange-traded funds, would you see it as the PRA's
role to continue to monitor that and to take responsibility?
Mr Sants: No. Well,
not primarily because the PRA is not the market's regulator. That
would be sitting with the CPMA and potentially with the clearing
and settlement component of the Bank of England. The PRA is a
firm-specific regulator for prudential risk in the insurance and
banking system. That is the way that the Government are proposing
to set it up.
Q711 <Andrea
Leadsom: So there is going to be an issue there
then of you needing to pass information to the CPMA if there's
something that's bothering you about the activities of a particular
firm?
Mr Sants: Of course,
or back to the point earlier, whenever you have an organisational
divide, information must be exchanged. As we said before, the
advantage of a single regulator is that firm-specific risk is
looked at by a single team of supervisors who are at least meant
to be looking at everything in the round. If you split it up,
you get the focus and there is no likelihood of them being distracted
by another mandate or competing mandates, but they have to co-operate.
Risk will move around across the system, and if the various different
parts of the system do not co-ordinate, that risk will be lost
to visibility.
Q712 <Mr
Mudie: I think it's refreshing and good that we
look at a new structure, learning from the mistakes of the past.
Just on that, did the FSA have a view on whether Barclays should
have been able to purchase Lehman Brothers?
Mr Sants: Yes,
we did. Yes, most definitely, and we had the same viewI
had the same view and the FSA had the same viewas the senior
management of Barclays, namely that it should not purchase Lehman
Brothers if there was any possibility of it putting Barclays at
risk, and at no point did Barclays ever suggest to us a deal that
was of that sort of nature.
Q713 <Mr
Mudie: No, but that's not the question. The report
has come through that Bob Diamond had negotiated a bad Lehman
Brothers that was left in the Americans' hands and Barclays were
going to buy the good part of Lehman Brothers, and that was what
was turned down. Is that a mistaken report?
Mr Sants: Yes.
Q714 <Mr
Mudie: So it was always a purchase of bad assets?
Mr Sants: As John
Varley has reported a number of timesand my recollection
of events is completely in line with that of John Varley's, and
since we were talking and we were the decision makers here that
would seem to be where you should look to establish the factsat
no point did Barclays make a clear proposition to us in relation
to the acquisition of Lehman Brothers that we then turned down.
There was no structure, as I understand it, which John Varley
and the board found acceptable and therefore they didn't put one
to us. If they had put one to us we would have evaluated it on
the criterion I have just described, but we did not have a definitive
proposal put to us.
Q715 <Mr
Mudie: On the question of shadow banking that Andrea
was dealing with, how much of the shadow banking worldit's
estimated at $20 trillion, twice the mainstream banking moneydo
we regulate?
Mr Sants: I think
Adair is wanting to
Lord Turner: This
is an issue that we are looking at carefully within the Financial
Stability Board and within the Committee for Supervisory and Regulatory
Co-operation, which I chair. It's one of our most important workstreams
for the next six months. I think the crucial thing, and the first
thing we are going to be doing, is really defining what we think
we mean by this word "shadow banking", because it's
not straightforward.
Q716 <Mr
Mudie: No, no, before you take up time going in
a different direction, I am asking at the moment and in the past
few years how much of the shadow banking market have we or are
we regulating as we sit? It is all right telling us what
Lord Turner: No,
okay, but to answer that I need to first of all quickly define
what we would mean by shadow banking. The shadow banking system
was, in its core, primarily a US phenomenon, although with connections
into the UK. The absolute core of it is a process whereby a chain
connects money market mutual funds, a series of vehicles like
SIVs, conduits and prime broker dealers, and indeed hedge funds
and banks themselves. To begin with, a lot of that was not regulated;
the capital levels of SIVs and conduits were not regulated. The
money market mutual funds, which are not a significant phenomenon
in the UK but were a very big phenomenon in the US, were not regulated.
What they were doing was taking a maturity transformation risk.
Banks take a maturity transformation risk: they have shorter term
liabilities than their assets. Through this chain, that maturity
transformation was occurring. There was a group of American investors
in money market mutual funds who believed that they had money
they could get back immediately, and at the end of a chain there
was a British retail residential mortgage-backed security with
a 20-year loan. If that had occurred within a bank balance sheet,
we would have closely regulated how much of that maturity transformation
was occurring: because it occurred for different steps along the
road, we didn't broadly regulate it.
Q717 <<Mr
Mudie: I think you lost me about five minutes ago,
but that's not hard. Put in percentage terms, I've not heard you
say of the $20 trillion
Lord Turner: Yes,
but I don't recognise the $20 trillion. The trouble is since I
don't know where the figure comes from
Mr Mudie: >That's
a New York Fed research paper of July this year, available on
the net.
Lord Turner: Which
I have read from cover to cover.
Mr Mudie: >Well,
it is in there.
Lord Turner: Yes,
but that is one particular definition. There are other definitions
that
Q718 <Mr
Mudie: No, no, look, we are speaking about regulation
and we're trying to work it out. There is $10 trillion stuff that
we regulate and there is a $20 trillion shadow system. You have
just explained to me what we don't regulate; I've not heard that
we regulate any of that $20 trillion. What percentage, as you've
described it, of the shadow banking exercise do we regulate?
Lord Turner: I'm
afraid I don't think that is a meaningful question and therefore
it is not possible to give a meaningful answer.
Mr Mudie: >Okay,
well don't answer it then.
Lord Turner: I'm
sorry, but the shadow banking system has become much smaller than
it was, we didn't regulate any of it, whatever it was
Mr Mudie: >Well,
it's $15 trillion now. That's again the same research so it's
still considerable.
Mr Sants: I think
we could say this, couldn't we, Adair, if this helps.
Mr Mudie: >It
is still considerable.
Mr Sants: Without
the breakdown of the $20 trillion, I agree with Adair, we wouldn't
want to be over precise but
Mr Mudie: >Well,
what figure would you put on it? Seeing you won't take the Fed's
figure, what figure would you put on? Hector, what figure do you
put on it?
Mr Sants: I would
say the following, what is within the UK's regulatory net we do,
and have always had oversight of. We regulate hedge funds. We
do not have money market funds of the size and the significance
that you see in the US and the remaining small amounts of off-balance
sheet conduits and SIVs owned by the UK banks, where we are the
lead regulator, are visible to us. So there is very little shadow
banking by entities in the UK that doesn't fall broadly into our
oversight regime for prudential and financial stability purposes.
The vast majority of that number will apply to activities outside
of the UK and probably in the US, and until the US have completed
the changes to their regulatory architecture, which includes increased
oversight of hedge funds, it probably remains relatively unregulated
in comparison with the UK. Is that a fair thing to say about it?
Lord Turner: Can
I very quickly
Q719 <Mr
Mudie: I have very little time so I just want to
ask Hector, because you are going to take this up in the future.
So, you're saying to the Treasury Select Committee that it's not
a major problem in Britain and it's well under control from your
organisation's point of view, so we don't have to worry?
Mr Sants: In terms
of the visibility of that which we have regulatory responsibility
for, the answer is yes. That does not mean, of course, that we
might not be systemically affected by events in other parts of
the world where we do not have regulatory responsibility.
Q720 <Mr
Mudie: That is where I come to you, Lord Turner,
because you are involved with the G20. How confident can we bepeople
are losing patience with all the arguments about regulation and
so onthat they have the determination to move on to that?
Lord Turner: I
think reasonably confident, but it requires effort and it requires
work. I can very quickly give you some figures. There is a money
market mutual fund industry in the US; think of it as $3 trillion
or $4 trillion. It wasn't previously regulated; it now has some
regulation. There is a hedge fund industry worldwide; think $2
trillion or $3 trillion. There are debates about whether that
needs to be regulated but we certainly need to oversee it. SIVs
and conduits were $1 trillion or so, but are now much smaller.
I think we have greater control over it, but we need to watch
it very carefully, because what we learnt in the past is that
these things transmute, they mutate in ways that we don't understand.
We failed to see that the broker dealerssuch as Goldman
Sachs and Lehman Brotherswhich were not systemically important
in 1980, were hugely systemically important by 2008. This system
has shrunk quite a lot already. Bits of it are being regulated
that weren't previously regulated, in particular the US money
market funds, but I think we have more work to do to make sure
that we really understand it. That's why it's a key priority for
us to look at now.
Q721 <Chair:
Before I hand over to Stewart Hosie, we have been talking here
about the various ways in which this punchbowl might get full
again. At the moment the punchbowl is very empty, and it is important
to find out if both of you are thinking about ways in which some
normalisation of credit can resume, using macro-prudential tools,
using various weapons that may be available to you. In addition
to the ones we already have in play, do you think that there are
some other things that we should be considering and are you considering
any? In particular, do you think we can have normalisation of
banking conditions without a recovery in the securitisation market?
Lord Turner: The
issue of the supply of credit to the economy is one that we, with
the Bank and the Treasury, have debated at considerable length.
We have done a very careful exercise with all of our banks to
understand what their plans are for the next three yearsthree
years in which they have to repay the Bank of England special
liquidity scheme, meet our new liquidity requirements and to term
out their fundingand what the consequences of that could
be for their lending volumes, and whether those lending volumes
are sufficient to serve the needs of the real economy. That has
been an integrated exercise that we have been at work on and it
has a very detailed set of figures attached to it.
What the analysis suggests is that until now the
supply of credit to the economywhile problematic, perhaps,
in particular areas like SMEsis not significantly different
from what you expect at this stage in a recovery from a recession.
If you look at the pattern of 1993-1994, early stages of a recovery
from a recession are often not particularly credit intensive.
It is also clear, however, that it is at least possible that the
combination of us applying new liquidity requirements and the
Bank requiring the repayment of SLS by early 2012 might constrain
the future pace of credit growth which might be required to support
the economy. The crucial lever we have available in that, which
we have debated with our tripartite colleagues, is to think carefully
about the pace of the application of our new liquidity standards.
We have twice this year communicated that we are not switching
on those liquidity standards immediately until there is an assured
pace of recovery. So, to that extent we are taking into account
those credit conditions.
Chair: >That
is an important and well rehearsed argument.
Lord Turner: That
is the single biggest lever we have.
Q722 <Chair:
My specific question was whether we can have a
recovery without a recovery in securitisation?
Lord Turner: On
the securitisation, I think we can have it without securitisation.
It would be easier with securitisation; on the other hand I think
we have to be realistic. Quite a lotand this does relate
to the previous issue about shadow bankingof what was previously
securitisation was based upon unsafe forms of maturity transformation
and is not coming back.
Q723 <Chair:
What proportion? What was good and what was bad?
What have we lost that we'd rather not have lost?
Lord Turner: I'm
afraid the vast majority of the UK securitisation pattern was
based upon a particular set of investors that were not sustainable.
Very quickly, if I can draw the distinction: if it had been the
case that UK residential mortgages, which are essentially 20-year
assets, were ending up being securitised and ending up in the
hands of the natural buyers of long-term assetspension
funds, insurance companiesthen you would have a sustainable
non-bank form of mortgage credit intermediation. That was hardly
what was occurring at all. Almost all of UK RMBS was, through
a series of chains, ending up in the hands often of US investors
who at the end of that chain thought that they had a short-term
asset. That was something that I think no amount of transparency
and better regulation is going to make come back, because it was
risky.
Chair: >You
have given me a clear answer, and if you have further substance
you want to add to it in writing we would be interested to see
it.
Lord Turner: I would be very happy
to do it.
Q724 <Stewart
Hosie: I have a number of questions about structure
and staffing of the new bodies, but can I just go back to something
you said about the future? You said, Hector, that it wasn't about
stopping banks and financial institutions failing, it was about
stopping failure without cost. I take it you mean failure without
systemic risk, as opposed to cost?
Mr Sants: And also
cost to the taxpayer.
Q725 <Stewart
Hosie: Fine. So that means you would not have put
£37 billion into Bradford & Bingley because their failure
wasn't systemic? You'd have let them fail?
Mr Sants: Exactly
right. If you had a regime, which the US to a degree had, that
enabled a bank to fail with the cost of that failure being borne
only by those who had subscribed the capital, and therefore did
so knowing that there was a potential cost if it failed, that
should be acceptable to Society. If you can have a failure where
the cost only falls on those who provided the capital and there
is no adverse impact to the rest of the system for systemic purposes
and no adverse impact to the consumers and users of those bank
accountstheir bank accounts are transferred over to another
bank, for example, I would say going forward that the PRA would
not see that as a failure of the PRA. It is reasonable to have
a system where failure of that nature occurs because without the
opportunity for that sort of failure you do not get risk and innovation.
Q726 <Stewart
Hosie: Fine, and the same would apply to Northern
Rock and Dunfermline?
Mr Sants: Quite
so. In the US hundreds of banks fail all the time and normally
this is not considered to be a regulatory failure. The consumers
are not inconvenienced and historically the costs have not fallen
any further than the providers of capital.
Stewart Hosie: >I
just wanted to get that clarified.
Mr Sants: I think
it would be very helpful if people understand that, in terms of
judging the PRA going forward, that is the right way to judge
it.
Q727 <Stewart
Hosie: Thank you, it is helpful to get that on
the record. Can I ask some questions about how we move forward
now? The Government in their consultation said that whenever the
CPMA disagrees with the PRA, the PRA's decision would be finalreflecting
the important role of prudential judgement in the delivery of
regulation. Do you agree with that?
Mr Sants: Broadly
speaking, yes. I think there is a risk that that sort of language
creates some notion or idea that somehow or another the CPMA is
a secondary authority. That would be wrong and if that impression
gains ground that would be very unfortunate, and we should try
to avoid that. But the point of substance is that conduct risk
can evolve into prudential risk. For example, as we've discussed
in this Committee in the past, mis-selling can obviously lead
to prudential risk through the build-up of poor quality assets
on the balance sheet, and it can also be a very important lead
indicator of poor cultures, which can lead to prudential mismanagement.
So there is a clear interaction between conduct regulation and
prudential regulation.
There is also interaction at the systemic level where
you can envisage certain circumstances where a closure of a bank
might have systemic implications, for the reasons we have just
discussed. In those circumstances, and those circumstances alone,
it is right that the CPMA should have to consult before taking
an action with the PRA and, if the action it was taking was deemed
by the PRA to have systemic implications, it is reasonable that
the PRA should have an override. We all know that the cost of
this crisis has been multiples of any single mis-selling event
and therefore, in terms of the impact on society as whole, systemic
failure is the most costly.
Q728 <Stewart
Hosie: I'll come back to this perception of the
CPMA as a secondary body in a moment, but what you've just said
would lead us to conclude presumably that consumer protection
would always be compromised in order to protect the integrity
of the financial system, if there was a conflict between the micro-prudential
and the systemic and the consumer?
Mr Sants: It depends
how you view consumer protection. I think it would be reasonable.
Obviously it is a matter for Parliament, but I would say it would
be reasonable for Parliament to make the judgement that systemic
failure is a failure that affects consumers. If, at the end of
the day, what we want is a market that works for consumers in
the round, that should include avoiding systemic failure. But
you're right: the judgement has to be that systemic failure is
bad news for consumers. I happen to think systemic failure is
very bad news for consumers, and therefore that is something that
the regulatory system should try to protect consumers against.
Q729 <Stewart
Hosie:I agree entirely, systemic failure is catastrophic
for everybody, including consumers, but there is a perception
in the real worldnot on this Committeethat this
is once again Government and regulators looking after the banks
with the consumer deemed or seen to be a poor second to the big
picture of this.
Mr Sants: Yes,
I think that's an educational challenge for Parliament and the
regulators over the coming months to get over the point that we
have just exchanged views on. I think that we're broadly in agreement:
this is not about a structure where consumers are second choice
or coming off second best. It's about creating a structure where
consumers are at the forefront and that is designed to give the
best possible result for consumers.
We had a discussion earlier on about the benefits
of change and everybody was relating it back to the question,
"Does this mean the crisis wouldn't have occurred again?"
I personally think that the biggest opportunity is not just about
trying to avoid a repeat of the crisis: it's about taking the
opportunity of change to improve the deal for consumers. So it's
really important that the CPMA comes forward with an improved
set of powers, relative to what the FSA has had, and that there
is a real opportunity here to improve the lot of consumers.
Q730 <Stewart
Hosie: That's helpful, but you're going to have
to have high quality staff in the CPMA. Given that there is this
perception at least that it may be a secondary body, and the CPMA,
as you said in a previous answer, would have to consult with the
PRA, how will you bring the right staff into the CPMA to do what
is a very important role in its own right, while it seems to be
playing second fiddle to the PRA?
Mr Sants: This is a really important
point, I think, and Adair wants to add something in a moment,
but I think that is a clear challenge. As I've just said, in normal
market conditions there is a tremendous opportunity here for the
CPMA to make a real difference to society and that, I hope, would
appeal to individuals and provide a compelling reason for them
to want to work in the organisation.
Certainly, within the FSA, broadly speaking,
we have yetwe still have 18 months to goto settle
on the final numbers, but it's going to be something in the order
of two-thirds of the FSA staff will be in the CPMA. The PRA will
be a much smaller entity than the CPMA, and the general reaction
of staff within the FSA is one of excitement about an opportunity
to deliver a better result for consumers than we have had in the
past. So I think there are lots of people out there who are very
interested in improving conditions for consumers.
Q731 <Stewart
Hosie: I'm glad staff are excited, but in your
written evidence you were speaking about how the problems might
be mitigated through people strategies and good initiatives such
as secondments between the PRA and CPMA. Does this not really
say people are going to serve a bit of time in the CPMA and hope
they're very quickly going to get the move to the organisation
they really want to go to?
Mr Sants: I don't think so, no.
Lord Turner: I don't think that
is going to be the case. We are well aware that the FSA board
and executive has to achieve two things over the next year and
a half to two years, one of which is to divide off the PRA which
will become part of the Bank. The other is to create what is the
bigger successor body, which is the CPMA, and we are now going
through a process of selecting a chief executive-designate for
that, who we will have in place some time in the spring. It is
quite an exciting opportunity to create a new body that gives
consumer protection its own distinct focus. I don't think it is
going to be seen as a second-best organisation at all, but certainly
that is something that we are aware we need to dispel any belief
about. I think it's more a belief that we hear expressed in meetings
like this or from the press: it's not something that I think we
feel within the organisation ourselvesthe secondment thing.
Q732 <Stewart
Hosie: You said, "We envisage there being
some difficulty in attracting and retaining specialist prudential
advice in the CPMA which will continue to have some prudential
responsibilities."
Lord Turner: This is a very specific
point about prudential advice.
Stewart Hosie:
Indeed. I make the point that those are your words.
Lord Turner: Okay, but they are
related to a very particular set of skills, yes.
Stewart Hosie:
We are probing this. That's important.
Lord Turner: I understand, yes.
Mr Sants: There
is a particular point which that submission highlighted that the
CPMA is not just a conduct regulator. It is also proposed that
it will be a prudential regulator for those firms that the PRA
is not the prudential regulator forthe non-banks and insurers.
Within that context, there is potentially somewhat
of an issue that that expertise could feel subordinated to the
core activity of the CPMA, which is conduct regulation, and therefore
we will want to make sure that there is plenty of expertise exchanged
between the prudential regulatorthe PRAand those
people doing prudential regulation in the CPMA. But that was not
a comment about the whole of the CPMA.
Q733 <Stewart
Hosie: Let me just ask a final question then. We
do know the prudential and consumer are not unrelated: they are
linked, of course they are. What will you do in practice to ensure
there is proper co-ordination between the two bodies, not rivalry,
and that we don't create another crack or an underlap, as we've
had in previous architectures?
Mr Sants: This is undoubtedly
a major challenge and it is the principal risk in the new system,
which everybody has rightly identified. I think we have to work
hard at this. There are a couple of obvious measures to be taken.
First, wherever possible we should continue to retain common standards
of regulation and a clear interaction between the CPMA and the
PRA in articulating those standards. So, for example, in the authorisations
process, where we have a requirement for probity, we should not
be having one judgment of probity being different to the other
from the two organisations. So there needs to be convergence where
standards are common.
Secondly, which I think is the principal action
that needs to be taken, we need to ensure that in terms of oversight
of individual firms that we put in place some structural co-ordination
mechanisms through formal MOUs and do not rely on informal processes
and rely on the fact that at least initially the staff will have
all worked in one organisation in the first place, which will
obviously help. We need to institutionalise the requirement to
co-operate and, as the Government's document indicated, we would
envisageto use regulatory speakcolleges for the
larger firms that are supervised by the CPMA and the PRA. I think
we need some structured obligations for interaction and communication.
We need to make sure as well, of course, that firms don't feel
we're building an inefficient process, thus we'll need to have
common interfaces for collecting data, a common data set and so
on. So we'll need a set of structural processes as well as hard-working
communication at the senior management level.
Q734 Mark Garnier: My
questions are to Hector Sants, and before I start can I set you
the challenge of brief and pithy answers, if I may, because I
think we're running a bit short of time. Following on from this
and also from Andrea Leadsom's questions a bit earlier, if we
follow your reasoning about what keeps you awake at nightthat
risk is going to be pushed to the consumer rather than to the
manager of riskwhat do you think that is going to make
the next crisis look like?
Mr Sants: Well, of course, if
I knew precisely the answer to that, we would be taking anticipatory
action now. I think that, as I say, at the end of the day a financial
crisis ultimately has to be linked to the build-up of risk somewhere
in the system. That is the intrinsic nature of a financial crisis.
It will be the build-up of risk somewhere, either that is not
fully visible to the regulatory system, or that is visible but
they have misjudged the level of risk or do not have the appetite
to make an intervention, which is the
Q735 Mark Garnier: So,
following that, that is absolutely where the risk goes to the
consumer, because that could be hidden risk because you can't
see into that. So, the crisis is going to come to the consumer,
which is a lot of personal crises as opposed to huge crises that
can be dealt with by the state; personal crises aren't quite so
easy to deal with. Does that mean that the CPMA, rather than the
PRA, are going to be attempting to mitigate this risk and how
are they going to do it?
Mr Sants: I think, at the end
of the day, if consumers have built up financial risk they will
do so through the owning of financial products; a mortgage, an
investment product and so forth; and The CPMA must therefore equip
itself to fully have the required information and data and to
understand the risk that the consumer is owning. So, that takes
us back to the earlier discussion about having a transparent markets
process, a good clearing process, a good data process. Secondly,
it must have a mechanism of intervention, which is where I think
the earlier intervention on the product side
Q736 Mark Garnier: Risk
is not just about owning one product: it could be owning a number
of contradictory products. You can have a mortgage, which in itself
is fairly straightforward, but then you can have an overdraft
and a credit card. Each one of those individually is not a problem,
but you put all of them together and you've got a colossal problem
for a family or a household. How are you going to deal with that?
That's how I see risk being pushed down to the consumer and I
don't see how you are going to deal with this.
Mr Sants: That's a mixture of
two. The CPMA intervention would be on a product-specific basis
and a product-design basis, but the aggregate riskssorry,
we're back round in the circle again to our FPC discussionthat
would be for the FPC to intervene, using the various mechanisms
that we've already described. So I'm just making the point it's
a twin process.
Q737 Mark Garnier: I'm
trying to move on. Has the CPMA got the tools to deal with your
element of it and what tools do you think they are going to
Mr Sants: The CPMA, if it only
inherits the FSA's tools, does not have sufficient tools.
Mark Garnier: So you'd need more finance?
Mr Sants: We need powers of product
intervention. At the moment the FSA's powers, in the round, are
essentially to make a rule, which then would ban a product, but
you have to go through a whole process in order to make the rule.
If Parliament wants a genuinely interventionist, powerful CPMA,
which is seen as powerful, then it needs the power to make executive-driven,
direct interventions to ban products.
Q738 Mark Garnier: In
response to one of Stewart's questions, you said that your staff
are excited by the opportunity for better results for consumers.
Let's turn to RDR, because there has been a lot of controversy
about RDR among the IFA community. You set out to try and, "Improve
the clarity with which firms describe their services to consumers;
address the potential for adviser remuneration to distort consumer
outcomes; and improve advisers' professional standards."
Have you achieved that?
Mr Sants: Well, since the RDR
is not yet in force of course we can't answer that question. We
believe that the measures we have laid out for implementation
through the RDR process will broadly do that. I think it is fair
to say, however, over the lifetime of the RDR, which traces its
life back to Adair's predecessor who made a speech about some
of the failings in the consumer market, it has become more focused
and more realistic in its intent. We've laid out very clearly
our intention to have a transparent and fairer charging system,
a better qualification framework for advisers and greater clarity
around the type of advice that is being offered.
So, the RDR is set to deliver three specific
elements that would contribute to, overall, a better regime for
investors. I think the measures we've laid out, when they are
in place and implemented, will deliver those three specific outcomes.
I do not think you should characterise the RDR as the panacea
to the investment market and the solution that is going to lead
to a new savings culture and a fundamental change in the marketplace.
Q739 Mark Garnier: I think
a lot of people would agree with that. What do you think was then
behind themoneymarket.co.uk's article on 16 July saying that the
FSA at a board meeting had discussed scrapping RDR?
Mr Sants: I'm not aware of that
article. We have not discussed scrapping RDR so I think it's media
speculation.
Mark Garnier: So all these reports about
you potentially scrapping RDR?
Lord Turner: I can assure you
that there has been no discussion at any board meeting of scrapping
the RDR.
Mark Garnier: Fantastic.
Lord Turner: And in fact I wasn't
aware of the article, so I didn't even know the statement had
been made.
Q740 Mark Garnier: I will
get it forwarded to you. The other really important point about
this is that the cost-benefit analysis was originally talking
about £400 million cost; it has now gone to £1.7 billion.
Now, let's leave aside the massive cost overruns that this has
introduced
Mr Sants: If I may, it's not a
cost overrun, just to be quite clear for the record. An FSA cost-benefit
analysis invites the industry to tell us how much they think it
will cost to implement a measure. The judgment of how much that
is is made by us on the basis of the industry feedback. The initial
consultation of the industry came up with the first number you
mentioned: in subsequent consultations, the industry revised their
estimates of cost. So those are cost estimates made by the industry
to the FSA. Any suggestion that is the FSA's direct cost, which
has not been managed, is obviously a complete misunderstanding
of the story.
Q741 Mark Garnier: I absolutely
stand corrected. I stand corrected and I'm glad you put that on
record. Nonetheless, what you are effectively doing is taking
£1.7 billion out of the savings pool, because this is going
to be borne directly by savers. Here we are in a country where
I think we have the lowest savings ratio of the G20, we have the
highest personal debt in the G20an average of £28,000
per personand the FSA, which is a regulator but is also
there to help the savings market, has effectively sucked £1.7
billion out of that savings market. Is that a good thing for the
FSA to have done?
Mr Sants: I think, as you say,
it's a judgment and we have to make that judgment in the round.
What we are looking atand I think it will be the same data
as you're looking atis that we know that over the years
there have been some very significant consumer mis-selling events,
pensions, mortgages and so on. These, in total, have added up
to many billions; £13 billion is one particular estimate.
We have also, which I think is maybe more pertinent to the direct
issue of RDR, done some sampling of the degree of mis-selling
that we can estimate in respect of smaller, more regular events
and we've come up with an estimate of around £250 million
per year. We have some other data that suggests that's an under-estimate;
it's probably more like £0.5 billion or so. The RDR is estimated
to cost, in terms of ongoing cost, around £200 million a
year; your £1.4 billion to £1.7 billion range includes
a set of one-off costs of some £700 million. So we're looking
at an estimate of the annual benefit it would bring, in normal
circumstances, of a multiple above what we think the annual costs
to the industry are.
Mark Garnier: Assuming it works.
Mr Sants: Assuming it works but,
of course, we have to make that judgment and we've done it on
the basis, I think, of some thorough analysis and the knowledge
that there are some very big events out there that completely
dwarf the annual running costs. So, I think that's a fair judgment
for us to make this time around and the numbers we've laid out
there do support it.
Lord Turner: I think it is a very
good challenge. It clearly is concerning when there is a large
cost from the FSA itself, or from the compliance costs that we
impose upon an industry, that must come from consumers at the
end of the day, but the starting point is a system where pretty
much everybody is agreed that we don't have a very good retail
financial distribution system to start with.
When I did the work that I did on the Pension
Commission it was quite clear that the sales of personal pensions,
to take one product, were involving a completely harmful degree
of churn where people were just churning through different products
from different providers because the commission bias, under which
IFAs were operating, was providing them with incentives to do
so. We did analysis that showed that very significant proportions
of people's total pension pot, by the time they got to retirement,
had disappeared in the reduction in yield from all the different
costs that were created by this system. I think it was why, when
Callum McCarthy gave his speech that announced this, he said we
have a system which pretty much everybody was agreed didn't work
particularly well for the consumers or for the producers, because
there was so much cost going in the administrative and selling
costs.
We are trying to get to a more sensible system
and I think at the core of that, the absolute core, is that the
removal of producer commissions must be a sensible thing to do
because the fact that people or intermediaries are paid by producer
commissions is an extraordinary incentive for churn in activities,
which is wasted money. So we're trying to end up with a system
that has less wasted money, but the fact is we start with a system
where a depressingly large amount of people's savings is disappearing
in the intermediary and administrative costs.
Hector, you also wanted to make a point and a quick
reply.
Mr Sants: The biggest bit of the
ongoing cost burden results from the change in the commission
structure. Almost all our submissions from consumer groups are
very, very supportive of banning the practice of being paid by
the manufacturer of your product which must put bias into the
selling process. So the main cost change is in relation to the
main detriment, where I would say there is very strong support
from consumers for change.
Q742 Mark Garnier: I completely
accept there are a number of good things about RDR and it would
be wrong to completely say it's all rubbish, because generally
a lot of it is good. However, amongst the IFA community there
is a reasonable proportion, about 30% or so, who are outraged
by what's happening and find it very difficult and there's a significant
proportion of that 30% that are now considering completely coming
out of that industry altogether. Do you feel that that is an acceptable
cost to implement RDR?
Mr Sants: Well we obviously have
looked closely at this issue. We have some data that suggested
more like a 10 to 20% reduction in capacity could flow from the
RDR measures. We've obviously deemed that to be acceptable or
we wouldn't be going ahead. But in my experience in the lobbying
process you tend to get fairly extreme statements made, which
don't necessarily always come about in practice.
Lord Turner: But we shouldn't
exclude the possibility that some exit of capacity from the industry,
which is therefore also an exit of administrative costs, may be
in the interest of consumers. That's a cost that is being absorbed,
isn't it?
Mark Garnier: I put on the record I disagree
with that.
Q743 Mr Love: Mr Sants,
we've discussed this morning all the complexities of the structural
reform that we're talking about and now that the consultation
is finished, that may be tweaked in some way. We're just about
to go on to talk about mismatch in Europe and the challenges that
face you regarding that. You have a major programme of activity:
we've talked about RDR; there's a mortgage market review. And
against that backdrop, you're having some staff retention problems.
Are you going to be able to complete this structural reform by
2012, facing all of those challenges?
Mr Sants: Yes, but it is very
difficult, for the reasons you've outlined.
Q744 Mr Love: Can I ask
you then because, Lord Turner, you said in an article that there
are some risks to business as usual from bringing in this structural
reform: where do you see the real challenges that you face to
bring it in by 2012?
Lord Turner: The challenges, which
were extensively discussed by the board two weeks ago on the basis
of very detailed presentations from the executive, are essentially
these. A process of organisational change will absorb the time
of many of our major managers. For instance, they will have to
sit down with people and discuss with them where they are going
in the new organisation and where they want to go. They will have
to design training programmes and some people may challenge where
they are going to go. Those processes, those actual personnel
processes of selection and decision and challenge, simply take
time anybody will tell you thatand that is taking
key resources away from business as usual activity. That's a fact.
The crucial thing then is to plan that out very
clearly, and we were discussing two weeks ago very clear plans
to make sure that we have thought through whether there are things
that can be temporarily de-emphasised, either on the policy side
or on some of the issues to do with frequency of supervision for
some of the lower risk authorised firms, which will free up that
resource that is required. It varies according to the different
bits of the organisation. There are some bits of the organisation
where essentially they will, what we call, lift and shift. Pretty
much the whole of our prudential policy division we know is going,
in its entirety, to that side.
Mr Love: Excuse me for interrupting.
Lord Turner: But there are others
where there is a major split, that's what we have to manage.
Q745 Mr Love: Excuse me
for interrupting you, but we are limited in time.
Lord Turner: Yes, sure.
Mr Love: I wanted to focus specifically,
since you're talking about staff retention, on the financial stability
division, which has two major problems. First of all, the head
has announced that he's leaving and, secondly, this is the part
that will merge with the Bank of England, and therefore there's
a possibility of redundancies; let's say there's uncertainty about
the future. How are you coping with that and is that a major strain
on you?
Lord Turner: It's not a major
strain at the moment. We are sad to lose the head, David Strachan,
but there are very good people beneath him. We are continuing
to do our work in that area. We are continuing to head towards,
for instance, our prudential risk outlook in the spring. The work
that they are doing is of very high quality. We will, with that
group of people, have to be completely honest about the fact that
there may be some overlap with the Bank of England and we will
have to manage that through.
But I can assure you at the moment that is not
an area where I would be worried about interruption to business
as usual. I would be more worried about interruption to business
as usual in our core supervisory teams where what we have to do
is split them in two and decide who is going which way. That's
where we are more concerned and really focusing to make sure that
things don't slip through the cracks.
Q746 Mr Love: Mr Sants,
can I ask you the first question by a roundabout route. Say you
complete it by 2012, will there be so many stresses and strains
within the organisation that you won't function to an optimal
level in terms of regulation?
Mr Sants: Clearly between now
and 2012, as Adair has just laid out in some detail so I won't
go back over that again, we have a finite number of people and
they are going to have to do an additional task in that period.
The additional task in that period is this reorganisation. Reorganisations
are very time consuming. We have to prioritise delivering that
reorganisation in order to hit the 2012 deadline, which I believe
we can do, but if we prioritise carrying out the reorganisation
that involves partly, for the reasons you have just said about
staff uncertainty, managers spending a lot of time internallyputting
staff at the forefront of their mindsthen there will be
less time to carry out other functions.
The main activity of the FSA is frontline supervision.
Relatively speaking, if we look at our activity breakdown, we
are a micro-prudential regulator. We spend the bulk of our time
on day-to-day supervision, not on designing new policies. We are
in fact trying to do as little as possible by the way of new initiatives,
other than those mandated to us by Europe. So we will do somewhat
less supervision in that period, but we will make that judgement
on a risk basis and seek to make sure we mitigate the adverse
effects. But it obviously necessarily follows that if we are doing
something extra we do a bit less elsewhere.
Q747 Mr Love: That's very
helpful. I want to switch now back to an answer you gave to John
Thurso in relation to the mortgage market review and it's this
hoary old question about appropriate regulation. Do you think,
in terms of where you've gone so far, you've hit the right button
in terms of appropriate, because the accusation has been made
that it's too onerous?
Lord Turner: We are very aware
of the need, as we bring the mortgage market review to conclusion
over the next several months, to really step back and to think
very carefully about this balance, and this is one of our highest
priorities over the next few months, to get this right. It is
a matter of balance. If we protect some people against taking
on board unsustainable mortgage commitments, at the margin somewhere
else we'll constrain somebody's right to take on board a mortgage
commitment that might have been affordable: that's almost necessarily
the case. We are looking at it very carefully and we will be conducting
a complete economic analysis of all the proposals before launching
the specific proposal next year.
But I would make two points. Can I quickly make
two points? First, easy credit supply is not necessarily good
for first-time buyers. One of the features that occurred in the
mortgage market up to 2008 is a gradual fall in the percentage
of credit going to first-time buyers as more and more of it went
to remortgages and mortgage equity withdrawal, where the easy
supply of credit, by driving up the price of houses, was actually
making it more difficult for first-time buyers to get into the
market. So the somewhat easy assumption that easy credit is good
for first-time buyers is not necessarily the case. That's point
one.
Secondly, there was a clear tail of very harmful
lending that occurred before the crisis, extending it to people
who could not afford it and that is why, for instance, from people
like Shelter and Citizens Advice there is strong support emerging
to say don't compromise on the FSA proposals, which is balancing
the argument from the other side of the industry of saying we've
got it wrong. We are very well aware of the need to strike a balance.
We'll be thinking very carefully about it and we will communicate
very carefully the balance we've struck and the macroeconomic
analysis.
I called last year for a very open public debate
about this. It's one of the most important decisions we've got
to make and we're not going to rush it.
Q748 Mr Love: You mentioned
about the tail, which you estimate, as I understand it, to be
about 5% but the mortgage companies are suggesting much higher,
some of them dramatically higher figures. The accusation that
they are making is that you're not putting any responsibility
on the consumer, and that all the responsibility, not only to
carry out affordability tests but also to make an assessment of
the consumers' ability to pay, they consider that very onerous
and they're likely, they claimand I'm not one to put words
in anyone's mouththat that will mean a withdrawal from
the marketplace. How do you respond to those concerns?
Lord Turner: We don't think there
will be a major restriction of mortgage credit. You have to always
distinguish here. It may be that at the margin some people will
only be able to borrow on an 85% LTV, not a 90% LTV, but that's
different from somebody not being able to get a mortgage at all,
and that gets mixed up in these figures claiming that 50% will
be affected. So we are looking at it very carefully.
On the basic concept of assessing affordability,
most of the major lenders believe that that is something they
should do because it's something they should be interested in.
They shouldn't be interested in writing a loan contract where
the person can't afford to pay it back, because that's just going
to produce arrears and repossessions down the line. So I don't
think the concept of affordability assessment is being challenged.
It's simply how we get the correct calibration of how significant
the constraints should be, how tight they should be.
In particular, on crucial issues like when you
offer somebody a mortgage at 3.5%, how much should you stress
the interest rate to deal with the fact that it might go up in
the future? That's something where we haven't been definitive
yet and accordingly, as you flex that, that's the sort of thing
that either produces a big effect or a small effect. We are going
to think very carefully about that in the final stages of this
consideration.
Chair: You can come back
to all this. A quick further question from Andy.
Q749 <Mr
Love: I wanted to get this question in, and it
goes back to something that John Thurso said, the interaction
between these consumer protection measures and macro-prudential
tools. Have you given any thought to how they would interact with
each other? If you go more on the consumer protection, does that
inevitably mean that we won't need to use the macro-prudential
tools as much?
Lord Turner: We
are not seeing what we are doing within the FSA's mortgage market
review as focused on the macro-prudential side, and that is why
it is focused on the tail of bad lending rather than the general
supply of lending. So we're not intending, in the mortgage market
review, to do things that would, as it were, have slowed down
the across-the-board growth of credit in 2004 to 2007. That is
a separate set of tools that have to be discussed by the Financial
Policy Committee. Obviously there has to be a joining up, which
is why the future chief executive of the CPMA is rightly one of
the members of the Financial Policy Committee. But we do see these
as complementary, and we do not see the tools that we are intending
to put in place on the mortgage market review as addressing the
wider issue of the through-the-cycle variation in the overall
supply of credit. That would be more countercyclical capital requirements,
or perhaps LTV or LTI constraints.
Q750 <John
Mann: Thank you, Chairman. I will not be seeking
to catch your eye again in this hearing.
I do have three questions and possibly a supplementary,
particularly on the last question. First, I wanted to pick up
your answer, Lord Turner, to Mr Mudie on what I thought was a
very important issue, where you statedI think I have this
down accuratelythat the FSA didn't realise the systemic
risk from investment banking. Talking in confidence to FSA insiders,
as I have been doing, I put to you that that's not accurate, that
in fact the situation inside the FSA and the discussions that
you had were not that you did not appreciate the systemic risk
from investment banking, but that you truly did not anticipate
the extent of the systemic risk: perhaps more fundamentally, you
didn't know what to do about the systemic risk with investment
banking. I put it to you that investment banking is fiercely competitive
in some areas, but there is no competition whatsoever in other
areas. The big question being asked is "are banks too big
to fail?" Isn't the more pertinent question "are investment
banks too big to regulate?"
Lord Turner: I'm
not sure I agree with what you're saying there, because I do think
the fundamental problem was a failure across the world to understand
what was going on in the area that spans investment banking, securitisation
and the shadow banking system, but that of course includes the
trading activities of major commercial banks. Let's be clear at
this point, the trading activities of UBS, which is a commercial
bank, were as relevant to this as a standalone investment bank
like Lehman Brothers or Goldman Sachs. I think there was a failure
to put together the bits of the jigsaw puzzle and to realise that
once there were things going on in the money market mutual funds,
the SIVs, the conduits, the trading books, the investment banks
and the broker dealers themselves, the totality of the system
had a set of risks that people didn't understand. Indeed, let's
be clear, it's not just that they didn't understand it: there
was a very overt philosophy, attached in particular to Alan Greenspan
but set out in documents, that you didn't need to understand how
it all fitted together because you could have confidence that
the free market was bound to disperse risk so that it would be
constrained. I can point to bits of IMF documents that say that.
So, I am not sure that it was the case that there
were a whole load of people looking at it. Obviously you then
have a matter of degree, but there was a failure to understand
how this new system of credit supply all fitted together. Remember
in the US, the pure play investment banksthe five banks
that did existthey really did escape prudential regulation,
because they were regulated by the SEC, which is not by its nature
a prudential regulator, it's a conduct regulator.
Q751 <John
Mann: I'm sure that we'll be keeping a very close
eye on both whether there is competition, and whether there is
any real regulation of investment banking.
Let me come to you, Mr Sants. When did you warn the
Treasury about the seriousness of our exposure to the Irish economy?
Mr Sants: I am
going to have to give you a written answer on precisely when the
first meeting on Ireland was, but it was a long time ago. This
is not something that has suddenly sprung on us, for the reasons
that Adair outlined in terms of his analysis of what is underlying
in the Irish crisis. I'm trying to think when our first Irish
meeting
Lord Turner: I
would imagine probably the tail end of 2008.
Mr Sants: Yes,
2008 or something like that. It is a long time ago that goes right
back into the depths of the crisis; I would guess 2008 some time.
Q752 <John
Mann: During the last three or four months, how
much have you been warning the Treasury?
Mr Sants: I think
warning the Treasury is probably not the right description of
events. I think all elements of the tripartite system, the Treasury,
the Bank of England and the FSA, have nearly continuous meetings
and discussion on this subject for the last 12 or 15 months. There
is always work going on in the FSA on Irish banks. That information
is regularly communicated to the Treasury and we are doing it
jointly with the Bank of England. So, because it is such a longstanding
issue, it is something that is now embedded in our work as business
as usual. It is reviewed regularly in all the deputies meetings,
and principals meetings.
Q753 <John
Mann: So the Government has had good time to plan
its decision making then in relation to the Irish banks. Are there
any other economies where you are warning about our exposure,
for example Portugal or Spain, at the moment?
Lord Turner: The
situation on our exposure to Portugal and Spain I would say is
as follows. In both of those we again had relatively little exposure
to sovereign bonds. In general around Europe, the major exposures
to sovereign bonds by banking systems are not in the UK. You can
see that from the results of the CEBS stress test earlier this
year, which revealed significant sovereign bond exposure of some
of the continental banks but not the UK banks. We do have one
bank that has a non-trivial involvement in mortgages in Spain,
because it has a business in that area. Those will, of course,
depend upon the quality of those mortgages. Some of them, although
they're in Spain are, of course, to British citizens who have
taken out mortgages to buy second properties. But the scale is
not on the same scale as the Irish exposure. We do not have the
same equivalent of RBS owing a large Irish bank.
John Mann:>
I appreciate that. Let me
Mr Sants: Eurozone
issues have been a regular part of our stress testing supervisory
approach to the UK banks for well over 12 months now.
Q754 <John
Mann: Mr Sants, didn't you think it appropriate,
considering that British taxpayers are having now to bail out
Ireland and Irish banks, that the Chairman of this Committee should
be alerted to the seriousness of your concerns?
Mr Sants: First
of all, I think to be quite clear, it is not a result of the failure
of UK regulated entities among the UK banks that has led to the
Irish banking crisis. That is a matter for the Irish regulator
and
Q755 <John
Mann: No, but we're involved in the bailout and
there is a specific link between this Committee and yourselves.
Considering the seriousness of the situation and the seriousness
of the advice that you have been giving to the Treasury, did you
not think that this Committeeat least the Chairman, whether
in confidence or notought to be alerted to the situation
where the British taxpayers are being asked to bail out Ireland
and Irish banks?
Mr Sants: The decision
to bail out Irish banks or the contribution to the Irish package
is a decision for Government not for the FSA. As I understand
it from the public announcements that have been madethe
decision takes into account a number of other factors, including
our export/import relationship with the Irish economy, and no
doubt other factors of which I'm not awarethis is not a
specific regulatory intervention.
Lord Turner: Can
I just make one other point? The fact that RBS has a large exposure
to Ireland has been obvious to anybody who picks up an RBS annual
report and realises that it owns Ulster Bank. This is not something
that, as it were, the FSA has to discover and reveal to people.
It's an obvious matter of public record that follows from the
ownership of Ulster Bank, which, as I say, before RBS bought NatWest,
was owned by NatWest for decades.
Q756 <John
Mann: Yes, but it may be a surprise to the British
taxpayer to have to fund it. But let me ask you a different question
on a different issue, Lord Turner. You have been in post since
September 2008. Isn't it the case that you have taken your eye
off the ball when it comes to what is happening in Europe and
European regulation, and as a result of that we have not been
winning the battles when it comes to European regulation?
Lord Turner: No,
I don't think that is the case. We have been focused very clearly
on the European regulatory environment and many of the things
that have occurred in Europe we have strongly supported. There
have been debates, for instance, about the alternative investment
fund management directive about things to do with passports and
so on, but it includes within it the powers for the regulator
to gather information to understand where prudential risks are
emerging, which are precisely what we require to keep track of
the shadow banking system. That has not been something imposed
on us: that is something we've argued for. We are coming forward
with European capital requirement directives, which are the expression
into European law of precisely the things that we have been involved
in agreeing in detail at the Basel Committee on a global basis.
Now, of course, when things happen in European law, people may
add bits of the agenda that we don't like, but the broad thrust
has been things that we're arguing for.
Q757 <John
Mann: Why then is ESMA based in Paris and why do
we have only one seat on ESMA?
Lord Turner: ESMA
is based in Paris because CESA, which existed before, is based
in Paris, and because CEBS, which will become the European Banking
Authority, is based in London. A deal was done a long time ago
that said there were three main committees, which are now three
main authorities, and they are in Paris, London and Frankfurt.
Q758 <John
Mann: Yes, but some people might agree more with
me that you have not had your eye properly on this issue. For
example, Peter Clarke of the Man Group says, "The UK's bargaining
position in Europe has been impaired". Mr Rolet, head of
the Stock Exchange, goes much further: "The regulatory environment
probably sows the seeds for the next crisis". That is pretty
stark coming from the head of the Stock Exchange. Basically, Europe
has trampled all over us while we have been restructuring in this
country, hasn't it?
Lord Turner: No,
I don't think that is true at all, and I don't think there is
any evidence to suggest that, whatsoever.
Mr Sants: The European
regulatory structure that is now being implemented from the beginning
of next year was decided through a full European process, which
is primarily one determined by governments rather than regulators,
long before the proposal to restructure the UK environment was
proposed. These decisions pre-date this entire debate we're having.
These decisions were made in 2008 to 2009, not in 2010.
Q759 <John
Mann: So you disagree with Mark Hoban when he says
that we've been losing the arguments in Europe?
Lord Turner: We
do not think that we have been losing the arguments in Europe.
You win some, you lose some; that is the nature of the European
debate, and it always has been, and it will be the case whoever
is the Government in power. We have been working with Europe to
achieve some re-regulation of our financial system, and I'm a
bit surprised to hear you totally supporting those who favour
a completely light touch approach against the bad European imposition.
I'm slightly interested
Q760 <John
Mann: I'm asking the question because Government
has made changes to our structures. A lot of time and effort has
been spent on them. They don't come in until 2012, but Europe
is up and running with its regulation in a month's time.
Lord Turner: Some
of which are direct responses to problems that we have. Let's
be clear that the problem of the Icelandic banks revealed to us
that a single market in financial services can be a very dangerous
thing, unless there is some mechanism at European level to check
and challenge the quality of supervision in all the countries
of the European economic area. We, and I think this Committee,
argued that there had to be action at European level to deal with
the problems that were revealed by that.
Q761 <John
Mann: You are putting up a robust defence of how
that has been negotiated, which is very clear for the record.
Has there been any step change in the last three months in terms
of how effective we've been in winning arguments in Europe and,
if so, what?
Lord Turner: I
don't think there has been a step change, I think this is just
a continual process in which we are extensively involved, the
Treasury is extensively involved and, given the nature of European
decision making, there are many things that result that we agree
with and there are some that we disagree with. I think if you
don't want that you should probably join UKIP.
Chair:> We are
going to be having Mr Barnier along very shortly and we will be
able to take these issues forward there. Hector, I would like
to draw this to a close now, unless John has one very quick question.
Q762 <John
Mann: Just one final question. What I am attempting
to see is whether over the process, particularly since you've
been in post, Lord Turner, whether in essence our approach to
Europe on this matter of regulation has been consistent over your
time in office, or if there has been huge variations during your
time in office?
Lord Turner: I
don't think there has been any variation. I think you can legitimately
ask whether we have won all the arguments, but I've seen no sign
of a shift in our approach during that time, because it has been
a consistent process. That's what I would say.
Q763 <David
Rutley: I would like to turn to something at a
much more micro level, which we have not discussed so far but
I know many of us around this table have had some concerns from
constituents around foreign exchange businesses, particularly
Crown Currency Exchange. I know it's quite a complex regulatory
environmentnot complex, perhaps, but not well regulatedbut
the FSA hasn't been required to regulate all the activities, particularly
on the foreign exchange activities of that company, and the administrators
are reviewing the situation. That said, people are out of pocket,
so it's not great. I just wondered what lessons you have learnt
so far, prior to the administrators coming back? Are other companies
being reviewed actively to determine whether their business models
are fit for purpose? Are there any emerging thoughts about how
you can improve the regulatory framework within the context of
the twin peaks?
Lord Turner: What
I suggest is Hector says something specifically on this case and
then I'll just make one very brief point about a general principle
we draw from this.
Mr Sants: It is
an important case to focus on, not just because of the current
consumer detriment but in terms of learning some lessons here
for the legislative framework for the CPMA, which Adair can expand
on in a moment. But, as you rightly point out, the FSA is not
responsible for regulating foreign exchange transactions. Its
only jurisdiction over Crown or similar business is in relation
to the powers given it by the Payment Services Directive, in relation
to money transmissionthe forward activities where money
is being paid to another party, not just by going in and exchanging
your forex over the desk. The activity, therefore, the FSA have
their engagement with is a very small portion of the Crown's business.
We were not regulating Crown through the FSMA Act. We were running
a registration service. We run a registration process under the
Payment Services Directive. The only oversight we had was in respect
to that registration, which requires a form to be submitted.
There is a significant misunderstanding here where
consumers are under the impression that registration with the
FSA under the Payment Services Directive in some way or other
implies that the FSA is regulating and overseeing that type of
activity in the same way as it does for FSMA firms: we do not.
In my view that registration process does not imply any investor
protection of any materiality whatsoever and, therefore, that
was a misunderstanding. The power we should have had, and we've
asked for, is the power to say to firms, "You cannot publicise
the fact you are registered with us". The fact we run registration
is an administrative service for the Government's compliance with
the Payment Services Directive: it's not a regulatory activity.
So, no, we are not out there now looking at other
firms because we are not regulating other firms in that space.
We run a registration service. What needs to be changed is the
confusion caused by that registration service. Then I think there
are some wider perimeter issues.
Lord Turner: I
think what this illustrates is that there is a distinction in
the law and in our activities, between authorisation and registration,
which I suspect is not clear to many consumers. What we essentially
do on companies of this sort is register them in the same way
that Companies House registers companies. The point is going forward,
I do think one should consider going in one or other direction.
Either we should not be the registrar of these things, or it should
be done under a completely different brand name, or they should
be authorised and regulated, but I do think we have a slightly
uncomfortable
Chair:> We get
the point. David, you have one more question.
Q764 <David
Rutley: Should they be authorised and regulated,
based on what you see?
Lord Turner: I
think there could be an argument for doing that. We'd have to
think in detail about whether to do all of their activities. Certainly
those that go beyond the straightforward instantaneous exchange
of currency do not need to be regulated, because there isn't a
risk in that, but for those where you end up with some sort of
forward commitment from them to deliver your money, then arguably
there should. But I think the crucial thing is that it's one of
these things where we have to go one way or the other. We need
clarity. We are in an uncomfortable position at the moment where
we are being asked to do something called registration, which
consumers probably think is more significant that it is.
Mr Sants: The longer
term point is that it's very important that Parliament doesn't
dilute the brand name of the CPMA. I think the CPMA, if it is
to be set up as a consumer champion, needs to have the right set
of powers, and it should only be overseeing those firms that that
full set of powers apply to, otherwise you run the risk of dilution
and confusion in the consumer's mind, which is whatquite
understandably I might sayhas occurred here, because we'd
been asked by Government to take on these additional tasks, no
doubt for the convenience of the process. We should avoid this
convenient parking.
David Rutley:>
Thank you.
Chair:> That
is a very helpful exchange. We are running behind schedule and
I think we all deserve a five-minute break and then we are going
to resumefor, unfortunately, a briefer look than perhaps
the subject demandsat competition and choice in banking.
Thank you.
|