Competition and choice in retail banking - Treasury Contents


Written evidence submitted by Virgin Money

1.0  EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

1.1  Retail banking does not seem very competitive. It is dominated by five large banks with broadly similar products, prices and customer service. As a strongly pro-competition new entrant, we would like to see greater competition, and we believe that competition in retail banking would benefit from more providers and from greater diversity of providers. But smaller providers and new entrants will make little difference to overall competition in retail banking if entry is difficult, and if those which do enter simply compete with each other for such switching business as is available in a "two tier" market of large incumbents and smaller providers.

1.2  Our view is that smaller providers and new entrants will only be able to compete effectively with the larger incumbents if actions are taken to reduce or eliminate some significant barriers which are discussed in this paper. Our conclusions, from consideration of these barriers, support our specific recommendations at the end of this submission.

2.0  BACKGROUND AND INTRODUCTION

2.1  Virgin Money was established in 1995. It now has over two and a half million customers, and currently offers a range of financial products across lending (including credit cards), savings (including tracker funds) and protection (including motor insurance).

2.2  Virgin Money's experience is that initial entry to financial services through the provision of a limited product proposition is not particularly difficult. We have maximised income opportunities by concentrating on "transactional" products such as credit cards and motor insurance, where customers are willing to switch between providers, and have minimised costs by outsourcing product "manufacturing" activities to established providers, and by limiting access to direct channels—mainly the internet.

2.3  Despite Virgin Money's success so far, we recognise that this business model has some limitations. Because of its limited product range and the absence of branches, it does not appeal to all customer segments. In considering how to expand our business to the benefit of a wider range of customers, and become a credible alternative to large incumbent banks, we believe that it is important for us to become a full-service bank, offering "relationship" as well as "transactional" banking products. As a first step towards establishing full-service banking capabilities, to support our business expansion, we acquired a small bank, Church House Trust, in January.

2.4  Our business plan to become a full-service bank sounds simple. We aim to add a range of "relationship" banking products—deposits, mortgages and personal current accounts (PCAs), and, if possible, banking services for small business (SMEs). To meet customer needs and expectations, we plan to open a limited national branch network. And, to maintain our "Virgin" reputation for product innovation and good customer service, we intend to establish some in-house "manufacturing" capabilities.

2.5  In planning this business expansion, we are encouraged by the demand for Virgin to offer a credible alternative to the large incumbents. Quantitative research from February 2010 shows that consumer consideration for Virgin as a banking provider has grown to reach the same levels as the incumbent big four high street banks (NatWest, Lloyds TSB, HSBC and Barclays). However, despite consumer consideration on a par with the incumbents, we observe that a number of barriers make the implementation of our plan more difficult than it sounds—or, we think, than it would be in many other industries. We discuss a number of such barriers in the next section of this submission.

3.0  BARRIERS TO ENTRY AND EXPANSION

Market structure

Barrier

3.1  It is difficult for new entrants to compete with the large incumbent banks in retail banking because of the large banks' dominant market shares in most banking products, particularly in the key relationship banking products, PCAs and SMEs.

Commentary

3.2  The UK market in retail banking is highly concentrated. Four large domestic banks (Lloyds, RBS, Barclays and HSBC) and the UK subsidiaries of the large Spanish bank Santander, together account for almost 90% of PCAs and over 90% of SMEs. Lloyds Banking Group (formed by the merger of Lloyds TSB and HBOS) alone accounts for 30% of PCAs and over 20% of SMEs.

3.3  In such a concentrated market, these five banks enjoy competitive advantages from substantial economies of scale in their operational and marketing costs, and from their extensive branch networks.

3.4  Twenty years ago, there were many more providers of personal banking services and a much greater variety of providers. In addition to the "Big Four" (Barclays, NatWest, Lloyds and HSBC), customers could choose as alternatives the two Scottish banks (RBS and Bank of Scotland), the unique TSB, the converted bank Abbey National and the about-to-convert Halifax, and a number of building societies with national distribution including Nationwide, Cheltenham & Gloucester, Woolwich, Northern Rock, Alliance & Leicester and Bradford & Bingley. Many of these providers were retail-only, and they competed effectively with the "Big Four" by offering a different product focus or service proposition, reflecting the priorities of their stakeholders. Now, in the UK, there is no credible alternative to the large banks for full-service banking, except to some extent Nationwide and the UK subsidiaries of NAB.

Conclusion

3.5  The UK banking market has evolved to the point where there is a limited oligopoly of incumbent banks that have very little differentiation. As we will discuss in the following sections (3.6 to 3.14), their control of the PCA and SME markets makes it very difficult for a new entrant to compete effectively and grow successfully in this market.

Personal Current Accounts (PCAs)

Barrier

3.6  In personal banking, PCAs are key "relationship" products, enabling banks to establish long-term relationships with their customers, to gather information about them and to offer them other suitable products. However, PCA switching rates are low, and it would take some time for a new entrant to achieve scale in PCAs—during which time incumbent banks could respond to threats from new entrants.

Commentary

3.7  We believe that "free" banking contributes to the low rates of switching in PCAs:

  • The widespread availability of "free" banking means that all banks seem the same to consumers, and there is no obvious financial incentive for customers to switch their current accounts.
  • Even if customers are considering switching between current account providers, "free" banking means that it is not easy to assess likely charges, and it is not possible to compare the levels of service offered by different banks, except by hearsay.

"Free" banking makes it very difficult for new entrants to the PCA market:

  • New entrants are not able to compete by offering lower prices (than zero) or by innovating with simpler, lower-cost products.

3.8  Of course, "free" banking is not free. Free banking for good customers is subsidised by "insufficient funds" charges, which are generally paid by customers who are less affluent or less well-informed. We believe that it would be fairer for all customers to impose or at least encourage a more rational pricing structure, with lower insufficient funds charges and with some appropriate fees for PCA services. As well as being fairer, this more rational pricing structure would make it easier for customers to compare their likely charges, and would enable new entrants to compete on price and through innovation.

Conclusion

3.9  We recommend that the TSC should acknowledge the need to bring fairness and transparency to current account bank charges.

Small Businesses (SMEs)

Barrier

3.10  It is desirable that a new entrant to retail banking should be able to offer SME as well as personal banking services, to serve the needs of communities, including many small businesses where personal and business activities are inter-related, as well as to generate additional income to justify the necessary investment in people, infrastructure and branches. However, organic entry to SME banking is very difficult.

Commentary

3.11  To enter SME banking, a new entrant would have to offer current accounts and other SME banking products, recruit experienced customer-facing and credit personnel, and invest in appropriate infrastructure—and would probably have to open branches, since many SMEs visit branches frequently for advice and to make payments. Credit management is also challenging for a new entrant, without historic customer information.

3.12  Even if these could all somehow be resolved, there would remain the difficulty of demonstrating a reputation for good service in SME banking. SME banking is different from many other businesses in that both the customer and the bank expect a long term relationship in which the unquantifiable aspect of service is as important as the quantifiable aspect of price. A reputation for delivering the required quality of service can only be achieved through being in the business. So, in a perverse sense, an SME bank "has to be in the business to enter the business".

3.13  A new entrant without a reputation would find it hard to compete on price alone, because switching rates of existing SMEs are very low, and new SMEs are offered free banking for an initial period—and so, given the absence of a price advantage from new entrants, new SMEs (and their financial advisors) are likely to "play safe" with established incumbents.

Conclusion

3.14  Given the barriers to organic entry and expansion, including the necessary up-front investment in people, products, infrastructure and branches, the absence of a reputation in SME banking and the time it would take to achieve scale, it is clearly difficult for a new entrant to become a significant challenger to the large incumbents within a reasonable period by this route.

Growth by a new entrant through acquisition

Barrier

3.15  An alternative route, to accelerate entry and expansion for a new entrant, would be the acquisition of a suitable banking business. However, in practice, entry by acquisition is difficult—possibly even more difficult than organic entry.

Commentary

3.16  Although theoretically attractive, it is not easy to enter retail banking through the acquisition of a suitable banking business:

  • In the UK, no small banks with suitable characteristics exist.
  • It is clearly not possible for a new entrant to buy a large incumbent bank.
  • Acquisition of another new entrant would add scale in "transactional" products such as credit cards and insurance, but would not address the strategic objective for a new entrant of entering the market for PCAs and SMEs, and establishing branches.
  • Acquisition of a building society would add capabilities in mortgages and deposits, and branches, but the acquisition of a mutual building society is a prolonged process and is vulnerable to interloper risk. Other than Nationwide, building societies have only limited regional networks.

3.17  It is extremely unlikely that incumbent banks would wish to sell any of their core retail banking assets. If such banking assets do become available, as a result of financial difficulties experienced by incumbents, it is still very difficult for new entrants to take advantage of such opportunities:

  • The first of the EC-mandated disposals, the sale of the RBS assets (in which Virgin Money expressed strong interest, and for which it received indications of material financial support) to Santander, shows that a new entrant can be beaten by an incumbent which is able to deliver cost-saving synergies and funding benefits by integrating the acquisition with its existing business, while meeting the market share threshold set by the EC (regardless of other competition issues).

Conclusions

3.18  Growth through acquisition is challenging for a new entrant - and this makes the disposals being made of RBS, Lloyds Banking Group and Northern Rock assets critically important if further competition is to be introduced into UK banking.

3.19  These disposals should be subject to the normal OFT/Competition Commission review on their likely impact on competition in the UK, but in addition should also benefit from a public interest test where the long-term economic implications of proposals made to acquire the assets are understood. Such a public interest test should consider, for example, the retention of jobs and the commitment to lending made by a potential acquirer.

3.20  This will ensure that the RBS, Lloyds Banking Group and Northern Rock disposals are not judged just on the short-term economic value they deliver to shareholders, but also on the long-term value they create for society, including stimulating greater competition.

3.21  In addition, the disposals of RBS, Lloyds Banking Group and Northern Rock assets should be structured such that there is a level playing field for banking incumbents and new entrants (for example, by enforcing the provision of cost cover for due diligence for all parties).

3.22  In particular, we believe a public interest test should be applied to the RBS asset disposal before the transaction is completed and the assets sold to Santander.

Regulation

Barrier

3.23  Basel II regulations place new entrants at a financial disadvantage relative to the large incumbents, despite the fact that retail-only new entrants such as Virgin Money are essentially low-risk, while the large incumbent banks have high-risk activities in investment banking, including complex products and proprietary trading.

Commentary

3.24  Pillar I of Basel II prescribes how banks must calculate capital for credit, market and operational risks. New entrants, without a sufficient track record, must use a standard approach. Large incumbent banks are allowed to use their own statistical models to estimate their capital requirements, which have generally been lower than would be required by the standard method, despite the limitations of the models in extreme situations.

3.25  In addition to the Pillar I requirements of Basel II, the local regulator requires additional capital to be held under Pillar II for other risks, and for stress tests. Although the local regulators' requirements for individual banks are not disclosed, it is believed that new entrants may be subjected to more onerous requirements, compounding the Pillar I imbalance.

3.26  The disadvantage of requiring proportionately more capital is not particularly onerous at entry, when the amounts of capital are relatively small. However, as a new business expands and requires more capital, the cost disadvantage from having to carry proportionately more capital could become a significant barrier.

Conclusion

3.27  A level playing field in capital requirements between incumbents and new entrants would reduce this barrier to new entry and expansion, and would encourage greater competition. Given the riskiness of the business models of large banks, and the limitations of their risk models, our conclusion is that a level playing field should be achieved by requiring large banks to hold at least as much capital (proportionally) as new entrants—and perhaps more at some times in the economic cycle.

Government initiatives

Barrier

3.28  It seems unlikely that a more competitive market in retail banking will emerge unless the authorities are willing to impose more pro-competition measures than have so far been indicated.

Commentary

3.29  Policy initiatives over recent years have been disappointing for new entrants. The Cruickshank Review quantified "excess profits", but did not suggest structural changes or actions to improve competition. The Supreme Court failed to support the OFT ruling that current account insufficient funds charges should be reduced, preventing the possibility that banks might start to charge for some current account services, to offset their reduction in income—a move which, we believe, would have encouraged greater competition and more switching in PCAs. The acquisition of HBOS by Lloyds TSB was allowed.

3.30  Although only two of the five large banks (RBS and Lloyds) received state aid, all banks benefited from actions taken to protect the banking system, and now they all benefit from being perceived as "too big to fail":

  • There is no incentive for customers to move deposits from a state-aided bank, or from a bank that is "too big to fail".
  • In an environment where bank lending is restricted, banks have greater power than their borrowers to determine the availability and pricing of loans.
  • The large banks, whether overtly supported or not, are all benefiting from funding rates lower than they would otherwise be—and lower than new entrants.

3.31  These factors make it difficult for new entrants to benefit significantly from the financial and reputational difficulties suffered by many large banks in the financial crisis. In other industries, where large providers are not protected, strong challengers can gain at the expense of weakened incumbents.

3.32  Banking initiatives have tended to concentrate on one aspect of banking at a time, without considering the possible unintended consequences on other aspects. In particular, the need to create a more competitive framework has been subordinated to financial stability issues. We therefore welcome the current initiative by the OFT and the TSC to look at competition in retail banking, and the establishment of an Independent Commission to consider at the same time financial stability, possible reforms and competition.

3.33  However, it is disappointing that, while the sale of Government-owned shares in RBS and Lloyds have been deferred until after the Independent Commission has reported, and will be sold with a view to encouraging greater competition, the disposal of RBS's retail banking assets, which could have been a key component in the creation of a more diverse and competitive retail banking market, has been allowed to proceed.

Conclusion

3.34  In view of the continuing benefit that all large banks are gaining from their "too big to fail" status, we believe that the Government will have to introduce some significant legislative or regulatory reforms such as those recommended below, to redress the detriment to competition caused by the "too big to fail" status of large banks and by the prioritisation of financial stability above competition, and to deliver the cross-party pre-election consensus of the need for a more competitive and diverse retail banking market.

4.0  RECOMMENDATIONS

4.1  Structural reforms

Consider splitting large retail banks into smaller units as well as to splitting large banks between retail banking and investment banking.

4.2  Current accounts

Acknowledge that the ending of the apparently unfair cross-subsidy in current accounts caused by unauthorised overdraft charging would be fairer for all customers, and would enable competition in the PCA market to be more easily created.

4.3  Regulation

Remove any regulation which, however well-intended, is unfairly onerous for new entrants to retail banking and could therefore discourage new entrants.

4.4  New entrants

Consider what legislative or regulatory reforms are required to encourage the creation of new building societies, banks, credit unions and community banks, as the Conservatives promised before the election.

4.5  Acquisitions

In relation to retail banking assets being sold now or in the future, take a wider view of public interests (including in particular the expected impact on competition) than has been the case during previous banking consolidation.

September 2010


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 2 April 2011