Competition and choice in retail banking - Treasury Contents


Supplementary written evidence submitted by the Co-operative Financial Services

CORE CAPITAL FOR MUTUAL AND CO-OPERATIVE BANKS

Thank you for the opportunity earlier today to explore our thoughts on competition and choice in the banking sector. During the hearing, you indicated that it would be helpful if I set out details of the issues faced by mutuals and co-operatives in the current changing regulatory landscape. Accordingly I set out our thoughts below.

CONTEXT

If mutuals were not to have access to Core Tier 1 capital other than through retained earnings, the sector will be affected in three main areas:

The boards of mutuals will not have the ability to manage and grow their balance sheets flexibly and, as a result, will be hampered in their ability to ensure that their members' interests are best served and protected. Balance sheet growth will be constrained to the uneven (and currently very modest) rate at which organic capital can be generated from retained earnings, and this will have an unwelcome procyclical effect. (Nor can organic capital be generated overnight to respond to — for instance — sudden increases in capital requirements, or the step change effect of regulatory capital deductions which are increasingly taken against core capital). This means mutuals will be less able to maintain lending in a downturn, and will be less able to provide effective competition to banks. So the playing field will be far from level and competitive disadvantage will result from no access to external core capital. Reserves built up from retained earnings are expected to remain the predominant form of capital overall for mutual and co-operative deposit-takers in the UK, but from time to time some of them will need access to external capital for specific reasons.

The sector will also be viewed as second tier as it has not been afforded equal treatment to financial institutions which are organised as joint-stock companies with the resulting negative connotations associated with such a view. This is inconsistent with HM Government's commitment in its document The Coalition: our programme for government which states:

"We will bring forward detailed proposals to foster diversity in financial services, promote mutuals and create a more competitive banking industry."

The ratings agencies will also be forced to take a negative view on the sector compared with financial institutions organised as joint stock companies, as the ability of mutuals to create capital will have been restricted and will become more dependent on the economic cycle. This restriction will not only apply to Core Tier 1 but will also affect the ability of the sector to issue contingent capital as there will not be a valid "go-to" instrument. This negative view could well translate into ratings downgrades across the sector as a whole which will have a knock-on effect on the ability of the sector to access the wholesale markets for funding. None of this is positive for financial stability in the UK.

BACKGROUND

The UK's mutual sector has outlined a principles-based approach to modification of the core capital criteria proposed in Annex IV of the European Commission's February 2010 consultation document on CRD 4. We argued that such modifications should not be based on existing national peculiarities or special pleadings, but on transparent, existing pan-European principles. The relevant principles are those already recognised in European law in the recitals to the Statute for the European Co-operative Society, namely limited interest on capital, open membership and disinterested distribution. Together with the Building Societies Association, we have worked with the European Association of Co-operative Banks, in order to press this case in pan-European terms.

The final guidelines from the Committee of European Banking Supervisors (which since the beginning of the new year has become the European Banking Authority) on Article 57a (core capital) instruments and the accompanying feedback statement, were in fact most helpful in advancing the cause of mutuals and co-operatives. That said, CRD2 and CEBS guidelines unfortunately do not accommodate the legal structure of UK co-operatives in the modifications applicable to mutuals and cooperatives, and amendments are required.

This structure and the related issues are described in detail below on catering for UK co-operatives. It is also important to ensure that the CRD 4 drafting is both sufficiently explicit on these matters — as the CEBS guidelines were — so as to avoid what we call "interpretation risk" and also does not introduce any other provisions that are damaging to mutuals' and co-operatives' ability to raise core capital. Indeed CRD 4 should seek to create parity between mutuals, co-operatives and other banking entities.

On a positive note the Treasury has recently proposed the following wording for inclusion in CRD4. We welcome the Minister's support for this so far, and encourage the Minister to give this a high priority in UK negotiations at a European level.

58(1)
"Common Equity Tier 1 capital instruments set out in paragraph 1a of Article 57a shall include any other instrument:

(a) issued under the specific constitutional and legal structure of a mutual, cooperative society or
similar institution; or
(b) issued by a credit institution in which, and for so long as, a mutual, co-operative society or similar institution holds 100% of the ordinary shares;

and which is deemed fully equivalent to an ordinary share in terms of its capital qualities regarding loss absorption, and does not possess features which could cause the condition of the credit institution to be weakened as a going concern during periods of market stress,"

58(2)
"Instruments issued in accordance with Article 58(1) may be subject to a dividend cap provided that the primary purpose of the cap is to limit distributions to investors and protect the reserves of the credit institution. The credit institution may indicate to the market that where possible it intends to pay dividends at or below the level of the cap, provided that at all times the credit institution shall retain full discretion over the payment of dividends and shall exercise that discretion to stop or reduce dividend payments in order to protect reserves in accordance with the level of distributable items [or to build up reserves where necessary to do so]. The credit institution shall regularly review the cap and whether it is appropriate to use the cap as a level of intended dividend."

SPECIFIC POLICY PROPOSALS

(i)  Catering for UK co-operatives

There remains a challenge for co-operatives. UK co-operatives are generally incorporated as industrial and provident societies and consequently cannot undertake banking business directly. In order to accommodate UK legal and regulatory requirements, in 1971 what was previously the banking department of the Co-operative Wholesale Society had to be separately incorporated as the Cooperative Bank, a wholly-owned company subsidiary of an I&P society. That is why the BSA has consistently urged the Authorities to ensure that principles-based modifications for mutuals or co-operatives in CRD 4 should apply to their respective groups, whether or not specific group entities are structured as companies, and this is clearly needed where the use of a company subsidiary is necessitated by national law or regulation.

For a banking business which is a subsidiary of a UK co-operative, this means that the bank should be able to issue capped core tier one instruments to raise external capital without prejudice to its ability to make uncapped distributions to its I&P parent.

The structure of a mutual group with a joint stock company as a subsidiary is also required under UK law specifically in the Building Societies (Funding) and Mutual Societies (Transfer) Act 2007 ( the "Butterfill Act") which provides a framework for merger of one type of mutual with another type of mutual. It is a requirement of the Butterfill Act that any merger of two different mutuals must be effected by the transfer of the business of the transferring mutual to a subsidiary of the acquiring mutual, with membership rights conferred in the acquiring mutual itself.

The acquiring mutual's subsidiary must be a Companies Act company or a body corporate incorporated in another EEA state. Given that such a UK co-operative structure is prescribed by UK law, clearly it needs to have the ability to issue a core tier one capital instrument of a similar nature and with similar features to the instrument proposed for mutuals which are building societies. Indeed there seems no legal basis to draw a distinction between such a UK co-operative structure and building societies in respect of the issue of core tier one capital instruments since they adhere to the same mutual principles. To underline this point, that the subsidiary, although having the form of a joint-stock company, operates as a co-operative business, we draw attention to the feature, in the CFSI Co-operative Bank structure, that the bank's customers are entitled to membership of the top co-operative, and that anyway membership in the new holding mutual is a requirement for any kind of transfer under the Butterfill Act.

(ii)  Flexibility on caps

The CEBS guidelines fully accept the principle of capping distributions on the core capital instruments of mutuals or co-operatives, making the further, and helpful, link that these caps operate to protect the reserves from over-distribution, and are therefore prudentially desirable. The final guidelines have also taken the step that such a cap may be provided for either in national law or in the constitutional documents (ie Rules or Articles) of the mutual or co-operative. There may however be potential ambiguity as to how this needs to be specified. In this context it is important to avoid being drawn too closely towards the current French model, where the Ministry of Finance determines the cap (ie the actual numerical percentage rate) twice a year and this applies to all French mutual or co-operative banks.

Instead, we need to clarify that national law, or the Rules, needs to provide for there to be a cap, but that the actual percentage level of the cap should be left for the different issuers to decide. The desired outcome is (i) that different mutual or co-operative institutions can make their individual decisions on where to set a cap, (ii) this can be decided in the context of an actual issue (whereas enabling rule changes will have been made some time in advance) and (iii) if possible, setting different caps for different issues by the same institution should not be precluded.

(iii)  Interpretation risk

There is a wider concern, deriving from the experience of the UK discussions on Mutual core tier 1 and CRD 2/CEBS, which we describe as "interpretation risk" that is, provisions which are initially taken to have a clear, explicit meaning may be subject to later interpretation, on a "purposive" basis, producing a result some way from the explicit meaning of the provisions (and connected perhaps to the separate agendas of the interpreting authority). In that context we note inter alia the potential future risk from binding rulings of the European Banking Authority in place of the persuasive but non-binding guidelines of CEBS. CRD 4 drafting must therefore minimise any interpretation risk to mutuals and co-operatives. A particular instance of this concerns "pre-indication". As we have argued recently, all securities, even ordinary shares, are sold with some pre-indication of expected return. In the case of an IPO of ordinary shares, this takes the form of a formal dividend forecast for the current or next accounting period, and a dividend policy: these cannot be contractual, but they must be made or given in good faith after due diligence, since they are intended to, and do, influence the behaviour of prospective investors.

The current language in the CEBS guidelines (paragraphs 69 to 71) sensibly recognises that institutions (both proprietary and mutual/co-operative) may disclose a dividend policy. But the term "pre-indication" is too vague and more clarity is required.

I trust this addresses your request for further background information that you might raise with the Financial Secretary to HM Treasury at the next meeting of the Treasury Select Committee on 2 February 2011.

February 2011


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 2 April 2011