Budget 2011 - Treasury Contents


(Examination of Witnesses Questions 241-337)

Q241 Chair: Good morning. This is the first session where you have come before us having had a reasonable opportunity to work out your own methods and, with a bit of time, to think through what you want to present publicly. I would like to begin with an issue about process. I noticed from your published document that you required all major policy decisions to be received by you by 9 March, a full fortnight before the Budget, and that this means that two major items that were decided after that were not fully accommodated in the forecast. Why did you require a fortnight?

Robert Chote: That is the appropriate time horizon, I think, given the fact that once you have an economic forecast, the Chancellor needs a stable platform in terms of an economic forecast in order to reach final views on the content of the fiscal package, and then once we have an economic forecast, then there is the longer process of going through the fiscal forecast, which is not simply a matter of hitting a button on a spreadsheet. We have to send that set of determinants out to departments and that takes a couple of days for them to come back with the material from that. So we discussed with the Treasury at the beginning of the whole process what would be an appropriate time horizon that gave them the information they needed with reasonable certainty, and good enough time for decisions, and then would allow us to come up with the forecast at the end of the day. They were happy with that; we set that out in terms of the time horizon we would need—

Q242 Chair: The fortnight schedule is their suggestion, is it?

Robert Chote: We agreed it. We had a discussion at the beginning of the process at what—because you know at that stage when particular data are coming out so on some occasions you end up with particularly important data coming very close to the final stage, some a bit later, so you look at the calendar, see what seems an appropriate set of time horizon, we explain that to the Treasury, we agree that in advance and then I think it was quite important that having set out that timetable, we should stick to it and be transparent.

Q243 Chair: What I am trying to get at, just to be clear, is that the fortnight period after which you were not prepared to take further changes, was agreed by the Treasury—

Robert Chote: In advance of the process, so six weeks out from the process, yes.

Q244 Chair: All right. In working that out, did you look at how previous Budgets had been put together?

Robert Chote: I had not been through a previous Budget process in the same way; Graham has probably had some experience of that time horizon. Judging from the Treasury's reaction to that, I presume that was fairly consistent.

Q245 Chair: But the answer—it is a very long answer to a very simple question—to that question is, "No" is it?

Robert Chote: I have not been through a previous—

Chair: It is either yes or no.

Robert Chote: I have not been through the process before.

Q246 Chair: If you have not taken a look at that, you did not ask for any information on that question?

Robert Chote: In terms of when we think that the answers can be put in, whether Treasury felt that they needed to have a stable base, I presume they were certainly drawing conclusions from their previous experience and what requirements they would have there.

Q247 Chair: Yes, but the answer is no, you did not ask how it had been done by previous Administrations or in previous Budgets.

Robert Chote: I did not go through previous processes, no.

Q248 Chair: Fine. What will you do with this fortnightly schedule if there is a major macroeconomic event that radically alters the likely structure of the forecast within the fortnightly period?

Robert Chote: If that is likely to show up in the form of a piece of data that would come out on the calendar, then that is one of the things we would take into account in future occasions on deciding what the appropriate time horizon is. If you knew that you were going to have a particular GDP number, for example, out of some particular—

Q249 Chair: I am talking about an unexpected event.

Robert Chote: If you have an unexpected event, we would look at that when the unexpected event arises and say, "What adjustment can we make for this in the appropriate time horizon?" but I think it would be very important to be transparent about what we had done there rather than to just claim that we had managed to put everything together in the appropriate time.

Q250 Chair: In the interests of transparency, it might be helpful if you tell us when you were told about the two major tax changes that were notified to you after the—

Robert Chote: On the 16th and 17th that were the three—

Chair: Right. So basically with a week to go?

Robert Chote: Yes.

Q251 Chair: Did you ask whether historically the Treasury had been capable of absorbing that and redoing the forecast in a week?

Robert Chote: I'm sure I have—although I have not been through the process, I am well aware that, I think, in previous Budgets there were often significant decisions taken rather later in the process than a week before the final announcement. How well that was integrated into the final forecast is a matter for them.

Q252 Chair: I think the Committee would like to see much more detail on any decisions that have been notified to you late in future documentation, please, and in particular we would like a substantive explanation of why it is that you were unable, in this case, to accommodate those two measures, or the big measures, which are corporate tax and the fuel duty, even though you had a week to do so.

Robert Chote: Can I just say I think one very important reason for that would be that having set out this process and the timetable in advance, one lesson that I think you drew, as well as we would have done from the experience of the interim OBR in the early years—in the early period—is that, having set out a timetable, it is wise to stick to that and be transparent about it, and less people misinterpret changes in the timetable.

Q253 Chair: It is also wise to be flexible, don't you think? You do not want to create a new huge bureaucracy here.

Robert Chote: No, it is wise to be flexible. It is also wise to put in clear transparent deadlines and stick to them when you have put them in place, I think.

Q254 Chair: Can I turn to the correspondence that I have had with you on behalf on the Committee on asset sales and privatisation receipts? You say there that to supply such numbers will leave us with the problem of coming up with sensible estimates, but you have to come up with sensible estimates for all sorts of unknowns or very difficult issues to forecast, do you not?

Robert Chote: We do. I am not sure it is in quite the same sense. You have the combination of actually knowing what the timing of particular sales is going to be and actually putting a value on the particular asset that we are talking about, when it is often not clear in what exact form that asset is going to be sold, so, yes there are lots of difficult things that we have to estimate. I think here the question is the clarity about the policy rather than the uncertainty that surrounds the estimate as much as—

Q255 Chair: But you are writing in zero for something that is very likely to have a positive number, are you not?

Robert Chote: As we said in the letter, there are offsetting effects in different parts of the public finances if you are selling an asset that brings in a stream of revenue. It could well be that the value of the asset is equal to the present value of the future stream of the revenue, for example. And so you could see often offsetting effects there, but I think you do have to say, "Can we be clear enough about what the policy is? Is this going to go ahead?" and whether you can say what information there is available. So I think in terms of where we can go forward from the information that we have presented in the past, the two areas that I think are most amenable to progress would be, firstly, setting out as far as we can in advance how we think a particular type of asset sale is likely to score, so to try to identify at least qualitatively where it will show up in different parts of the public finances—

Q256 Chair: That is not the question that I am really posing to you. I am posing the principle of whether you should try to establish an indicative number over the forecasting period, and I agree that there will be pluses and minuses and various assumptions that you will need to make in order to arrive at a number, but it does not strike me that the uncertainty involved is any greater than it was, for example, in the 1980s and 1990s when there was always an indicative line for privatisation proceeds in the accounts.

Robert Chote: Hopefully, we are trying to be more transparent about the way that we are presenting these things nowadays, and I think actually requiring some clarity in terms of the policy and the timing in which it would have its effect is a sensible thing. I think the difficulty of producing an aggregate estimate of where this is going to come from in that we do not break it down into its individual components and then attributing it that year by year, is that there is not a strong enough evidence base to say that that is a sensible projection. I think it would be misleading; it would be a bit un-transparent if we were not prepared to explain where it was coming from, and it would also be an open invitation to Ministers to make pronouncements about the fact that they intend to sell something which subsequently turns out not to be sold. The tote has been at the top of the list for quite a long period of time and has not actually come off the slipway yet.

Q257 Chair: None of the concerns that you have expressed seem to have been insurmountable in the past, and I would be grateful if you would take another look at this issue. I would also be grateful if you make sure that it is a subject that you look carefully at with respect to your assessment to overall fiscal sustainability.

Robert Chote: I think there is an interesting issue, because we have more emphasis on the balance sheet side there, so it may be possible to look more at the issue of where the valuations of these things appear. I think Whole of Government Accounts will hopefully help us in that when we get those.

Q258 Chair: In our letter, we asked for you to make that first assessment for the period at the end of this Parliament. Are you happy to do that?

Robert Chote: Sorry, so for—

Chair: This is a long run fiscal sustainability assessment and the question is: where should be the start date for your first forward-looking part of that assessment? And I am suggesting that the opportunity—

Robert Chote: I think the general approach for the whole long-term sustainability report is that you take the forecast as we have it over the five year period, and that is your jumping-off point on the grounds that we know what policy is defined to be over that period, and then you have to say—

Q259 Chair: It is very hard work this morning. Your jumping-off point is clearly going to be different, is it not, for the sustainability estimate if it includes privatisation proceeds? Your jumping-off point will not be the same as the forecast which is explicitly excluding those numbers.

Robert Chote: I am not sure by that stage we are going to know if and when these things are going to be sold. What we may be able to do is to say if you look at the value of these assets, as far as it is possible to estimate, then there may be more information on that which, obviously, feeds into the long-term sustainability report.

Q260 Chair: Yes. So are we getting a commitment, in four years time, to have a fiscal sustainability number as the starting off point that will include privatisation proceeds?

Robert Chote: Those privatisation proceeds where we are clear enough what the policy is, that we can have essential—

Q261 Chair: That is back to your letters, so the answer is that you have not made up your mind.

Robert Chote: If we can produce an estimate that is based on sufficient evidence that we think is robust enough, then by all means, but I would not want to make a commitment to that prior to having to worked out whether we have the robust enough evidence for it.

Chair: We have not come very far this morning so far.

Q262 Mr Mudie: I cannot think I will improve matters, sir, but we will try. In terms of unemployment and employment, I seem to see from your figures that you have downgraded the private sector employment level and increased the public sector employment level over the period.

Robert Chote: The aggregate employment, the revision to the figures for employment and unemployment, is essentially a reflection of what we have done to the overall path of economic growth. We are more pessimistic about growth in the short term and so therefore you have less overall employment growth and a slightly worse picture for unemployment. On the Government side, we have obviously taken into account the latest data that we have had from ONS, the reclassification decisions there, and at the moment we continue to have to use this top-down approach, essentially trying to derive a path of general Government employment from the overall pool of money available to spend on it and assumptions about pay bills, so that is where that change has come about.

Q263 Mr Mudie: I think the Chairman was right. Let us try and put that into English, and coming from me, that is something.

Robert Chote: Growth is lower, unemployment is higher, and data suggests there are more public sector employees.

Q264 Mr Mudie: Sorry, say that again. "Unemployment is higher and there are more ..." Finish that sentence off.

Graham Parker: Data suggests there are slightly more Government employees.

Q265 Mr Mudie: And apart from this business of the colleges coming into figures, there are rumours that, certainly at Government level, the Departments are not cutting as fast as, say, the local authorities. Is that reflected in the figures?

Robert Chote: It will not be reflected in the figures because they are a top-down analysis based on the total amount of money spent in central government, local authorities and the BBC. I think, hopefully, before long it will be possible to supersede these sorts of forecasts by actual estimates out of departments of how many people they are intending to employ and presumably at some stage, before too long, the Cabinet Office will be pulling that sort of data together.

Q266 Q27 Mr Mudie: That is one of the questions. In the past, you have suggested something about publishing specific workforce plans. Have you raised that with the Treasury and have you had discussions with them?

Robert Chote: We asked whether they—and that would be for them to do because it would be pulling together data from Departments, so we said, "Do we need to continue with this process or are you effectively going to supersede it by having a full set of employment numbers from Departments?" and they said that they were not in a position to do that yet, and hence we have done another round of this one.

Q267 Mr Mudie: I understand the vagueness of that reply. Did they say they will do it? You said they are not in a position to do it now. Are they going to do it, and when?

Robert Chote: I do not have an answer to that question.

Q268 Mr Mudie: Stephen is looking restless. Is it Stephen? No, Graham looking restless beside him. Do you know anything about this?

Graham Parker: No. It is up to them. It is for them to answer that question.

Q269 Mr Mudie: Robert, if you thought it was important and you have asked and you have not received an answer, why not and what have you done about it and how satisfied are you with it? If it is important and you asked them, and months have passed and you have no response, come on.

Robert Chote: The Government has to decide when it believes that its own employment plans are robust enough for them to publish, so I think you have to say, "When are you—"

Mr Mudie: But you could wait forever. That could be an excuse for doing nothing.

Robert Chote: And in the meantime—

Q270 Mr Mudie: You have the job of independent Office of Budget Responsibility; you cannot have the Treasury deciding we cannot give you these figures because we are unsure of them. "When will you be sure of them?" "Well, we will tell you when we are." That is no way to let them pull you around.

Robert Chote: We continue to use this method for as long as we have to until the Government is in a position to do that. But you have to ask them to say, you know—

Q271 Mr Mudie: It would be very helpful if you said to us that any help we can give in pressurising the Treasury into getting their act together sooner would help you do your job, we would be happy to do it.

Robert Chote: But you will find a reference in the book, I think, for the desirability of them actually publishing estimates like that so we do not have to continue to—

Mr Mudie: Melvin used to put little notes that he would use later to say that he had told us about the impending crisis; it would be very much—

Robert Chote: I'm happy for you to say if you—

Mr Mudie: The importance of this is—

Robert Chote: If you were able to encourage them to do that, I would be delighted.

Q272 Mr Mudie: Good, I think that is an important part of your job. Now, the important part in the figures is that we had very strong arguments last year about the private sector were going to produce the jobs that the public sector were losing so there would not be heavy unemployment because they would switch over. The figures you have given suggest that you have reduced your figure by 200,000 for the private sector. You have kept the figure for the public sector level, but you have indicated elsewhere in the report that there is movement that you may not have picked up. We would suggest that, from personal experience, the local authorities and the health service are cutting faster. So the 400,000 may be, as was raised last year, wrong; it is going up but the private sector's job creation is going down. Is that now a worry to the basic strategy or is it just a blip?

Robert Chote: As I said, knowing the timing of exactly when the changes in general Government employment are going to come along does, as you say, depend on some bits of Government, presumably, deciding that they want to get the job that they think will need to be done eventually done relatively early and relatively later and you may be picking up differences between local Government and other bits of Government and how they do that. So one issue is how much of the data that you have seen for the recent past showing public sector jobs going relatively quickly—to what extent that is people doing the job that our figures suggest is implied by the spending numbers over the coming four years, earlier or whether that is in addition, and that is something that we simply do not have the information to base that on—

Q273 Mr Mudie: Are you seeking that? Are you keeping track of local authority job losses? Because it is starting this financial year. This Friday, all the redundancy notices are going out, people are taking it now. Are you keeping track of it?

Robert Chote: No, we are not. We are looking at an aggregate forecast for employment, which is driven from the approach we are taking on economic growth.

Q274 Mr Mudie: If the Budget figures are different by more people being made unemployed and redundant and the private sector are not picking those up, that affects the Budget figures in a major way.

Robert Chote: The overall level of employment is likely to be determined by the overall level of demand in the economy, and that is reflected—the make-up obviously does depend in part on what is going on in the public sector, but we have a limited amount of information that we can draw upon.

Q275 Mr Mudie: A last question on youth unemployment. There is a suggestion, as happened in the 1980s, that a long period of unemployment at the start of a youngster's life, often coming out with different skills and different education, sort of scars them for life and that they see that as a way of life and we have lost generations since the 1980s. Do you see any sign, do you have any fear of that in the figures that that is going to happen again?

Robert Chote: It is obviously a concern. At the moment the evidence on detachment would suggest that the level of long-term unemployment, and the level of long-term unemployment amongst relatively young people, is lower than it was in the 1990s. But it clearly is a risk to the forecast and when we produced our persistent low growth scenario last time around you will recall that we had a different view of the long-term rate of unemployment in that it reflects exactly that sort of risk.

Q276 Mark Garnier: Good morning. Can we turn to the housing market? There have obviously been a number of measures that have been brought in with the budget including first time buyer and also some of those planning rules. Overall what impact do you think this Budget will have on the residential housing market?

Robert Chote: I think in the longer term the issue of the planning reform is the item that has the potential greatest impact in the longer term but it is not clear exactly how that will materialise and what the effects will be. There is certainly plenty of evidence, people have suggested, that you might expect benefits from planning reform, not just in housing but also in retail distribution et cetera. I think in terms of its—we haven't reflected that in the projections for the housing market performance, what we have basically done there is we take the independent forecasts for house prices over the next couple of years, and in this occasion we are using those forecasts for the CLG measure of house prices and then extrapolate forward thereafter in terms of the average earnings. You might expect assistance to first time buyers, for example, to do more to push up on the demand side, but I don't know whether, Steve, you're—

Stephen Nickell: I think that there is an explicit piece of assistance to first time buyers, but it's relatively modest so I don't imagine that will have an overall very big impact on the housing market. I mean, the fact is that the credit crunch is restricting mortgage availability to first time buyers in a very serious way, as you can see from the very large rise in deposits that are required, and there doesn't seem to be much sign of that changing soon. I would argue that the changes, so far, that have been announced in the Budget will only have a relatively modest impact on the prospects for the housing market.

Q277 Mark Garnier: You have in your figures from 2012 and onwards the transactions jumping by 20% to 13-14, 10% to 14-15, 5.2% 15-16. That is quite a sizeable jump from a drop of 1.9% in 11-12 and 10-11. What are you basing that on, or again is this just simply—

Robert Chote: It's based on a view of in the long-term you get back to the level of house price transactions implied by the average period for which people occupy a house. At the moment you have housing transactions considerably below that sort of level, so essentially we've taken a judgment about over a number of years returning to that level.

Q278 Mark Garnier: So this is suggested as a bit of a backlog that is going to come through in those two years when it's 20%, essentially.

Robert Chote: Yes.

Q279 Mark Garnier: There have been one or two commentators that have been talking about the fact that the property market is still very high, and I think you and I spoke about this in the past, and certainly some people subscribe to the fact that it really is still high particularly when you look at first time buyers coming into the market going back 40 years or 30 years was early 20s and now it is late 30s. Do you think there is a questionable moral issue, if you like, with trying to help people into the housing market as first home buyers at this high level? Or do you think those commentators are wrong?

Stephen Nickell: Do you think there's a—did you say "a moral"?

Mark Garnier: There is one or two commentators in the press have suggested that it is the wrong thing to do to try to be helping first time buyers at the very high level. Do you think that is an unfair criticism?

Stephen Nickell: I think you can see where people are coming from when it comes to saying help first time buyers. The fact is that given the shortage of housing—that is to say the low level of house building relative to the rise in the number of households over the last decade—simply helping first time buyers just raises the demand for housing which will just be reflected in prices because real help to first time buyers, that is to say allowing more first time buyers to move into houses, can only happen if there are more houses for them to move into. If there aren't any more houses for them to move into the help for first time buyers equals rising prices.

Q280 Mark Garnier: So do you feel that there should be more help for the construction industry be it the production of raw materials and constructors as opposed to necessarily just having something like this to—

Stephen Nickell: I think that I would go back to planning—in fact, I think that the binding constraint over the last two decades has been the planning constraint and that if the planning constraint can be eased then I think that's the best prospect for house building and therefore for the construction sector and in the long-term that would be the best prospect for first time buyers because then there will be more houses and then they have some chance of moving into them.

Q281 Mark Garnier: On that basis do you think the Government could have gone further with the planning changes?

Stephen Nickell: They produce a growth report and they have their eye on the planning system and they rightly argue, the Treasury rightly argue, that the planning system is holding back the construction sector and maybe even productivity growth. On the other hand, of course, this is—I mean, I hesitate to step into a political arena—obviously a highly political activity because there are forces in the other direction, forces of localism and so on. You don't need me to tell you this, and so the eventual outcome is quite hard to perceive at the present time.

Q282 Mark Garnier: That is quite a political answer. So do you have an opinion on this?

Stephen Nickell: Do I have an opinion?

Mark Garnier: One that's actually coming to one side of the fence or another, I mean—

Stephen Nickell: Are you asking me—should the OBR have an opinion on this highly political subject.

Mark Garnier: Well, as an economist.

Stephen Nickell: As an economist. I'm more on the side of relaxing the planning constraints. That would be my own—

Q283 Mark Garnier: So, the Government could have done more?

Stephen Nickell: Oh, the Government could have done more. Well let's see how the proposals in the growth review actually pan out because we don't know what the outcome is going to be at the moment.

Q284 Andrea Leadsom: Thank you, Chairman. I would like to talk to you a little bit out inflation because interestingly you seem to be rather in line with the more laissez faire members of the Monetary Policy Committee suggesting, I think, that inflation will sort itself out by 2013; you are suggesting that it will be back at the central target of 2%. Can you just talk me through what you think the kind of cost per inflationary factors—commodity prices rising, the VAT rise plus the depreciation of Sterling—what impact are those in aggregate having on the public finances and how are they going to take us back to the central 2% inflation rate by the middle of 2013?

Robert Chote: Shall I start off with the prospects for inflation and then turn to the prospects for the public finances? I guess I think our view of inflation over the medium term partly reflects the fact that we still see there being considerable spare capacity in the economy and that will have an underlying downward effect on inflation. There is also the fact that VAT, unless there's a policy change we're not expecting, is not going to go up again and therefore the increase in the price level as a result of that will drop out of annual comparison so that pulls the rate down. We've made the assumption that oil prices move in line with a futures curve over the period of the forecast, and since the November forecast you've seen the Sterling price jump by about £15 in the spot price but by less if you go further out. We're assuming that food prices, although higher, are not going to continue to rise and therefore there's a persistent effect there. So taking all of those factors together you would expect inflation to come back down. There's clearly the possibility that the bad news on inflation becomes incorporated in wage increases and that you end up with greater persistence as a result of that and that's why we've included the persistent high inflation scenario as one of the two alternatives which basically says what would the impact be if that were to persist.

That shows the contrast between the central forecast and that scenario does point up one of the interesting ways in which inflation is affecting the public finances. At the moment the impact in the central forecast is a negative one because it's dominated in large part by the impact on inflation on the cost of social security bills because of benefit up-rating and on the cost of index linked gilts. But because we're assuming it's not incorporated into wage increases it's no pushing up the total cash value of spending and incomes and therefore providing more revenue there.

  

Q285 Andrea Leadsom: So the big assumption is—

Robert Chote: But the irony if inflation stays higher the impact on the public finances actually looks less harmful over that period simply because you're getting more revenue there. There may of course be very good other reasons for not wanting that scenario to unfold.

Q286 Andrea Leadsom: Because then you are making big assumptions on fuel prices not continuing to exponentially rise, likewise food prices and you are also assuming that earnings will not go up in line with this, what you believe is a temporary inflation blip. So how much sensitivity analysis have you done around those three assumptions not proving to be true?

Robert Chote: Well, that's what I was saying. We've done a sensitivity analysis in the sense of saying, "What happens if inflation persists at a higher level and what impact would that have?" and we've spelt that out there.

I think in terms of the oil effect we do have, somewhere, a reference to the direct effects of the increase in the oil price we have had, which from memory is .4% on CPI from the increase that we've seen since November, so you might expect that to be, you know, you could scale that if there were to be another increase of a similar proportion, but I'm not sure we included one for food prices.

Q287 Andrea Leadsom: And your expectations, your curve on the way inflation will right itself back to the 2% does not assume any action on the part of the MPC. You are assuming that base rates remain fixed, is that correct?

Robert Chote: We're assuming that monetary policy is in line with market expectations.

Q288 Andrea Leadsom: Which is what particularly? You are assuming that interest rates are not—the base rate does not rise.

Robert Chote: It goes up. The interest rates go up with rates that the market is expecting.

Q289 Andrea Leadsom: Sorry, let me just be very clear, you are assuming the MPC is not going to raise the base rate. Is that right?

Robert Chote: No, we're assuming that—exactly, that's right. We're assuming that it rises in line with the expectations of the financial market. Not hugely.

Andrea Leadsom: Right. Thank you.

Q290 Chuka Umunna: Before I ask you about some of the risks can I just ask you a question about your claimant count figures because I noticed that from November to your latest figures claimant count has been revised up by 50,000 this year, 120,000 next year and 130,000 the year after. Can you just explain to us why you have revised them up?

Robert Chote: Well the main reason is that it's an automatic consequence of the fact that we're expecting a weaker profile for economic growth and the level of activity. That reflects the evidence on weaker momentum behind the economy coming into the end of last year and the impact of inflation squeezing consumer spending and therefore squeezing growth. So the main factor there is that you essentially have is less growth around and as a consequence of less growth we see unemployment peaking at higher level, otherwise we'd be—we still basically have it going up for a bit in the early part of this year and then started to come down.

Q291 Chuka Umunna: Thank you I just wanted to check that I was not misreading something. In your report you set out a few parameters and the effect you think they will have in your forecast. So you talk about the size of the output gap, the speed with which it will close, interest rates on Government debt and so on. Where do you think the main risks lie for the Government in meeting its fiscal target?

Robert Chote: Well the biggest uncertainty is whether we have the amount of spare capacity in the economy correct because essentially the amount of spare capacity you have determines how far the economy can grow in a sustainable way and therefore how much of the deficit that we have at the moment will be soaked up naturally as the economy recovers and how much, as it were, is left for policy to deal with.

Q292 Chuka Umunna: And if the Chancellor has to borrow more, what effect do you think that is going to have on his ability to meet his fiscal target?

Robert Chote: Well it would depend on why he has to borrow more. The targets he has are the first one the fiscal mandate is set in cyclically adjusted terms, so if he had to borrow more because he thought that the economy was temporarily weakened but that it would make up that lost ground that's not going to affect his ability to hit that target. If he were to—if he was borrowing more and you thought that that bad news was not going to be made up then that would have a direct effect. In terms of the second supplementary target, the difficulty there is that it's not a target for the level of debt but just how much it moves between 14-15 and 15-16. The difficulty with that target is it's really down to what's happening between those two years. We see there being no room for manoeuvre, you'd have to expect that the situation in 15-16 to be appreciably worse relative to the position in 14-15 for that to be a particularly binding constraint at this stage, but it's not certain by any means.

Q293 Chuka Umunna: And if he is in that situation, perhaps if I just direct this to Mr Parker, because you seem to want to say something, what options in that scenario would the Chancellor have to get back on track?

Graham Parker: What, in the second scenario where it's structural borrowing? It depends, you know, again on what was going to happen to the economy, I guess. But clearly it's not for us to decide whether he needs to raise taxes or reduce spending further. The only way if he got higher structural borrowing would be to do one of those things if he wants to meet the mandate.

Q294 Chuka Umunna: Perhaps if I was to move on to what would happen—with you, Mr Nickell—if growth came in lower than forecast? The Chancellor is being quite clear that he will look to the MPC to stimulate growth in the economy; he said that in the House of Commons on 29 November.

We obviously had the MPC in front of us a couple of weeks ago and the message I had from the evidence that they gave was that if inflation is as per their central projection for the next year their ability to further make some monetary policy is going to be quite restricted. Now, obviously on the fiscal side the automatic stabilisers will kick in, but what other options would there be in that scenario where you have a constrained MPC, Mr Nickell, to stimulate growth in the economy if it is more sluggish than we think it may be now with your downgraded growth forecast?

Stephen Nickell: That's a very important question. Can I just go back to inflation and then come back to your question? I think the biggest risk to this forecast, and in some sense the biggest risk to the economy, is if oil prices and food prices, but particularly oil prices keep rising faster than the average rate of inflation because, as you know, embedded in our forecast is the prediction of the forward market for oil prices, which is relatively flat and viewed somewhat downward moving. So if the oil prices continue to move up then inflation will be higher in our forecast and, under the assumption—which I think is reasonable—that wages don't adjust to this, real wages will fall and consumption will fall and growth will be lower. That in some senses is the worst of all possible worlds because we have higher inflation and lower growth as a consequence of this which means that the difficulties facing the MPC are of a very high order—

Q295 Chuka Umunna: Particularly what's going on in the Middle East, I suppose?

Stephen Nickell: One can think of any number of scenarios as to why the oil price might continue to rise faster than was expected and then the MPC is in a very tricky position because the inflation forecast is higher and it's not a position I would like to be in. So the question, "What should be the policy response under those circumstances?" is one which luckily I don't have to answer.

Q296 Chuka Umunna: That was very skilfully done, Mr Nickell, but I am actually asking you the question and it would be nice to have an answer. And I suppose I'm not necessarily asking you to say exactly what the Chancellor should do, but what I am asking you is: what are the options in that scenario where you have a constrained MPC and you have growth coming in lower than forecast and my constituents and the constituents of everybody around the table are paying the price?

Clearly one must hope that the Chancellor would not sit on his hands, so what I am asking you is what are his options in that scenario where the MPC can't do anything to stimulate demand in the economy? Okay, maybe the automatic stabilisers will kick in; what are the other options for him to stimulate growth and what other contingency planning can be provided for?

Stephen Nickell: Well the options are clearly he can cut taxes or raise expenditure and he could cut taxes in such a way as to try and offset the increasing oil price, but that would be at the cost of his fiscal plans to some extent, plainly.

Q297 Chuka Umunna: This is why it's a difficult decision but of course—

Stephen Nickell: And one luckily I don't have to make.

Chuka Umunna: —could change his fiscal plans could he not, Mr Nickell?

Stephen Nickell: That's his responsibility. I mean, of course he could.

Q298 Michael Fallon: Professor Nickell, in Chapter Five you sketch out a weak Euro area scenario and you suggest that the overall effect of it would be negligible on borrowing: why should we not worry about problems in the eurozone?

Stephen Nickell: The weak Euro scenario has—my reading of it—

Michael Fallon: Paragraph five, 42.

Stephen Nickell: Oh right, I was looking at table three.

Michael Fallon: Page 164.

Stephen Nickell: Yes, now are you asking why should we worry about it?

Q299 Michael Fallon: You said the overall impact is small.

Stephen Nickell: On net borrowing is small.

Michael Fallon: Yes.

Stephen Nickell: Well that doesn't mean that the overall impact—we don't just worry about net borrowing, we worry about the people in this country and as far as I can see they would be, initially at least, somewhat worse off because of the fall in demand. But further out, of course, they will actually benefit because real wages will be higher than otherwise would be the case. That's basically because our exchange rate rises relative to the eurozone so of course eurozone goods become cheaper which is helpful.

Q300 Michael Fallon: That implies the recovery is not particularly reliant on exports to the eurozone. Is not, doesn't it?

Stephen Nickell: Well, yes, but what you lose on one side in terms of exports to the eurozone you gain on the other side in the longer term because of increased consumption. So you get less of the rebalancing that is currently in our forecast but in the longer term the household consumption growth compensates.

Q301 Michael Fallon: You don't think that if the eurozone continues to weaken there would, in fact then, be lower consumer confidence and thus in the end lower consumption?

Stephen Nickell: Well I guess that consumer confidence is one thing, but real incomes tend to trump consumer confidence and if real incomes improve that has a more direct impact on consumption than consumer confidence, I would argue.

Q302 Michael Fallon: And what happens if the problems in the Zone get worse this year and next; what's the impact on the public finances of the deterioration of the Zone?

Stephen Nickell: Impact on the public finances—

Michael Fallon: Well, that is what you deal with.

Stephen Nickell: Sorry?

Michael Fallon: That is what you're responsible for.

Stephen Nickell: No, we're responsible for forecasting the economy. The impact on the public finances is a very little change because there are changes in—let me just—I have to work this out now. Inflation is weaker so that will have various offsetting effects on the public finances, consumption is higher so VAT will go up. I mean, there are, sort of, pluses and minuses in the public finances and the overall impact is relatively modest.

Q303 Michael Fallon: If there is a crisis in the eurozone what more could Government do to stimulate growth here to offset it?

Stephen Nickell: What more could the Government do? Aside from any response of the MPC?

Michael Fallon: Yes, what could the Government do to strengthen growth here if we see a serious deterioration in the eurozone?

Stephen Nickell: I wouldn't expect the Government to adjust its fiscal or other policies in any serious way.

Q304 Stewart Hosie: Robert, in the central forecast you have a positive contribution to GDP growth from net trade of 0.7%, 0.6% and 0.5% over the next five years. In the weak Euro scenario that goes to 0.2, 0.3, 0.1, 0.1, 0.1 for the next five years. Convince me why I should believe there's a positive contribution to GDP growth from net trade in either scenario, given what we have witnessed in terms of balance of trade over the last three, four, five years?

Robert Chote: Well, I think you can look at the contribution that you had the last time we had a significant depreciation of the exchange rate in the 1990s; and we're assuming a contribution that is not as dramatic per percentage point change in the exchange rate than we had then. I think the fact that goods export performance has been relatively positive coming out of last year between November and now while trade growth has been stronger than we've anticipated then it's reflected in things like the IMF forecast. That seems a reasonable view to take looking forward on the basis of the history and the basis of what we've seen in the recent past.

If you look at the data over the last couple of quarters, the picture is slightly muddied by the aircraft imports that we've highlighted in the report, but I think, as I say, a combination of history and the rather greater momentum and news that we've had in recent data, I don't think it's unreasonable. In the contrast between the central scenario and the Euro scenario, as Steve said, you're essentially talking about a shift in the balance in the sense that if you're having weaker external demand you would assume that the Bank of England, other things being equal, is going to want to see more domestic demand and so you do have less of a contribution there. The difficulty would come obviously if you arrived at the stage where the Bank of England was constrained and being unable to compensate for that, but with the path of interest rates heading where they are, we're away from that yet.

Q305 Stewart Hosie: You are talking about the history of this, but let's look at the last four or five years. The sterling exchange rate index has a 23-and-a-bit% fall since the peak in July 2007. There has been a four-year fall peak to trough against the euro, and there was a three-year fall against the dollar. We keep being told, "Ah, the depreciation will see exports begin to boom". Exports did not boom. In 2010, we saw that we did not move forward from the £82 billion deficit in the trade in goods. We managed to create a colossal £97 billion deficit in the trade in goods and a £46 billion deficit in goods and services. There was a 0.3% negative contribution in Q4 last year. I am not seeing any evidence at all that the depreciation, which has been huge over a prolonged period, has delivered the positive contribution to GDP growth that people expect.

Robert Chote: The history of the past does come with a lag. Steve may be able to talk about that. The other thing you have to bear in mind is that in terms of a net trade contribution, you are looking at both the imports and the exports, so we also have a weaker forecast for consumption and consumer spending going forward, which is likely to reduce the amount of imports you have as well, so you have movement on both sides of the account there. Steve, do you want to say anything the fact that we did see a response to the lower exchange rate the last time that this happened but it did not come to anything?

Stephen Nickell: Yes. Responses to changes in the exchange rate take quite some time to come through. Back in the mid-1990s, they did come through in the end. The surveys and so on are suggesting that there is quite a lot of strength in exports coming up, and furthermore, this year we have had a great deal of restocking, which is very import-intensive. That will fade away. This is our best judgement as to the impact of the exchange rate fall, but of course, as with many of these things, there is a good deal of uncertainty about this. I think you may be right to be ever so slightly sceptical, because people have promised this sort of thing in the past.

Stewart Hosie: I am considerably sceptical, not least because one of you fine gentlemen gave me the same answer when I asked you this question last year. I understand there is a lag, but the reason I gave the SERI figures is because this is a four-year, near-quarter depreciation against the major countries to which we export. There comes a time when we no longer have a lag we are waiting on or a catch-up we are waiting on, but a structural problem, so I will remain suspicious, but can I ask that you look at this? All the evidence over the last four years is that we have not benefited, given the huge increase in the trade deficit.

Q306 John Thurso: This is a process question. What notice did you have of the changes to the oil and gas regime, i.e. the supplementary charge, and to fuel tax?

Robert Chote: We had some of the fuel duty changed bar the 1p reduction, which we certainly knew about before the deadline we were talking about. I cannot remember precisely when we were given that. It was the additional 1p cut that was gaining beyond the deadline.

Q307 John Thurso: Let me get this straight. The two-week deadline: did you know about the cancellation of the accelerator?

Robert Chote: Yes, that is right. It was the additional 1p, which is about £450 million worth of the reduction.

Q308 John Thurso: Did you know before the two-week time limit about the changes to the tax regime for the supplementary level?

Robert Chote: Yes.

John Thurso: So that was all done two weeks ahead.

Robert Chote: Yes.

Q309 John Thurso: What estimate, therefore, have you been able to make of the impact of the changes to the oil and gas regime?

Robert Chote: The costing document: we are assuming there is no significant effect on the investment and production profile of that change. It should be said that there is quite a lot of change in the expected profile of North Sea activity between the November and March forecasts because there is new survey data from DECC as to the research and development plans and capital expenditure plans over that period, so relative to those, we thought the changes to the tax change would be relatively modest.

Q310 John Thurso: There are two areas in which I would be interested where you have looked in this. You have just started to address one, which is investment going forward. Today's headline in that great newspaper, The Preston Journal, is that Statoil have cancelled their forward investment plans. I understand also that Centrica have put a moratorium on all future investment in gas until they have been able to work through the changes. Bearing in mind that the cost of gas is actually well below the stipulated $75-dollar-per-barrel limit, being around the mid-50s, the two questions are: how did you test and what have you seen as the Treasury's test on investment overall, and secondly, on the differential effect between oil and gas?

Graham Parker: We did talk to Treasury about this, but certainly, on oil, the conclusion we reached on the high oil prices was that this is still very much a profits tax, so it is just increasing the Government's share of the profit on the oil production. Because of the high oil prices we are forecasting, we assume that the companies would still want to go ahead, on that basis.

Q311 John Thurso: Are you aware of the considerable difference between the oil price and the gas price, and the volume of profit that comes out of the North Sea that is gas related? What studies did you do on the gas price?

Graham Parker: Yes. The gas prices are quite variable. The prices from different fields vary quite a lot. Some fields are determined by the spot price of gas, and others have it written into their contracts. We thought that there may be some effects. We did not think it would have that much of a significant effect on the forecast period, because it is still a profit tax.

Q312 John Thurso: So, the assumption that has been made in forward forecasting is that as far as the oil price goes, there is sufficient profit and they are still making more money, so they will go ahead. What about the gas price?

Graham Parker: If they are making a profit, they would still go ahead, but clearly, there is more risk there. I should point out that the main effect of a reduction in the investment would be an increase in tax take over the forecast period. There is quite a lag between the reduction in investment and the reduction in production.

Q313 John Thurso: Yes, but if there is a rapid decrease in investment activity, there is a rapid decrease in the economy of the second-largest growth area of the United Kingdom, which may or may not be something that was taken into account. The other point on gas price is that this will presumably feed directly through into domestic inflation and domestic gas prices.

Graham Parker: I guess there is more likelihood of it affecting gas prices than oil prices, yes.

Q314 John Thurso: It seems to me that they are two very distinctly different sets of calculations, and therefore, what I am wondering on the process is whether either you or the Treasury had sufficient time to do a proper piece of work on the impact that this is likely to have.

Graham Parker: I certainly think we would have liked more time to be able to discuss it more widely, and it is probably something we should look at in our work-up. To do this properly, you do have to do a thorough analysis on an investment, project-by-project basis.

Q315 John Thurso: If you look at your box 4.1 and some of the forecasts and so forth that are made in there, you do say the impact on the economy is highly uncertain, as are the projections of future North Sea oil production, but clearly, if future Chancellors are going to be making these kinds of decisions, we really need to know a very great deal more. Is that something you feel the OBR should be taking forward?

Robert Chote: We will get to know more. Certainly, when we get to the next forecast round, DECC will have much more robust data on which to view the anecdotal talk—as you say—of what is being reported in the newspapers at the moment and whether that is actually showing up in what they are reporting as a long-term profile. There has been quite a lot of change in that survey since November anyway, so we will certainly keep a very close eye on that.

Q316 Chair: Have you done a full rerun of the economic and fiscal forecast to take account of all these things that came to you too late, where you did not have sufficient time?

Robert Chote: No. The main impact that you would have seen would have been the inflation impact from fuel—

Chair: Was the answer yes or no?

Robert Chote: No.

Q317 Chair: So, we do not know whether your judgement that to have done this work could have led you into publishing something that would have been inaccurate or misleading is correct.

Robert Chote: No, but we are confident, given the nature of the changes, that the effect would not have been material.

Q318 John Mann: In your labour market statistics, there is nothing about who the new jobs are; for example, how many are migrant workers. Can we in the general public expect to see that in future reports?

Robert Chote: It is not something that falls within our remit in terms of the impact on the public finances. No.

Q319 John Mann: It is an important factor to know who the new jobs are and where they have come from, because that affects both economic and social policy. If you are predicting 1.1 million new jobs, and 700,000 are new migrant workers, that does not impact on the economy. If they are not migrant workers and it is the under-employed or unemployed returning to work, that has a huge impact. We need to know that, so why has that not been included in your analysis?

Robert Chote: The experts who came before you on Friday were saying that given, for example, the fact that you have such large gross flows in and out of employment and unemployment, giving an analysis that would say, "Do these new jobs go to migrant workers?" is something that would be beyond our remit and is a rather different category of work.

Q320 John Mann: In terms of output gaps, such as housing supply and where people can go to establish communities and language barriers, they are fundamental issues, and we cannot have a handle on the community—I do not see how you can—if that is not part of the statistics that you provide.

Robert Chote: We are making an assumption on net migration in terms of its impact on overall labour supply. That is within the forecast, and we look at that to see what the impact of recent data is, the policy and so on—

John Mann: Which is well-hidden in the forecast.

Robert Chote: —and reaching a judgement, we are assuming net migration of 140,000 per year on average over this period; that broader structure of the labour market analysis.

Q321 John Mann: That is well-hidden, and whether that has been met or not is a key economic factor. If the new jobs being created are in and around London, and young migrant workers from abroad as opposed to 40- to 50-year-old public servants in the North, that is a major factor that policymakers need to know. What is the point of the OBR if you are not building in that kind of analysis and forecasting on from that?

Robert Chote: All the points you raised there about access to housing and the impact on public services are very important parts of public policy analysis. In terms of the remit that we have been given, it is not central to that, but clearly, those sorts of questions would be ones the policymakers responsible for those areas will be looking at.

Q322 John Mann: Are you saying that the growth of the labour market is not in your remit? If 700,000 people enter the labour market net from abroad, that is fundamental to the labour market. If it is half that number, that is fundamental. It is fundamental to growth as well.

Robert Chote: We are taking into account the net migration change. I will locate where it is pointed out. That is underlying our view of trend growth in the long term.

Q323 John Mann: I am sure some of us, perhaps all, will be looking for that analysis in future reports to see what is happening and what the implications are. Can I come to a second issue? You did your first report in November. For that quarter, you had growth significantly wrong. Why?

Robert Chote: A combination of factors: one, the snowfall, which the ONS estimates to have taken half a percent of GDP off. The striking thing, though, was that once you take that factor out, it was still a lot weaker than everybody was expecting. The figures out today have now revised the fall to be smaller than it was previously estimated—0.5%—so we are back to where we started on that. I think, there, if you are looking—

John Mann: Yes, but you gave a rosy scenario in November. During the snow, you gave a rosy scenario for that quarter.

Robert Chote: And as I say, the striking thing was not so much the impact of the snow but the weakness of the underlying path, and I think what we have tried to do here is spell out, looking back to the figures from the middle part of last year, what the underlying path has been. If you take into account not just the snow but the construction data that has been particularly erratic, and also the anticipated effect of VAT, what you basically find is a slowing in this underlying profile from the middle part of last year through towards the end of last year. We are now assuming that that picks up during the course of the coming year, but I am not going to put my hand on my heart and say I can forecast quarterly growth.

Q324 John Mann: No, but it is the process, and whether the processes you are using and the assumptions built in are valid that is the critical issue. If, say, in the first quarter of this year you find that your assumptions are again too optimistic and growth comes in below what you predict, are you going to make a significant analysis of why you have been too optimistic, so that we can see the processes gone through and how you are correcting those processes in order to have confidence of the impartiality and the potential accuracy of future projections?

Robert Chote: Absolutely, and as I say, we put in considerable effort in terms of disaggregating the numbers, looking back, and trying to explain this pattern over the past year. There is clearly enormous uncertainty now as to what the pattern is over this period, how much of this was in fact snow, whether the ONS was right about that, and how much of a rebound you will see, and that will affect forecasts going forward.

Q325 John Mann: You will appreciate that you have some fairly optimistic assumptions on growth going into future years, and with real wages falling and with inflation increasing at the same time and with rising unemployment, we want to be certain that you are not projecting too glossy a scenario into the future for growth, and one that is unrealistic. Therefore, if you get it wrong again in the same direction, would you not agree with me that it is particular important that your next report will be analysing why you got it wrong?

Robert Chote: It is particularly important whether we get it wrong or we get it right. We might get the number right, but we might have been wrong about the underlying reasons for why it happened, and that is just as important to explain. The overall forecast for 2011 growth is a little more pessimistic than the independent average at the moment, but in terms of that exact quarterly profile, yes, there is enormous uncertainty and we will certainly endeavour to explain why it has turned out as it has.

Q326 Chair: Would you agree, Robert, that it is inherent in forecasting that forecasters in this field are always wrong?

Robert Chote: Yes. As I say, the probability of a forecast being wrong is roughly 100%.

Q327 Chair: Exactly. Would you also agree that one of your duties is to explain to the public what a forecast really is, both its scope and particularly its limits, which are considerable?

Robert Chote: Absolutely.

Chair: I hope you will keep doing it.

Q328 Mr Love: Taking on board all of those points about uncertainty, have you been surprised by the mildly controversial nature of the way that the forecasting industry has received your report, particularly in relation to meeting the fiscal mandate? Have you been surprised by that? A number of forecasters have suggested you will not meet the fiscal mandate; there are others that are concerned about your growth figures for later years. There are others that say things the mix of consumer expenditure and so forth. I just wonder whether that surprised you, or do you think your scenario planning answered those questions?

Robert Chote: I am certainly not surprised that there is a wide range of different view on those issues, and we try to explain that in more detail in the report and set out the diversity of those views. Yes, that is exactly why we have the scenario analysis for things like the size of the output gap, so we have made an assumption that it is 3%. That is our best guess. It does not look unreasonable by the range of others, but it would be foolish to assume that that is correct. We need to present the implications for the fiscal objectives, i.e. what if that number is wrong in one direction or another? All the forecasts, as the Chairman said, are bound to be wrong, but it is also a good way of showing where the errors are most likely to affect the judgement that you make about the eventual chances of meeting the mandate. There, it is the size of spare capacity, for example, more than the interest rates on Government debt. It is partly a reflection of that that we have relatively long maturity of debt, so that is not as important in the longer term, but it enables you to scale, somewhat, what you should be more or less worried about.

Q329 Mr Love: Because of the particular uncertainty, the IFS in its Green Budget suggested, and I quote, that "The Chancellor should have alternative plans available". How sympathetic are you to that idea?

Robert Chote: I am sure that any Government will want to think about its contingency planning very carefully at all times, but as you know, you and your colleagues in Parliament have instructed us not to look at alternative policy paths, so at the risk of being locked up, I had better not go too far in that direction.

Q330 Mr Love: Your report leaves trend growth unchanged for the year 2013 onwards. Does that mean that you believe that the proposals contained in the growth plan will have no impact on trend growth?

Robert Chote: I think the short answer is that we do not know until you see exactly how they were implemented. Even if you were clear about that, in areas like planning reform—there are people who have looked at that in detail, and we have cited some of the academic studies—it is not obvious what the size of the impact would be. On planning reform, as Steve mentioned, the tensions between presumption towards development and localism could affect that. Our view is that, stepping back, the evidence is not strong enough for us to say, "We are now confident that past trends are no longer the best guide to the potential growth of the economy in the longer term".

Q331 Mr Love: Does that mean that the Treasury did not offer any evidence when they gave you the growth plan, or is that—

Robert Chote: The Treasury put us under no pressure to increase our trend growth estimate on the basis of the information they presented to us, so it is not as though we were pushing back against a request that we raise the trend estimate.

Q332 Mr Love: When we had the forecasters in front of us last week, they expressed some scepticism about the ability to influence trend growth in the medium to longer term. Perhaps you, Mr Nickell, could respond to that. What is your view about how much we really can influence medium to longer term trend growth?

Stephen Nickell: History seems to suggest that it is very difficult, in the sense that since the war, the productivity growth in the UK on trend has been pretty stable. However, I think that you may be able to increase growth rates in productivity over some period—not necessarily forever—by changing policies, and there has been some evidence that some of the structural changes that have occurred in Britain in the last 40 years have indeed impacted on the rate of growth for a period of time, i.e. five to ten years. Changing the rate of growth forever is a pretty tall order.

Q333 Mr Love: Can I come back to you, Mr Chote? There has been quite a lot of scepticism expressed about enterprise zones. You have already commented on the difficulties of planning reform; of course, the devil is in the detail. Are there any other policies in the growth plan that you suggest would merit serious consideration to improve productivity in future years?

Robert Chote: You mentioned enterprise zones specifically. In terms of enterprise zones, I think there is a question about whether your objective with that is a fundamentally distributional one, i.e. you are trying to shift economic activity from one part of the country to another. Maybe you want to shift it to areas more likely to be affected by the public sector job reductions, for example. I think you would probably look at that as something that is more about changing the distribution of activity rather than an overall boost to growth. You could, if you had sufficiently strong Silicon Valley agglomeration effects. I guess the net effect would be greater. Given the amount of money that has been spent in that area, I would not cite that as a hugely important one.

Simplification of the tax system is something which, again, it is very hard to estimate the exact impact of. There is potential for—if not a long-term increase in the trend growth rate—an improvement over time if you were to come up with a simpler tax system, but again, as I say, judging the magnitude there is not easy.

Q334 Mr Love: Simplification, one understands, would be of great benefit, but some of the recommendations, particularly the anti-avoidance measures, are likely to complicate things by taking away from the manual, but they are actually adding to it at the same time. Are we still facing in the right direction?

Robert Chote: They have made statements about wanting to look at the income tax and national insurance system. I did not see the evidence that my successor gave you, but I presume you brought that issue up with him. We have said in the past that that is desirable. How much changing the administration of the system as distinct from some of the broader parameters delivers you all the benefits that you might think out of that is debateable, but there is certainly scope for good things.

  You are right about the avoidance. That, by its nature, tends to be chasing the problems where you find them, and as the costings assume, you tend to put in an attrition there. You assume that you close one hole as people gradually open others.

Q335 Chair: Our job is to audit your independence, and I think we should ask you one important question: were you put under any pressure from the Treasury to move in any direction in this forecast other than the one you wanted?

Robert Chote: I am pleased to report not.

Q336 Chair: Did you get full co-operation from the Treasury in the construction of this forecast?

Robert Chote: Yes.

Q337 Chair: You will understand, of course, that the counterpart to your independence that is laid down is statute is that, as we explained in our report on this prior to the Act being published as a bill, we expect to see flexibility in responding to reasonable requests from the Treasury and from us, and I hope you will bear that in mind with respect to some of the remarks that have been made today.

Robert Chote: You may not have liked the answer that I gave on the asset sales, but I hope you will appreciate that we did look at that seriously and that you will understand some of the concerns we have about moving forward, desirable as that is.

Chair: There were three or four issues of this type that have been raised today, of which that is one. Thank you very much indeed.



 
previous page contents next page


© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 9 April 2011