Competition and choice in retail banking - Treasury Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Question Numbers 32-39)

Mr Peter Vicary-Smith, Mr Dominic Lindley, Mr Philip Cullum and Ms Sarah Brooks

18 November 2010

Q32   Stewart Hosie: On competition in particular, the retail bank market contains a number of distinct segments, there's mortgages, there's a bit of financial products. Do you view competition as ineffectual across the whole sector or are there bits of the segments within it where competition works well?

Ms Brooks: I think there are sections where competition works better than in others, but I think it's more a question of where competition doesn't work well that I could look at. If you're looking at low-income consumers, that is a big issue. Banks have not traditionally seen low-income consumers as a group of people that they need to compete for, and that's a big problem because, as we know, banking is now an essential service. There is very little you can do. If you don't operate a current account, our research on the margin shows that you are excluded from being able to set up direct debits; you can't buy online; you can't have your wages paid in if you don't have a bank account; you can't buy insurance products or pensions. So it is important that people do have access to a full range of financial services, but banks have traditionally shied away from this market, and that has led some other operators to come in. We talked about payday loans earlier, because some of the banks are not willing to be flexible with the way they operate their bank accounts because bank account charges are so non-transparent. That has led people to go to a market, which has APRs of 2,000%, which then leads to calls to clamp down on that. The issue around competing for the lower-income consumer is that there doesn't seem to be enough choice. The Government had the opportunity to use the Post Office as a way of increasing competition, by setting up Post Office banking. Now they've closed that down. But what they have done, quite excitingly, is to open up a possibility that credit unions could come into Post Offices in a greater way than they already do. There's already access to credit unions at Post Offices, but there is a possibility that the Post Office could form their own credit union and that could have a current account there. I think that would be a good way of introducing a new competitor. The Post Office has about 12,000 branches, so if there were moves to encourage competition for the lower end, that would certainly open up the market.

Q33   Stewart Hosie: I'm sure that's something the Chairman has heard, because there is a huge range of financial products the bigger credit unions operate, compared with the very basic things that the smaller ones do, and there is some real competition there as well. The Which? independent banking commission concluded that the retail market was characterised by rivalry between the firms, rather than competition. Can you explain the difference?

Mr Vicary-Smith: It is where you have a number of people who are doing a different square dance of appearing to compete with each other, but in practice there is precious little competition. If you look at PPI, for example, I don't think there is a great deal of variation in either the terms of PPI or the pricing charged. It was driven by the levels of commission and Alliance & Leicester salesman received, I believe, something like six times as much commission for selling a loan with PPI as selling a loan without PPI. Surprise, surprise, they sold an awful lot of PPI. That's what I mean by rivalry. There are lots of products available and precious little transparency. It is very hard for consumers to compare them one to another and, as a consequence, consumers think, "Everything is the same. What is the point of switching, because all these banks are the same?" which they're not, but that's the perception people have, and therefore there is no need to genuinely compete. It is a much cosier industry than the BBA would like to portray, and certainly—if I can just finish—one of the things we often talk about is if banks are genuinely competing, why do they spend all their time talking through the mouthpiece of the BBA? I used to work at Procter & Gamble. Procter & Gamble would not dream of sitting on an association with Unilever producing a joint formulated response. Tesco and Sainsbury's and Asda wouldn't dream of doing the same, yet in this industry, it is all very cosy and everyone sits behind and we have the lowest common denominator of the BBA, which represents the view of the industry. That's a sign of rivalry, to my mind, not cut-throat competition.

Q34   Stewart Hosie: You have spoken about a square dance. You have said "cosy" twice. Is there collusion, or is it just pricing?

Mr Vicary-Smith: I wouldn't want to get into the legalities around it. I don't think you need to have anything overt in what goes in the market. It's interesting, isn't it, that unauthorised overdraft rates are at over 18% now, which is the highest they've been for 15 years, so all of the competition of banks in response to the OFT court case, changing their terms, changing their rates, coming out with new deals, all the rest of it, hasn't made a blind bit of difference to what the consumer actually pays. So I have no evidence there is any collusion that went on in those, but the net effect to the consumer at the end of it is no difference.

Q35   Chair: Consumers know the price of a bottle of shampoo from Procter & Gamble, and they have a rough idea of what the rival prices are of most of the products Tescos sell. They haven't in banking, and suggestions on how they get closer to that are gratefully received.

Mr Vicary-Smith: One thing the supermarkets have done is of course when you go to buy your products, under the price it will say, "Price per 100 ml".

Chair: Yes, but we don't know what the—

Mr Vicary-Smith: They make it very easy to compare and the banks don't.

Chair: Well, what we need are suggestions on how to enable the banks to do it. The OFT are looking at that, lots of other people are looking at that.

Mr Vicary-Smith: We'll submit an—

Chair: I'm sorry to be rushing, because I know a number of colleagues have already signalled to me that they need to get away today.

Q36   Mark Garnier: I just want to follow up on another question with a previous witness about the big banks' access to huge quantities of data about their customers, and how this relates to competition with independent financial advisors, mortgage brokers, that kind of stuff. You know that if you are a customer of a bank and you pay in some money into your account and you have a lot of money floating around, your bank manager will get in touch with you suddenly out of the blue. As the last witness said, for the first time in 10 years, you get a telephone call from a bank manager, who would then like to sell you a product. There are two points about this that I'd like you to comment on. First, the banks obviously have this access to this data, which is not available to everybody else, and they are using that, to my mind, unfairly. The second point is that they are selling a product, and that product is not only going to be their own product and not one from a wider pool, but it will also be something to buy, and in many cases, one of the best ways you can save if you have a pile of cash coming into your bank is not to buy a savings product or a pension product; quite often the best way of saving is to pay off your 25% credit card debt, which of course will be the bank's product as well, so they do not want you to do that. Do you have any comments about how we can deal with this or whether you see this as a big problem? Sarah, you're nodding vigorously.

Ms Brooks: I'm nodding, because we've recently done some research into switching rates on personal current accounts and it is relevant to your question, because only 7% have switched in the last two years, and that compares with energy at 32%, and 17%—so 8 million people—had considered switching, but then didn't do it. So those 8 million who thought, "Oh, yes, this might be a good idea" didn't do it, and why was that? They were concerned about how complicated it might be; they were concerned about things going wrong, and also they were concerned about things like credit rating, because your time with the bank can affect your credit rating and that seems to me to be a very anti-competitive move.

But the other factor is that there is a huge amount of brand loyalty, so of the people who hadn't considered it, it was because they were satisfied with their bank, and I think it's because people have very low expectations of what banks should do. But also I think it's something to do with the fact that your bank is so important to you. It's how you pay your mortgage; it's how you put food on the table; it's your line of credit. You might have your pension with them, so in a way, they have you to ransom there. It's almost a sort of form of Stockholm syndrome, where you want to believe that you can trust your bank, because if you can't believe that, then that puts you in a very difficult position. So what we see, and what we always say, is that loyalty seems to be very much a one-way street with banks; that they will presume on that, but they don't offer it the other way around, and I do think that it should be incumbent on banks that if they want to capitalise on that loyalty, then we need to see much more evidence that they are offering the right products and the right advice to their customers.

On of my colleagues used to work in a law centre, and she had cases where adults with learning disabilities would come in and there would be charges that they couldn't work out on their bank accounts. It was because they'd been sold a bundled account, so they'd been sold an account where you had to pay a fee on it. Now, that is not only wrong, it should be illegal that you can take advantage of people in that way, and these are not isolated occasions. So going back to regulation, it is about reputation regulation. We'd like to see the FOS doing more of that, more of the putting out cases, but also the FSA taking action to make sure that the customers are treated fairly.

Mr Vicary-Smith: Two points: I think first of all you are absolutely right on information, which is why it is a bit rich when banks complain about the cost of running a personal current account, because, apart from the £8 billion a year that they get and the fact that retail banking was profitable right the way through the crisis—so it is not an unprofitable stream anyway—they get an enormous amount of data that they can use, as you say. If I was looking at it as a businessman, I'd probably be quite happy to have personal current accounts almost as a loss leader, because of all the other things that it enables me to do. So we don't have much truck with them complaining about the profitability of current account banking.

On the other dimension of what you get sold, you're absolutely right, that often paying down debt is the best form for many people of using windfalls. When you're then sold a product from your bank, as we argue strongly—this is one of the disappointing aspects of the retail distribution review—the bank sales staff should be called "sales staff", not "advisors". "Restricted advisors" doesn't do it for me either. They're not giving advice, they're selling a product their bank happens to make and I think we should be clearer with consumers about who is giving advice and who is making a sale. Finally, one of our recommendations to the Future of Banking Commission was that we believe that frontline bank staff should not be remunerated on the basis of commission, because we see the enormous distortions time in, time out that that has caused in the marketplace.

Q37   Mr Love: Let me ask about unarranged overdraft facilities and the OFT. The first question—and this is one that we hope that you'll be able to respond to—if the case had been won, would that have meant the end of what they call free banking? Secondly, the OFT has suggested a way forward that hasn't met with universal approval. What's your view on how we can take these matters forward?

Mr Vicary-Smith: Well, first of all, you're absolutely right in the distinction. We always call it free in-credit banking to differentiate it. I don't think it would have meant the end of that, no, because what we've seen is that current accounts are already highly profitable ventures—50% of the £8 billion, I mentioned earlier, is from interest foregone. It's not from other types of charges anyway, so there are many ways that banks can make money and make current accounts profitable, as they should be. We have no problem with current accounts being charged for in some way, and people are paying for it now and they would pay for it in the future. The models may change and we'd like to see a variety of ways that people can pay for their banking, but if the case had been won, some banks would have changed, some banks would not.

Q38   Mr Love: Miss Brooks, you mentioned earlier on about low-income consumers, vulnerable consumers. It raised with me the question of where we go now with the decisions that have been made in relation to the Post Office. It doesn't seem to me there's been entirely a market failure. Basic bank accounts are out there, there has been quite a lot of take up. I notice from your submissions that you've redesigned—if I can call it that—the basic bank account. Will that make a difference and do we need to bring regulation into this to, in a sense, put more pressure on the financial services sector to respond to the needs of low-income consumers? How do we deal with this going forward?

Ms Brooks: It relates to a certain extent to the previous question about unauthorised overdraft fees, because if we could resolve that situation, so that the fees were transparent and people knew and they were reflective, then people could understand what they were getting into. A low-income consumer doesn't necessarily just need the most basic banking, they still need access to the full range, but what they need to be able to do is to control money coming in and money coming out. If there were more regulation around the overdraft facilities, but also if there was a way that people could control their own direct debits, so that you could control the date it was going out, you could cancel it yourself, so you had a sort of joint mandate on direct debits, that would allow low-income consumers to have more control of what they were doing. So I think it does require some regulation. Not everybody who goes in wanting a basic bank account comes out with one, and that should be looked at as well, so that people aren't being sold the wrong products for them, as I alluded to in my previous answer.

Mr Cullum: Just to add to that, one of the key things that Sarah's alluded to a couple of times is about control, and it's one of the things that comes out again and again with all of our research of disadvantaged consumers. The real market failure here is the failure of banks to pay attention to their customers, to listen to what they want from some of these accounts and then provide it, and hopefully make some money out of it. That's what they're in the business to do. We are bewildered at times by their failure to act in their own self-interest and, as we listen to these customers and potential customers, the big thing that comes out from our research is that people want to have control, if they're not used to financial products particularly, and yet the ones that banks provide just don't provide them with that control. We then end up with the bizarre paradox where people who don't have very much money pay more for products that they perceive give them more control, and so they're turning down the ones that are cheaper, because they don't think it's doing the business for them, and that is a really clear market failure on the part of the banks.

Q39   Chair: I'd just like to put one question about UKFI to Peter Vicary-Smith. You've suggested that UKFI should apply a public interest test to secure greater competition in the market and the decisions they take on divestment. Could you explain how that would operate in practice?

Mr Vicary-Smith: UKFI of course has competition as one of its objectives, but looking through what it actually does, I see scant evidence that anything that it's doing is increasing competition in banking. The prime example of that of course was the sale of the RBS branches and payment centre to Santander, which could have been used to kick start a new player in the marketplace. The public interest test I mentioned would be to say, in looking at the future disposals in particular, and of course, we all have in mind the Lloyds branch disposals that will be coming up, it should not just be a matter of looking for the absolute highest price. It needs to get a good return, but not the £1 more than the nearest bidder. It should also be saying, "What is this going to do to competition within the banking sector, and is it going to enhance competition?" because we have a once in a generation opportunity to increase competition through enabling a new entrant to get to scale quickly through these disposals, and it would be tragic if we didn't use that opportunity and instead flogged it off to one of the existing incumbents.

Chair: Well, there is a great deal that has struck a chord with many of us that we've heard this morning, and I'm very glad that the session ran on a little longer so that we could hear some more. If there are further points you want to come to us with, please do. Thank you very much for your evidence this morning.


 
previous page contents

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 2 April 2011