Financial Regulation: a preliminary consideration of the Government's proposals - Treasury Contents


Conclusions and recommendations


1.  We are concerned that the current proposals for reform say relatively little about some key segments of the UK financial sector. Inappropriate regulation of non-banking sectors could cause serious and unintended damage to companies within those sectors, and to the UK more widely. As the Treasury's consultation evolves, it is important that the Government clarifies the regulatory impact of its proposals on the non-bank sectors. (Paragraph 15)

The Government's timetable

2.  We welcome the establishment of the Independent Commission on Banking. The Government should pay full regard to Vickers before coming to conclusions. Once Vickers has reported it will be equally important to maintain the political will to act on the Commission recommendations, if, after scrutiny, action is needed. This has implications for the timetable for the reforms set out in the current consultation paper. (Paragraph 23)

3.  The Government needs to take the time required to get its reform of financial regulation right. We note there was a year between the first publication of draft clauses on the Financial Services and Markets Bill, and the appearance of a further draft. Although the Joint Committee which scrutinised the Bill was given only eight weeks for the task, it subsequently took from 17 June 1999, when the Bill was presented in the Commons, to 14 June 2000 to become law. The Bill was very heavily amended in Committee in response to widespread criticism after its initial publication. It is one of the longest and most complex pieces of legislation on the statute books. The Government's current proposals include a suggestion that FSMA could be revisited in its entirety. We urge the Government to ensure that this is done, and present a new Bill only after full consideration has been given to responses to initial consultation. Drafting the legislation will then be likely to secure a more coherent final product and may eventually be quicker, given the complexities involved in comprehensive amendment of FSMA. (Paragraph 25)

4.  The legislation to establish the new regulatory structure should be subject to pre-legislative scrutiny, over a reasonable timescale; the eight weeks allowed for the Joint Committee on the Financial Services and Markets Bill was inadequate. Even with proper pre-legislative scrutiny, once introduced, the timetable for the Bill should be generous enough to allow proper parliamentary consideration, using carry-over if necessary. (Paragraph 26)

5.  However, scrutiny of the legislation will not be possible without fuller discussion of what financial stability might look like and how the democratic responsibilities of government can be combined with the delegation of significant economic policy making powers to an independent body. There also needs to be greater clarity about the wider regulatory framework; the major decisions on the structure of financial regulation should not be taken until there has been time to consider the recommendations of the Independent Commission on Banking. Whether or not it is possible to produce the final legislation within the two year time frame the Government envisages, the aim of introducing the legislation in "mid-2011" appears optimistic and, if pursued too rigidly, runs the risk of compromising its quality. (Paragraph 27)

6.  The FSA will divide internally, in preparation for the new arrangements. The Bank of England will continue to publish the Financial Stability Report, which is likely to be more influential in the interim period. While the draft legislation is being thought through, clear non-statutory interim arrangements will need to be in place. The Treasury should consider the preparation of an Memorandum of Understanding with the Bank of England and the FSA setting out those arrangements. (Paragraph 29)

A super regulator—the Bank of England (Paragraph 3)

7.  Until now, such policies have been seen as the responsibility of the elected Government. If the Financial Policy Committee is to be given lead responsibility for securing financial stability there needs to be clarity about what such stability means. The overall stability of the financial system should certainly not mean that no firm will ever fail. However, there is room for debate about how frequent and severe firm failures may be before it is considered that the system is unstable. Moreover, in the short term, there could be trade-offs between some types of stability and growth if, for example, regulation restricts free entry and exit of firms or discourages innovation in other ways; there are trade-offs between the stability of the individual firm and growth. Unlike the MPC, which has a clear inflation target and the well-defined tool of interest rates and now quantitative easing to achieve its target, the remit for the FPC is difficult to define rigorously. Nonetheless, the Government needs to give a view, and a detailed one, of what the financial stability 'target' should be, how it should be assessed, and how any trade-offs that financial stability policy requires are to be managed. (Paragraph 38)

8.  The independent members of the FPC will play a crucial role, at least as important as that of the equivalent members of the MPC. Given the close links between the internal members, the external members will play an essential role in ensuring that the Committee does not succumb to organisational "groupthink". They will need adequate support from the Bank. They should be given the right to commission any information and analysis they feel they need. (Paragraph 43)

9.  Whilst the MPC has four external members out of a total of nine, the FPC would have four external members out of eleven. A better balance between internal and external members of the FPC seems desirable. It could be achieved by increasing the number of external members on the FPC, to say six. That would increase the committee's size to thirteen, so that it would become rather unwieldy. The alternative would be to reduce the Bank's representation. The Treasury has given no explanation of the rationale for having Bank executives on markets and financial stability as full members of the FPC, rather than non-voting participants, when their respective bosses are already present, or for including such executives rather than staff of the PRA. (Paragraph 44)

10.  At least some of the external members of the FPC should have a recent senior background in the financial services industry. (Paragraph 47)

11.  However prestigious a regulator may be, it will always lose many of its best staff to the industry it regulates. This is why the experience and credibility of the external members will be particularly important in ensuring the success of the FPC, and its credibility in the industry. The Committee must contain someone with recent experience of risk management at the highest level from the regulated sector. It would be wrong to require that the FPC contain members with experience in particular industries; the task of the FPC is to look at the financial system as a whole. However there must be no room for accusations that it is overly focused on banking nor that it lacks the expertise to look at important sectors, such as insurance. (Paragraph 49)

12.  Conflicts of interest will be hard to avoid, even if external members have retired from the industry. They will need to be managed carefully. Some have made a case for those with current experience serving on the FPC, and we do not exclude that possibility. However, if the Government is considering this, it should set out clearly how those conflicts of interest will be dealt with. (Paragraph 50)

13.  The interim FPC is intended to have an important role in carrying out preparatory work and analysis for the permanent FPC. Its work may well result in fine tuning or even substantial amendment of the Government's proposals. It should be engaged in developing proposals for macro-prudential tools, and ways in which they might be adjusted. Given that this body has yet to be established, the current restructuring timetable, where the new regulatory system will be in place by the end of 2012, may be too challenging. We note that the Government has been unable to avoid delay on this, despite its desire for speed and the considerable control it had over this part of the process. (Paragraph 54)

14.  While in the long-term effective macro-prudential tools should increase economic welfare overall, particular individuals and companies find their access to credit affected, even though they are confident they could service the debt they seek. Many macro-prudential tools are only now being developed, and their effectiveness will need to be monitored. As the consultation paper notes, quantitative credit controls, which were used until the early 1980s, led to distortions. Moreover, financial innovation can be redirected to get around new regulations. (Paragraph 65)

15.  The Government has proposed that the tools available to the FPC should be set out in secondary legislation so that they can be 'fine tuned' if necessary. Given the impact that the use of macro-prudential tools may have, we recommend that secondary legislation used to introduce or alter them require the approval of Parliament. This raises wider scrutiny issues, to which we shall return. Parliament needs to assess the nature of the powers which it is to devolve to the FPC, and the extent to which these can be satisfactorily encapsulated in legislation. This means that the bulk of the secondary legislation should be available before the House begins detailed examination of any Bill. (Paragraph 66)

16.  Once appropriate tools are defined, we understand the rationale for giving the FPC discretion—in 'peacetime'—on when to use such tools, without reference to the Treasury. "To take away the punch bowl just as the party gets going" is easier said than done: it will be far harder if the FPC first has to identify a problem and then get the Chancellor to agree to the use of the tools which might mitigate it. However, only the Government and the House of Commons have the power to authorise the expenditure of public money. As we discuss further below, the accountability issues raised by the Government's proposals are complex, and hard to resolve and are discussed further in Chapter 9. (Paragraph 67)

17.  In its consultation document, the Government states that "the objectives of price stability and financial stability should generally be consistent and complementary". However, in acting to achieve their respective objectives, the MPC and the FPC will employ tools that may interact in unexpected ways. These interactions may mean the actions of one committee could affect the achievement of the other committee's objective. (Paragraph 72)

18.  The Government's proposals divide responsibility, but address coordination by having cross membership between the committees. At least three Bank officials will be members of both committees, giving them immense influence on monetary and macro-prudential policy making. Given this cadre of Bank cross-members, ensuring that adequate resources and support are available to the external members of each committee will be extremely important. (Paragraph 73)

19.  One of the ways to monitor the influence of the Bank cadre will be through the transparency of the minutes of the two committees. We will expect full disclosure of voting within the FPC on the use of the macro-prudential tools. External members of either committee will always have the ability to write to this Committee with any concerns they may have. Other aspects of accountability are discussed in Chapter 9. (Paragraph 74)

20.  The consultation paper proposes "Meetings of the MPC and the FPC will be carefully sequenced in order to ensure that both committees are able to fully take into account the most recent decisions of the other." This presumably means that one committee will not meet until the minutes of the other have been published. We support this, as likely to strengthen the position of the independent members. (Paragraph 75)

21.  Cross membership and sequencing of meetings may be sufficient in times of stability. However, in crisis periods the committees may need to work together more closely. Provision for joint MPC/FPC meetings so that policies on financial stability can be coordinated more effectively may be required. (Paragraph 76)

22.  Risks to financial stability may evolve, and may change in response to regulation. We welcome the proposal to give the FPC responsibility for monitoring the regulatory boundary. (Paragraph 79)

23.  The FPC should also have the power and the responsibility to recommend changes to the wider legal and regulatory framework, including arrangements that go across national boundaries, such as those for the resolution of cross-border banks. Any such recommendations should be copied to us. (Paragraph 80)

Micro-prudential Regulation

24.  Further consultations should give a fuller explanation of the reasons for making the PRA a subsidiary of the Bank of England. (Paragraph 86)

25.  While there may be circumstances in which public authorities need to prop up a particular firm to avoid systemic risk, we are concerned by the implicit acceptance that any failure of a high-impact firm should be avoided. (Paragraph 89)

26.  We are also concerned about the suggestion that the PRA's efforts will be focused on what it considers to be medium and high-impact firms. As the case of Northern Rock demonstrated, the failure of a company which was apparently "low-impact" engendered a systemic loss of confidence. The PRA will need to have a strong justification for reducing the supervisory effort for such 'low-impact' firms. (Paragraph 91)

27.  We agree that regulatory success does not and should not mean that no firm will fail. The Prudential Regulation Authority's aim should be, not to prevent firm failure, but to protect taxpayers and the wider economy from the consequences of such failure. Hector Sants' suggestion that the PRA will have a low tolerance for the failure of high impact firms is a source of concern. The assumption that certain firms cannot be allowed to fail results in market distortion, entrenches the market power of large incumbents and thereby stifles competition. That lack of market discipline may, over the long term, itself engender systemic instability. Although there may be combinations of circumstances in which individual firms require support to limit systemic risk, we reiterate our predecessor Committee's recommendation that no firm should be too important to fail. Competitive markets need both freedom to exit and freedom to enter. (Paragraph 92)

28.  Judgement-based regulation can cover a number of approaches, from challenging a company about how it would perform under a variety of market conditions, to substitution of the regulator's judgement for that of the company management. The aim should be to ensure that companies can fail without undue adverse impact, rather than to attempt to second guess management approaches. We are also concerned about how the PRA will manage situations in which members of the board of a supervised firm, who have personal legal responsibilities, do not agree with its judgment. (Paragraph 98)

29.  We welcome the memorandum of understanding between the FRC and the FSA on audit. The regulator needs to be confident that auditors will share their concerns directly and they should have a duty to do so. The regulator should also be able to obtain any audit information it needs from the auditors. (Paragraph 100)

30.  The debate about whether the CPMA should be a consumer champion demonstrates the importance of making sure that definitions are clear. We have no doubt that effective conduct regulation should be in consumers' best interests and will involve a high degree of consumer protection. Nonetheless, branding the CPMA as a consumer champion would be inappropriate, confusing, and potentially dangerous. The job of the regulator is to ensure that regulation is effective and proportionate. That requires a balance between preventing abusive behaviour and ensuring that regulation does not impose excessive costs and restrictions, in order to optimise economic efficiency. Financial markets manage and price risk; they do not remove it. If a regulator is promoted as a consumer champion, consumers may falsely believe that all financial products are risk free, creating moral hazard. It is simply not possible to protect every interest at all times. We strongly urge the Government to drop the title of 'consumer champion' from the CPMA. There are other organisations which campaign for consumers; the regulator's task is to be alert to abuse, and to ensure that consumers are appropriately protected in an open and fair marketplace with the minimum of moral hazard. (Paragraph 110)

31.  Competition is a highly effective means of protecting consumers' interests. The response given by the Financial Secretary when we pressed him on whether promoting competition should be treated as a primary objective for the new authorities was disappointing. The CPMA should have competition as a primary objective. This will benefit consumers directly and indirectly. Not only will there be a greater choice available for consumers, but the transparency which effective competition brings should reduce the need for heavy-handed regulation. Greater competition should also help prevent firms becoming too big to fail. We do not, however, believe that the regulator should have a remit to facilitate innovation—a properly functioning market will do that. (Paragraph 118)

32.  We have already proposed that the CPMA should have a primary objective of promoting competition, and there may be other places where regulators need a spread of objectives. However, we are unconvinced that 'have regards' provisions are effective in directing a regulator. The regulator will have to decide what trade-offs to make when desirable objectives compete: secondary statutory objectives are likely to be a more satisfactory way to specify such objectives for all but the most general provisions. (Paragraph 120)

33.  The CPMA will have a dual remit between consumer protection and markets regulation. The Government believes that a strong consumer division is required to deliver protection for consumers, while the industry believes there is a need for a strong markets division. It has also been suggested that market supervision might fit more naturally within the PRA. We urge the Government to give more detail about its thinking on this subject in the next consultation paper, and, in particular, what structure it proposes to ensure that both market regulation and consumer matters receive the attention they need. (Paragraph 123)

34.  We welcome the Government's decision to put the UK Listing Authority in the CPMA, rather than splitting responsibility for markets regulation between three bodies, as first proposed. However, there are still issues to be resolved, such as the concern about the UK's corporate governance position within Europe, where the CPMA will represent the UK in the European Securities and Markets Authority, although many corporate governance issues remain with the Financial Reporting Council. The success of the London markets underpins the success of the United Kingdom financial services industry; the markets division within CPMA must be adequately resourced, and may need a wider focus than pure conduct of business. (Paragraph 128)

35.  In principle the consequences of financial crises could pose more threats to consumers than individual cases of detriment. However, if the new arrangements work properly, choices between financial stability and consumer protection should be rare. If the FPC and PRA can produce a system in which companies can fail without financial instability, then CPMA decisions should not pose systemic risk. We welcome the Treasury's reassurance that the PRA's veto over the CPMA can only be used as a last resort. To ensure that this is so, cases when the power is exercised should be made public. It may not be possible to do so immediately, without threatening stability. In such circumstances the authorities should write to the Chancellor in confidence to notify him, explaining the reasons that the two authorities differed. We expect almost all such reports to be made public at the earliest opportunity, recognising that there may be exceptional circumstances. In such cases arrangements should be made to inform the Chair of this Committee. (Paragraph 133)

36.  It is important that the PRA and CPMA work closely together on both prudential and conduct of business issues; the absence of a Chief Executive designate of the CPMA risks regulatory thinking being developed only by those responsible for the parts of the regulatory structure which are or will be directly related to the Bank of England. We are likely to return to the relationship between the CPMA and the Bank of England in future work. (Paragraph 134)

Cost of regulation

37.  Given the urgency of the Government's reform programme and the resources and time needed to produce a further full study of the costs of regulation, it will be impractical for the FSA to devote resources to such a review at this stage. Once the new architecture has been set up, we recommend that the PRA and the CPMA revisit the whole issue of cost of regulation, in the light of the financial crisis and the changes in regulatory structure. (Paragraph 140)

38.  Under FSMA, the FSA is required to undertake a cost-benefit analysis of any proposed regulatory changes. However, the full costs—always ultimately borne by consumers—need to be shown. Cost-benefit analysis must be improved within the PRA and the CPMA. New regulatory requirements should only be introduced if a full cost-benefit analysis has been conducted. The authorities also need to be certain and demonstrate that the benefits are justified by any additional costs to consumers that might be caused by restrictions to competition. (Paragraph 141)

39.  We are unconvinced by the Financial Secretary's explanation that the £50m transition costs will be borne by the industry alone. His contention that a competitive market means that the industry will not be able to pass on the costs to consumers begs the question as to the degree of competitiveness in the market. We urge the Treasury to give more detail about the assumptions underlying the £50m transition cost. It should also report regularly over the transition period on the level of actual costs being incurred. (Paragraph 144)

40.  We appreciate the importance of avoiding the regulatory underlap that we have seen under the Tripartite system. However, removing the underlap should not result in an overlap of responsibilities between the new bodies. Overlap, like underlap, can lead to confusion and paralysis. Careful planning and consideration needs to be given to the remits and boundary of responsibilities, especially between the PRA and CPMA. (Paragraph 147)

41.  The move to new regulatory arrangements should be accompanied by better analysis of the cost of regulation, both one-off and ongoing, for all kinds of financial firms, by sector and by size. The aim should be to produce a better, more effective and more cost efficient regulatory system. (Paragraph 148)

International regulation

42.  Effective participation in international regulation is both a central part of macro-prudential policy and key to ensuring that micro-prudential policy can be conducted effectively. (Paragraph 150)

43.  Implementing the G20 priorities alone will place a heavy legislative burden on the EU. The lion's share of action will need to be taken at a global level if it is to be effective. The economic welfare added by regional action therefore requires particularly careful scrutiny. We are concerned about the scale of the EU agenda, particularly given that the European Supervisory Authorities, which should at least be able to help the Commission prioritise its work, have only just been established. The focus of European effort should be on explicit commitments by the G20 for reform. These should be implemented in close cooperation and after careful consultation with other jurisdictions. (Paragraph 158)

44.  If the European Supervisory Authorities focus on improving coordination between regulators, and drawing up technical standards which are based on a deep understanding of the markets regulators have to deal with, they can add value. However we are concerned at the sheer scale and pace of the reforms taking place at European level. The Commission needs to ensure its reforms are technically sound, and only brought forward after consultation. It also needs to avoid the danger that political pressure may lead to poor regulation. Inappropriate regulation will not only damage the United Kingdom, but the European Union as a whole.

45.  It is important that the UK, with a particularly large share of the financial services activity of the EU, secures appropriate representation on the EU regulatory bodies. (Paragraph 169)

46.  The establishment of the ESAs means the Government and the FSA need to treat engagement in European negotiations as a high priority. The United Kingdom's regulatory framework must be designed to ensure that engagement with Europe is effective. (Paragraph 170)

47.  At national level the Government is proposing to devolve a great deal of power to independent regulators. We do not oppose this, but many of the actions to prevent a recurrence of the crisis depend on actions which must be negotiated at an international level. Both the regulators and the Government may be involved in such negotiations. There are two potential dangers. The first is that international regulation becomes the preserve of technocrats, and Governments may become dangerously disengaged. The second is that political pressure results in bad regulation. The Government should provide greater clarity about the way in which negotiations will be handled and co-ordinated, what role the Government will play, and how it proposes to minimise these risks. (Paragraph 172)

Responsibilities in times of crisis?

48.  We have some doubts about a system in which one authority decides whether or not to put an institution into resolution, another related institution decides what form that such a resolution arrangement should take and a third is responsible for the decision to use public funds. We also note that the decision to allow an individual firm to fail might contribute to a systemic loss in confidence. (Paragraph 179)

49.  We accept that the Governor will keep the Chancellor up-to-date with developments in the markets which may have an impact on financial stability. However, if a systemic crisis occurs which the Bank considers public money is required to resolve, it is hard to see how the Government could assess such a request while remaining at arm's length from the process. As we have seen recently, rescuing the financial system may have significant effects on public finances. Only a democratically elected Government should make such decisions. It will bear the responsibility for any errors; it must have the information and freedom it needs to choose its position. In times of crisis, it has to be the Government that is in charge. Once it appears likely that intervention beyond a single firm is necessary, and where public funds are put at risk the authorities should take decisions together, led by Treasury Ministers, and where appropriate, the Chancellor, chairing any crisis management meetings. (Paragraph 181)

50.  The boundary between 'emerging risks' and 'crisis mode' is often unclear. As we saw in the banking crisis, major financial institutions, such as RBS and HBOS, had to be rescued over a short time frame, such as a weekend. There has to be some mechanism that will allow the Government to intervene if, in its view, a crisis is developing, and other authorities are unwilling to act. (Paragraph 183)

51.  Despite granting the Bank of England independence in monetary policy, the Treasury retains an emergency power to give the Bank directions in setting monetary policies, when it considers it is in the public interest to do so and under extreme economic circumstances. A similar 'reserve power' should be given in the new legislation. It is important that the Government retains the power to take control over actions for which it will ultimately be held responsible whilst recognising that the use of such draconian powers would be an extreme step and would prejudice the perceived independence of the regulatory institutions. (Paragraph 184)

Transparency and accountability of the new bodies

52.  The Monetary Policy Committee and the Bank of England have repeatedly demonstrated their commitment to transparency. They have seen their engagement with the Treasury Committee as a means of securing accountability. That has been a key reason for the system's success and we warmly welcome it. (Paragraph 189)

53.  The performance of the inflation targeting regime in the UK is measurable, with explicit and well-defined roles for the Treasury and the Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England as to overall policy remit, decision taking and implementation. Deviations from the target are obvious, to both the participants, and the wider public. By a one person, one vote system on the MPC, alongside vote publication in the minutes, decision making is transparent. The Treasury Committee takes an active part in this process, pursuing both transparency and accountability, using our hearings to draw out MPC members' thinking on key topics, and appointment hearings to assess their competence and independence. We can also question the Chancellor as to the remit set by the Treasury for the MPC. Independence is maintained by the strict separation between remit setting at the Treasury, and decision making over interest rates at the MPC. (Paragraph 196)

54.  The Treasury and the FPC must provide far more detailed criteria against which the achievements of the new regime can be assessed. Without this accountability will be considerably weakened. (Paragraph 197)

55.  The MPC is given its target in a regular, published remit letter from the Treasury. We recommend that this be the case for the FPC. We would not be surprised if the remit changed as more information and further research becomes available about the operation of the macro-prudential tools, and about how financial stability can usefully be defined. Such remit letters provide the political authority for the operation of such independent bodies. Their publication allows for scrutiny by this Committee, as well as other interested parties. We will take a close interest in the Financial Policy Committee, and its relations with government, and we will hold regular hearings. (Paragraph 199)

56.  The Committee will give further consideration to the accountability of the new regulatory structure in the light of the Government's second consultation document, due to be published shortly. Meaningful proposals on accountability cannot be made without more detail. (Paragraph 201)


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 3 February 2011