Office for Budget Responsibility - Treasury Contents


Written evidence submitted by the Social Market Foundation (SMF)

SUMMARY

  1.  Appropriate design of the OBR will be essential to its credibility, longevity and capacity to provide the best possible fiscal forecasts to guide policy. But in order to determine that design, a full analysis of the reasons for the failure of the old fiscal framework is needed.

2.  Consistently over-optimistic revenue projections over the past decade indicate a systemic bias in the way that projections were assembled. This is commonly attributed to political interference—a form of "top-down" bias. But given the nature of the forecasting process—based on myriad finely balanced judgements and assumptions made at all levels of the process—it is all but inevitable that it is vulnerable also to pervasive, if unintentional, organisational bias. It would be naïve to imagine that the judgements exercised by civil servants sitting within an organisation whose role is to serve the chancellor could be immune from such bias. A small OBR with minimal manpower will be unable to scrutinize the components of the forecast in sufficient detail to truly own the output and safe-guard against this, less visible, form of bias.

3.  The need to separate inherently political fiscal policymaking from essentially a-political forecasting is clear. But splitting the functions is further complicated by the fact that policymaking and forecasting are closely interconnected. Those Treasury officials responsible for feeding into the forecast are simultaneously needed in HM Treasury for their policymaking expertise during the budget exercise. Those making the forecast need to have a good grasp of policy and, currently, those making policy are the only ones who can make the forecast.

  4.  The only effective and practical solution to the problems of eliminating bias from the fiscal projections is therefore to ensure that the OBR is sufficiently well resourced for its officials to:

    — take on the forecasting role of officials at an early stage in the process, thus owning the forecast and eliminating the potential for bias;

    — have responsibility for a sufficiently narrow range of policy, to enable them to get to grips with emerging policy issues and their likely impact on the forecast; and

    — be based outside the Treasury.

  5.  Safe-guarding the forecasting process against both top-down and bottom-up bias will therefore require a significantly better resourced OBR than the current small secretariat. On the other hand, many fewer officials will be required than the hundreds currently involved in the process in some way. Only with this level of resource can the OBR as an institution address the full range of reasons for the failure of the defunct fiscal framework.

INTRODUCTION

  6.  This submission seeks to address the following two issues for the Office for Budget Responsibility (OBR) in relation to the Committee's terms of reference for this enquiry:

    — Appropriate means of ensuring both independence and accountability.

    — Appropriate resources for the OBR.

  7.  This submission draws on original work undertaken by the SMF in our recent publication "Forecasting Independence: Taking the politics out of fiscal projections", which is available to download from the website of the SMF. It also draws on the comments by attendees at a seminar held with Sir Alan Budd at SMF's offices in July 2010.

THE ELEMENTS OF FISCAL POLICYMAKING

  8.  Arrangements for fiscal policymaking ultimately come down to a set of choices around two dimensions:

    — Who should take tax and spending decisions and how?

    — Who should carry out the projections of revenue and spending on which those decisions are based?

  9.  These choices are subject to competing objectives such as the extent to which fiscal policymaking should be political and accountable versus independent and technocratic; and the extent to which decision-makers should be free to act with discretion, or should be constrained by pre-ordained rules or principles.

  10.  It is widely accepted that decisions over what to tax and how spend are entirely political. Similarly, decisions over when to spend and when to tax are usually deemed to be political. An exception to this is the case of Germany, where, from 2016 a balanced budget rule will operate, forcing the government to balance its books at all points in the economic cycle. However, the international consensus around who should undertake the revenue and spending projections on which policy decisions are made is moving in the direction of independence from government, in the form of an independent fiscal council, of which the OBR is one.

  11.  Nevertheless, the detailed design of the OBR will be essential to its credibility, longevity, and capacity to provide the best possible fiscal forecasts. In determining the appropriate design, this note argues that a full analysis of the reasons for the failure of the previous fiscal framework is necessary.

THE LAST GOVERNMENT'S EXPERIMENT WITH INSTITUTIONS

  12.  The self-imposed fiscal rules of the previous government represented an important experiment in the evolution of fiscal policymaking. The rules sought to articulate formal standards by which fiscal policymaking could be judged thereby increasing political accountability, even if the rules themselves amounted to nothing more than statements of intent.

13.  However, the current fiscal outlook, even in the context of the global economic slowdown of 2008-10, must be partly attributed to excessively loose fiscal policy in the years preceding the financial crisis. The reputational costs to the government of infringing their self-imposed rules may have had some constraining effect on policy decisions, but it was clearly inadequate to prevent the Government running a significant structural deficit. As such, the fiscal policymaking framework provided by the previous government's fiscal rules must ultimately be deemed to have failed.

WHY DID THE RULES FAIL?

  14.  Gordon Brown's fiscal rules failed, not because of over-optimistic GDP growth projections, but because of consistently over-optimistic revenue forecasts. In analysing the reasons for the rules' failure, the charge is that this must be attributable to some form of systemic bias—whether intentional or not—in the production of the forecast.

15.  There is widespread belief that ministerial pressure may have been at least partly responsible for the consistent over-estimation of future revenue. This can be called "top-down" bias. But top-down bias is not the only source of the problem—it is only the most visible one.

  16.  It is all but inevitable that the forecasting process is vulnerable also to pervasive, if unintentional, organisational bias. The forecast is built on myriad finely balanced judgements and assumptions made at all levels of the process—not just on "big ticket" judgements over, say, the size of the output gap. It would be naïve to imagine that the judgements exercised by civil servants sitting within an organisation whose role is to serve the chancellor could be immune from bias. Once again, it is important to stress that this "bottom-up" form of bias is most likely to be unconscious on the part of officials.

  17.  Essential to a full understanding of why the previous fiscal framework failed is, then, an appreciation of two kinds of bias: top-down political bias and bottom-up organisational bias. This understanding has significant implications for the design of the OBR in ensuring its independence, as well as for determining the resources it should command.

INSTITUTIONS

  18.  The failure of fiscal projections under the last government has led to a renewed interest in the institutional arrangements that underpin fiscal policymaking. This reflects a wider trend, over the past 13 years, of using careful institutional design to improve public policymaking, particularly by separating different functions according to the need for analytical independence and political accountability. Good examples include the granting of operational independence to the Bank of England, the establishment of an independent UK Statistics Authority and the creation of an independent Low Pay Commission to advise on the level of the minimum wage.

19.  Drawing on the success of these examples, as well as studying overseas fiscal councils, the Conservative Party in opposition announced that it would create an independent Office for Budget Responsibility, responsible for providing independent scrutiny of fiscal projections from HM Treasury. Quite rightly, their plans for the OBR aim to ensure the separation of inherently political policymaking from essentially a-political forecasting.

IMPLICATIONS FOR THE OFFICE FOR BUDGET RESPONSIBILITY

  20.  While the theoretical solution to the independence problem is clear—separating forecasting and policy-making roles—the practical implications are more tricky. The difficulty is driven by interconnectedness of policy and forecasting. For example, to effectively forecast the likely savings from the Government's plans to re-assess the eligibility of Incapacity Benefit claimants, one needs to have a reasonably strong grasp of the policy detail. For this reason the forecasting role of individual HM Treasury or HMRC officials is usually just a part of their mainly policy-focused work.

21.  The interconnectedness of policy and forecasting roles, together with the two sources of bias described above, dictate four broad models for the OBR according to the weight one places upon each of the trade-offs:

    1. The independence-light model. An independent but internal OBR, overseeing key discrete choices in the production of the forecast, which remains owned by HMT

    This "cheap and cheerful" option potentially safe-guards against the problem of top-down bias, although early question marks over the OBR's unemployment judgements means that the external perception of this cannot be assumed. The Treasury Select Committee's active engagement with the appointment of Budget Responsibility Committee (BRC) would also be necessary to ensure the external credibility of appointments, given the perceptions surrounding the Bank's Monetary Policy Committee appointment process.

    Further, this model does nothing to prevent bottom-up organisational bias from creeping into forecasts at a level of detail much below what the BRC would be able to detect. In its favour, this option would be cheap and involve no further institutional upheaval.

    2. The minimalist external model. An external OBR with a small staff, charged with overseeing the forecasting process, which remains owned by HMT

    An externally housed OBR, with the appropriate appointments process, would immunize the institution from any perception that it was there to disguise, rather than eliminate, top-down bias. However, with just a limited staff, the Office would suffer from huge information asymmetries with the officials who continue to produce the forecast from within HM Treasury. It is therefore unlikely that this model can do anything to resolve the bottom-up bias problem. Indeed, the problem may be exacerbated with the OBR no longer present within the Treasury building.

    3. The seasonal labour model. An external OBR with a small permanent staff, and HMT/HMRC experts seconded into the Office over the Budget and Pre-Budget Report period, while the forecast is done

    In order to protect against both forms of bias, it has therefore been suggested that policy officials might be temporarily seconded into the OBR, twice a year, to construct an OBR-owned forecast. However, this model entails serious practical problems.

    Those involved in the forecast have both a policymaking role, which must be Treasury based, and a forecasting role, which, on this model, must not be. The fact that those officials responsible for feeding into the forecast are simultaneously needed in HM Treasury for their policy expertise during the budget exercise makes this model problematic. HM Treasury would find it difficult to operate effectively at Budget time.

    4. The full independence model, An external OBR with a more substantial, dedicated staff charged with understanding policy in sufficient detail to develop the forecast from a low level

    The weaknesses of the above models imply that the OBR must be external, substantial and its workforce cannot be seasonal. The only effective and practical solution to the problems of eliminating bias from the fiscal projections is therefore to ensure that the OBR is sufficiently well resourced for its officials to:

    — take on the forecasting role of officials at an early stage in the process, thus owning the forecast and eliminating the potential for bias;

    — have responsibility for a sufficiently narrow range of policy, to enable them to get to grips with emerging policy issues and their likely impact on the forecast; and

    — be based outside the Treasury.

  22.  How many staff would be required to operate such a model is for others to determine. Nevertheless, it is clearly significantly more than the current secretariat of eight, while being many fewer than the hundreds of officials currently involved in the process in some way. Only with this level of resource can the OBR as an institution address the full range of reasons for the failure of the defunct fiscal framework.

  23.  These arrangements proposed by the SMF will not be without cost. However, the annual cost of the OBR must be set against the much longer-term and more substantial cost of poor fiscal policymaking.

CONCLUSION

  24.  The SMF argues that a greater level of institutional separation and independence for the OBR will be essential to its success as an independent fiscal council. This means that the OBR must:

    — be physically located outside the Treasury walls;

    — own the forecast process rather than sign it off;

    — have sufficient staff and expertise to be originate the forecast from a low base; and

    — have sufficient staff to understand the implications of policy at a detailed level.

ABOUT THE SMF

  25.  The Social Market Foundation (SMF) is a leading UK think tank, developing innovative ideas across a broad range of economic and social policy. It champions policy ideas which marry markets with social justice and takes a pro-market rather than free-market approach. Our work is characterised by the belief that governments have an important role to play in correcting market failures and setting the framework within which markets can operate in a way that benefits individuals and society as a whole.

26.  The SMF is politically independent, and works with all of the UK's main political parties. Our Board, Policy Advisory Board and staff reflect this. Our research work is undertaken by SMF staff; by our wide network of Associate Fellows and Advisory Board members, and by other experts in their field.

August 2010





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 21 September 2010