Office for Budget Responsibility - Treasury Contents


Written evidence submitted by Simon Hayes, Chief UK Economist, Barclays Capital

SUMMARY OF VIEWS

  1.  The OBR's core duties should be to provide an independent view of whether the government's public finance forecasts are "reasonable", and to provide an assessment of whether the prevailing fiscal stance is consistent with medium-term sustainability. If resources allow, the remit could be augmented with a requirement to promote best practice in fiscal policy.

2.  The OBR must "own" the macroeconomic forecasts, and must develop and maintain its own macroeconometric model. It is not necessary, however, for the OBR to replicate fully the Treasury's forecasting effort, although the OBR must have the expertise and access to information to scrutinise Treasury forecasts of tax and revenue streams.

3.  The OBR should not be involved in the specification of the government's fiscal mandate.

  4.  The OBR should have its own budget, and staff should report to, and be remunerated by, the OBR executive.

  5.  The co-existence of two "official" forecasts—the MPC's Inflation Report projections and the OBR's budget forecasts—seems likely to hinder the clarity with which macroeconomic policy is communicated to the public.

THE OBR'S REMIT

  6.  The OBR is potentially an extremely powerful innovation. Recently, an overseas client asked me whether the Budget forecast for the revenue gain from switching the indexation of some government expenditures to CPI from RPI was credible, or whether it might have been exaggerated. The answer was straightforward: the decision to make the switch was the government's, but the forecast for the gain was made by the OBR. The OBR's independence nipped any hint of impropriety in the bud.

7.  I believe the OBR should have two core duties:

    — To provide an independent view of whether the government's fiscal forecasts are "reasonable".

    — To provide an independent view of whether the prevailing fiscal stance is consistent with medium-term sustainability.

  8.  The purpose of these duties is to keep the government "honest" and "informed" and thereby to enhance public confidence in the management of the public finances.

  9.  Having the OBR produce the budget forecasts is an effective way of hard-wiring the first of these into the system, but it is not the only way. Fundamentally it is the OBR's sign-off, and the perceived independence of the sign-off, that are crucial, rather than the source of the forecasts. From this perspective I do not think it necessary for the OBR to replicate fully the forecasting effort of the Treasury. It makes sense for the OBR to "own" the macroeconomic forecast, but the detailed tax and revenue forecasts could be provided by the Treasury and other relevant government departments. The OBR must, however, have the ability (the expertise and the access to information) to scrutinise these forecasts.

  10.  There has been some debate about whether the OBR should comment on the fiscal "mandate"—which I take to mean the government's stated goals for the public finance dynamics. I see no reason why the OBR should be involved in the specification of the mandate. In fact, I think there may be a danger in the OBR becoming associated with any particular mandate: there should be no suggestion that the OBR has an incentive to produce forecasts that show that the mandate is likely to be supportive of growth, for example. Of course, the OBR will be commenting implicitly on the mandate through its growth forecasts and its sustainability assessment: this is, after all, its fundamental raison d'être.

  11.  The remit could be extended to give the OBR a more substantive role in framing the debate about the appropriate configuration of fiscal policy. For example, the OBR could be asked to assess the likelihood of meeting the mandate, or to produce analysis of fiscal "good practice" and fiscal "bad practice" against which existing or prospective government policies could be compared. The benefit of broadening the OBR's remit along these lines would be to help raise the quality of debate about the appropriate setting of fiscal policy. However, I would see this as a "nice-to-have" rather than a "must-have" feature of the set-up. So, for example, although the government of the day may wish for the OBR to provide an assessment of the likelihood of its mandate being met, as the current government did in June, I do not see this as a necessary OBR function and I would see no need to specify it as a core duty.

  12.  If the resources were available for "nice-to-haves" I would suggest giving the OBR an additional duty of promoting best practice in fiscal policy. The idea would be to improve the understanding, primarily among political leaders, of the economic efficiency arguments for and against certain tax and spending policies. The government, and opposition parties, might be encouraged to ask the OBR for independent assessments of prospective policies.

MEANS OF ASSURING INDEPENDENCE AND ACCOUNTABILITY

  13.  I have nothing to add to existing suggestions for the Budget Responsibility Committee (BRC): I think three people is the right size, that appointments should be made in a similar way to those of external MPC members and that the Treasury Select Committee should scrutinise the appointments.

14.  The OBR must have its own budget, preferably set in advance for a fixed period out of synch with the electoral cycle (eg a five-year budget set three years into each parliamentary term) or according to a pre-specified formula.

  15.  I think it is important that OBR staff report to, and are remunerated by, the BRC. Given the limited supply of relevant expertise it makes sense to allow staff to move between the OBR and the Treasury. This raises the concern that OBR staff might have an incentive to produce assessments that are viewed favourably by the Treasury in order to keep their career options open. I think this is a legitimate concern, but short of barring staff from crossing over I see no obvious solution. (A similar tension is likely to exist at the Bank of England, between the "internal" Monetary Analysis area and the MPC Unit, which services the external MPC members. It may be worth consulting with the Bank of England to gauge whether it is viewed as a material problem and whether there are measures that can be taken to minimise it.)

APPROPRIATE RESOURCES

  16.  Although it is difficult to take a strong view of the appropriate level of resourcing at this early stage, as a ball-park figure I would envisage the OBR as having a permanent staff of around eight analysts to cover the two core duties set out above. This is a little larger than the Bank of England's core forecast team, I believe, and certainly larger than the UK economics teams in the City, which typically comprise two to three analysts. The need for a larger forecast team at the OBR stems from the greater complexity needed to produce/scrutinise tax and revenue streams at a detailed level.

17.  If the OBR is to own the macroeconomic forecasts it needs to develop and maintain its own macroeconometric model. There is a set-up cost associated with this but it need not be an onerous one. Diminishing returns quickly set in with macroeconomic forecasting—the accuracy gains from increased sophistication are questionable beyond a basic level—and the Treasury model should provide a suitable baseline. In any case, I would imagine that the OBR's forecasts are unlikely to stray far from the consensus view: to a large extent it has been HM Treasury's propensity to publish macroeconomic forecasts that were some way different from the consensus that gave rise to concerns about the plausibility of budget projections in the first place. Indeed, I would think the OBR should maintain a constant (two-way) dialogue with other forecasters to gauge how its views are evolving relative to the consensus. It may also be beneficial in the medium term to encourage movement between the forecast teams at the OBR and the BoE.

  18.  I think that the OBR should be strongly encouraged to draw on outside academic expertise, engaging in joint research projects on ad hoc issues relating to macroeconomic forecasting and sustainability analysis.

A SINGLE "OFFICIAL" MACROECONOMIC FORECAST?

  19.  One broader concern I have is with the communication of macroeconomic policy when there are two "official" economic forecasts—the MPC's Inflation Report projections, which form the basis of monetary policy, and the OBR's budget forecasts, which underpin fiscal policy. If the two forecasts are materially different, it will be difficult for the authorities to argue that monetary and fiscal policy are appropriately co-ordinated. If they are engineered so as not to be materially different, it raises the question of why effort is being duplicated across two public institutions.

20.  It is easy to see circumstances in which the MPC and the OBR might produce materially different forecasts of the economy. For example, assessments of the level of the output gap, and the economy's "trend" rate of growth, are key inputs into both monetary policy and fiscal projections and yet there is no consensus in the economics profession about how to measure either. The OBR is currently assuming that trend growth is around 2-2.25% per annum: although the MPC tends to be reluctant to disclose its trend growth assumption, the indications are that its baseline assumption is that trend growth is faster than this—around 2.5%. If the MPC is right, the OBR is too pessimistic about the medium-term public finance outlook. If the OBR is right, the MPC is too optimistic about the inflation consequences of its growth projections. This is not a wholly satisfactory state of affairs.

  21.  Some would argue that this was not an issue in previous decades when policy was set with reference to different forecasts in different parts of government. However, forecasts have taken a much more central role in policymakers' communication efforts in recent years—in no small part because of the MPC's use of the Inflation Report projections as a communication device.

  22.  Note also that this is primarily a point about communication rather than about policy itself. Even within the MPC, members will have different views about the plausibility of the central Inflation Report projections and their policy votes will reflect their personal assessment of the outlook. This freedom lies at the heart of the principle that nine independent experts should, on average, make better judgments than a consensus view. However, the Inflation Report projections are used as way of communicating the MPC's "best collective judgment" to the public at large, and so it is perfectly reasonable for the public to ask how the MPC's assessment squares with that of the OBR and what the implications are of the forecasts being different.

  23.  At best, this introduces noise into the policy debate: at worst, differences in the assumptions underlying the forecasts make any claims of consistency or co-ordination implausible, and this could be harmful to the credibility of the overall framework. I think this concern argues for the OBR co-ordinating closely with the Bank of England to ensure a high degree of congruence between the forecasts—but it also raises the broader question of whether a single "official" projection is desirable for the purposes of communicating macroeconomic policy.

ABOUT THE CONTRIBUTOR

  24.  Simon Hayes is the Chief UK Economist at Barclays Capital, the investment banking arm of Barclays Bank. He is responsible for formulating the company's view on the outlook for the UK economy, including monetary and fiscal policy. Simon joined Barclays Capital in 2005 after eight years working at the Bank of England. Simon has a BA in Economics and a PhD from Newcastle University, and an MSc in Economics from Warwick University.

August 2010





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 21 September 2010