Written evidence submitted by Zacchaeus
Trust
With an explanation of the rise in cost housing benefit
to £21 billion year by Professor Peter Ambrose Visiting Professor
in Housing and Health at Brighton University.
HOUSING BENEFIT
REGULATIONSTHE
HB CAPS
1. We note
that the SSAC have been invited to submit its views to the Secretary
of State for Work and Pensions about The Housing Benefit Amendment
regulations (2010); Amendments to the Rent Officers (Housing Benefit
Functions Order). We are offering the same submission to
the Work and Pensions Committee that we have sent to the SSAC.
2. From April
2011:
- Local Housing Allowance levels will be restricted
to the 4 bedroom rate;
- A new upper limit will be introduced for each
property size, with upper limits set at:
- £250 a week for a 1 bedroom property
- £290 a week for a 2 bedroom property
- £340 a week for a 3 bedroom property
- £400 a week for a 4 bedroom property or
larger.
- The £15 weekly excess provision currently
payable within the Local Housing.
3. Allowance
rules will be removed. (As announced by the previous administration).
The size criteria will be adjusted to provide for an additional
bedroom for a non-resident carer where a disabled customer has
an established need for overnight care.
4. From October
2011: The Local Housing Allowance will be set at the 30th percentile
of rents in each Broad Rental Market Area, rather than the median.
The Committee is asked to consider the proposed amendments. An
explanatory memorandum is attached at Annex A. In addition,
we have appended a detailed impact analysis of these changes,
including at local level, to the memorandum
INTRODUCTION
5. The Zacchaeus
2000 Trust (Z2K) works with the most vulnerable citizens when
they have rent and council tax arrears, threats of eviction and
the bailiffs, or are struggling with overpayments of tax credits
and benefits. We only work "below the radar" while normally
passing mortgage and credit card debts to other advisers. We employ
three full time lawyers, an administrator and have 32 volunteers
who act as McKenzie Friends helping vulnerable debtors to engage
with the authorities delivering welfare and with the courts. At
any one time we are handling about 70 cases, Which are referred
to us by MPs, GPs in Tottenham, other NGOs and satisfied clients.
The trust was founded in the early 90s and registered as a charity
in 1997.
COMMENT
6. UK Governments'
have failed to take into account the consequential costs to the
tax payer in the hospitals, the schools and in the administration
of justice and in the economy at large of poverty related mental
and physical ill health, educational underachievement and crime.
Unless both the unemployed and the working poor receive the minimum
incomes needed for healthy living these costs will continue to
increase for the tax payers regardless of the system which delivers
welfare.
7. Limiting
the housing benefit will increase debt, and consequent mental
illness which is exacerbated when rent arrears, and other debts,
are enforced against poverty incomes. It is particularly important
to note the connection which has been made between debt and mental
illness.
8. The Government
Office for Science stated in its report "Mental Capital and
Wellbeing; Making the Most of ourselves in the 21st
century" Pollard 2008,
"There is a strong case for Government to work
with financial organisations and utility companies to break the
cycle between debt and mental illness. Recent research has indicated
that debt is a much stronger risk factor for mental disorder than
low income. A range of possible interventions are suggested: beginning
with better training for teenagers in managing finance; greater
awareness of the link between mental health and debt by banks
and financial institutions; and measures by utility companies
to handle arrears better."
9. We submit
that the combination of poverty level incomes and rent arrears
strengthens the risk factor for mental disorder and worsens the
cycle between debt and mental illness. Reducing such incomes with
rent arrears due to the caps on housing benefit piles risks on
risks. In our experience many claimants are already suffering
the draconian enforcement of rent and council tax arrears by the
local authorities and bailiffs and from consequent depression,
in some cases to the point of breakdown. This enlarges our concerns
about debt and mental illness in the UK of the Office for Science.
They continued;
"Common mental disorders affect 16% of the population
and are affected by a wide range of issues such as employment,
housing, urbanisation, exposure to crime, and debt. When policies
are developed in areas such as these, there is a clear case for
taking more account of the implications for mental health, as
is generally the case for physical health and safety."
RENT ENFORCED
AGAINST POVERTY
INCOMES
10. It is
also necessary to look at the arithmetic. The unemployment benefit
of a couple with two children is currently £235 a week after
100% Housing and Council Tax Benefits. It is that income which
will have to carry the increase in rent if families are moved.
It is already too low to provide healthy living under all available
measures. Enforcing rent arrears against these poverty incomes
as a result of the housing benefit cap will increase mental illness.
11. The relationship
between unemployment benefits and the government's 2020 child
poverty target was calculated by the House of Commons library
last year.
Table 1
SHORTFALL FROM 2020 TARGET
Unemployment benefits at APRIL 2009 and 60% median income.
|
£ per week |
ALL AHC
Over 18
£ per week
| AHC
Threshold | Benefits from April 2009 Actual
| Shortfall from target actual less threshold
| Shortfall from target £ per annum
| Benefits from April 2010 |
Childless couple | 199 | 100.95
| -98.05 | -5,099 | 102.75
|
Single individual | 116 |
64.30 | -51.70 | -2,688
| 65.45 |
Couple one child | 239 | 174.36
| -64.64 | -3,361 | 177.72
|
Couple two children | 323 |
230.47 | -92.53 | -4,812
| 235.29 |
Lone parent one child | 155 |
137.71 | -17.29 | -899
| 140.42 |
Lone parent two children | 239
| 193.82 | -45.18 | -2,349
| 197.99 |
Single adult 18-25 | 116 |
50.95 | -65.05 | -3,383
| 51.85 |
Source House of Commons Library and DWP.
12. Below we have selected items
from the Joseph Rowntree Foundation minimum income standards (MIS)
published in July at April 2010 prices which exclude rent, council
tax, child care and social and cultural participation. The food
budget is based in the science of nutrition, tested for consumer
acceptability with several focus group and priced in a supermarket.
All items in the budget are there because members of the public
think they ought to be in a minimum income standard.
Table 2
INCOMES FROM WHICH RENT ARREARS WILL BE ENFORCED
WHEN HB IS CAPPED
JSA | 235.29
|
Less MIS | |
Food | -107.13 |
Clothing | -29.58 |
Water | -5.70 |
Fuel | -20.09 |
Household goods | -18.96 |
Household services | -9.81 |
Personal goods and services | -29.20
|
Travel costs | -38.38 |
JSA Shortfall | -23.56
|
It should be noted that this family will not have a holiday, watch
live football matches, go on school trips; the costs of any kind
of social life are not included. Social participation is necessary
to health and well being. £104 a week is allowed for in the
JRF minimum income standards for social and cultural participation.
13. The family or individual
will certainly be paying off debts. Sometimes the level of debts
is so bad due to the complexities of welfare delivery that people
are literally unable to buy food. Z2K has a small fund to provide
them with temporary support beyond the scope of statutory welfare.
Food prices are increasing while benefits are being cut. Unaffordable
housing is already worsening poverty.
14. A socially
meaningful definition of the word "affordable" is a
prerequisite to responsible discussion of the issue. Currently
the adjective "affordable" is used with no evidence
base and simply to mean "below market prices and rents".
A debate conducted on this premise is meaningless. A rigorous
test of affordability was developed in 2008 by Professor Ambrose
using an adaptation of the MIS methodology developed by JRF. This
method operationalises the definition of affordable in the 2005
Z2K Memorandum to the Prime Minister on Unaffordable Housing.
15. In brief, this definition specifies that
housing is affordable if it can be afforded once all other
household expenditures required to live a safe, healthy and participative
life have been met. For a specified household living in a
specified area of east London this figure was calculated at £135
per week in 2008. This means that "social rented housing",
whether LA or RSL, was locally affordable to this household but
not any housing in the private rented or LCHO sectors. The affordable
figure can be calculated for any household type and for any local
area".
16. It should also be noted that the unemployment
benefits for single women under 25 years old is £51.85 a
week and £65.45 thereafter up to aged 60; it is slightly
less per head when paid to couples. The Joseph Rowntree MIS food
standard for single adults is £44.24 a week. It is therefore
impossible for an unemployed woman to buy a healthy diet and other
necessities before or during pregnancy; again this serious consequence
of poverty is exacerbated by debt and rent arrears.
Table 3
INCOMES FROM WHICH RENT ARREARS WILL BE ENFORCED
WHEN HB IS CAPPED
Working aged adult.
| £pw | £pw
|
Food | 44.34 |
|
Clothing | 7.73 |
|
Water | 4.93 |
|
Fuel | 9.78 |
|
Household Goods | 10.35 |
|
Personal Goods and Services | 8.95
| |
Travel costs | 19.78 |
|
Total | 105.86
| |
JSA under 25 | -51.85
| 54.01 |
JSA 25 to 60 | -65.45
| 40.41 |
In this case £42 is allowed for social and cultural participation
which is all too obviously impossible for unemployed adults. This
income also applies up to the age of 60 to single men and women,
widows and widowers, whose children have left home. This group
of people, when in expensive housing through no fault of their
own, will be most unjustly affected by the housing benefit cap
after their children have left home. The two following cases illustrates
the existing debts, and their consequences for vulnerable adults,
who will find it very difficult to hold down a job
CASE A
17. Local Government Ombudsman
reports the case of Mr "Watson", a single, semi literate
adult living alone in Southwark. Jobcentre Plus mistakenly cancelled
his JSA so Southwark cancelled his housing and council tax benefits
creating arrears in both accounts. On the 12 January 2001 CSL,
Southwark's out sourced agent collecting council tax, sends Mr.
Watson a summons for unpaid council tax of £235.10, plus
costs, for a hearing on 9 February 2001. The summons contains
the following threats, in bold type and highlighted. Thousands
are dispatched daily:
"If a liability order is granted the council
will be able to take one or more of the following actions:
Instruct bailiffs to take your goods to settle your
debt - this can include your car.
You will be liable to pay the bailiffs costs which
could substantially increase the debt. Instruct your employer
to deduct payments from your salary or wages.
Deduct money straight from your jobseekers allowance
or income support.
Make you bankrupt.
Make a charging order against your home. Have you
committed to prison".
His sister-in-law calls on him. His body is hanging
in his flat. The police found the summons with him, paper littered
with rough calculations and a note:
"Dear
. I at to do this I am in so much
in Detr good By for ever Love
"
Threats of eviction for rent arrears were not far
off. JSA was £53.05 a week after rent and council tax. (Now
£64.30). The Joseph Rowntree Foundation minimum income standard
for healthy living, after rent an council tax, is £144 a
week for a single adult.
CASE B
18. We work
with ATD Fourth World who are close to the poorest people in London.
They asked for our help with "Sarah" a 51 year old who
is single, unemployed, semi literate and in debt to Lambeth Council.
Her Doctor tells us
"she has learning difficulties and is illiterate
and for many years has had chronic anxiety with episodes of panic.
Were the Bailiffs to proceed with the seizure of her goods, the
effect would be catastrophic for her and would seriously compromise
her health".
She receives £53.05 a week income. She pays
each week a £4.13 a week water rate, £2.50 rent arrears
£36.42 to buy every thing but rent and council tax. Capita
Business Services in Bromley collect council tax for the Council..
She owes £468 from a failed attempt at low paid work. The
failure caused the debt. Equita Bailiffs in Northampton whose
computers, blind to her ill health, illiteracy and poverty, threaten
"We have arranged for our bailiff to call at
your home this weekend to seize your goods and transport them
to the auction rooms for sale", and two days later "NOTICE
PRIOR TO COMMITTAL TO PRISON PROCEEDINGS".
We tell Lambeth Council who call off the bailiffs.
The computer still runs. Another threat to sell the furniture
storms its way from Northampton to Lambeth. To relieve her anxiety
Zacchaeus promises to pay the £468 council tax arrears should
the magistrates be minded to imprison her rather than write off
the debt. We also promise to go to court with her. Lambeth backed
off.
19. The housing
benefit caps will result in rent being paid out of poverty income,
both in and out of work, which cannot be reduced without further
damaging the health and wellbeing of tenants and their children.
Rent arrears and evictions, and the depression that goes with
them, are inevitable.
20. Parents
are left alone in a council house or RSL after children have left
home. Some have been housed in expensive private rented accommodation
at the market price because there was nothing cheaper and the
local authority has a duty to house them when they had children.
Secure tenure is necessary to promote educational progress and
good behaviour in schools, local extended families are essential
for mutual support. That will be broken by forcing parents and
grandparents out of their homes. This will erupt as a scandal
into national media when repossession notices are issued and bailiffs
begin to implement evictions.
LARGE FAMILIES
21. Housing
for large families is in even shorter supply than housing in general.
Z2K serves a lone mother with eight children. The nine o them
live in an overcrowded council house. The local authority will
not move them or build on to the current three bed-roomed house.
Their education and their health is suffering. The only accommodation
available would be private at rents over £400 a week; rent
which will exclude the family from approprtate housing Professor
Peter Ambrose, an housing adviser to Z2K, has comments as follows.
"Home overcrowding is producing ever-increasing
costs in terms of calls on the NHS, Social Services, the education
and law and order systems and in human misery. Shelter data show
that overcrowding has got significantly worse over the past five
years and it continues to worsen as the shortage of genuinely
affordable rented homes gets more acute. The 2009 London Citizens
report "Housing our Future" by Ambrose and Farrell
uncovered the extent of over-crowding among a sample of primary
school children at four schools in Wandsworth and by means of
surveys and other enquiries assessed the adverse effects on the
children. These effects were judged by over 60% of the parents
to be harming their children's educational and social progress
in six different ways. Both teachers and parents also commented
on some adverse behavioural outcomes. Under-investment in housing
is producing some very regressive effects and adding seriously
to a range of public sector costs."
DECADES OF
FAILURE IN
HOUSING AND
LAND MANAGEMENT
POLICY
Professor Peter Ambrose
Visiting Professor in Housing and Health at Brighton University
22. We need
to understand how this huge call on the HB budget (£21 billion
per year) arose. It arose because of the failures in financial
management over the period 1980-2005. The financial deregulations
of the early 1980s allowed house purchase lending to spiral out
of control thus driving house prices to unprecedented levels and
with them rents which by various mechanisms reflect house
price movements.
23. A widow who has lived in her two-bedroom council
flat in west London for 22 years has received a phone call from
Kensington and Chelsea council warning her about her "under-occupancy".
Her misdemeanour is that she has a spare bedroom so that
her grandchildren can visit like the vast majority of
people in this country. Now she is understandably worried, fears
for her future and cannot sleep.
24. Most
owner-occupiers probably have at least one spare room for visiting
friends and family; they would not take kindly to being warned
as to their occupancy behaviour. This difference in value judgement
reflects the popular fiction that somehow tenants in "social
housing" (whether local authority or RSLs) are "subsidised",
and therefore can reasonably be pushed around, whereas owner-occupiers
have "stood on their own two feet", got themselves
properly indebted and consequently live independently of
public support.
25. This
picture is 100% wrong on several counts. Since the 1920s purchasing
owner-occupiers have been massively subsidised by exemption from
capital gains tax, Schedule A Tax and, until very recently, by
mortgage interest tax relief. In fact each owner-occupier was
receiving about twice the state subsidy per household compared
to households in the public rented sector throughout the period up
to about 2000, when most current owner-occupiers were in the buying
stage, Moreover, depending on when they enter and exit the market,
purchasers stand to make capital gains that at times far exceed
the income from their actual work. This route to wealth, at least
on paper, is denied to those not in a position to buy - ie those
in the poorest third of households. How much more regressive could
the system be?
26. In recent
years changes in public sector housing finance have meant that
a reverse subsidy is at work. Much more than £1 billion has
been abstracted annually from the council housing sector accounts
as rent policy has shifted from the former "pooled historic
cost" principle that delivered low rents with minimal subsidy
to a formula that feeds local private house values into public
rent levels. This is another effective way to penalise lower income
households living in high housing value areas - and to subsidise
the rest of society from the rents of the poorest third.
27. Had house
prices risen with general inflation since 1980 the average house
price now would be about £60,000, clearly much more in line
with incomes. How do house prices rise much faster than other
economic indicators (give or take the periodic downturns)? Loosening
the regulation of lending in the 1980s resulted in money flooding
into a housing market in short supply so forcing up prices. The
lending institutions initiate periodic bouts of excessive
and highly profitable lending from which, if it all goes
wrong, they can be sure of massive public funding bail outs.
These bail outs, the cost of the latest one was estimated at £750
billion, have inevitable impacts on every public spending programme
that most helps the vulnerable. So home owners' increased paper
wealth comes at the expense of increased stress, hardship and
health risk among those who can never aspire to play the home
ownership game. We see it all around us. Everywhere one looks
there are regressive effects.
28. Irresponsible
ending policies have forced up prices in the housing market in
short supply, while linking council and RSL rents to the housing
market forced up rents. This had led directly to the rising housing
benefit bill for the tax payer and more difficulty in transferring
into work for the benefit recipient.
29. Underlying much of the problem of low housing
output, and a worsening shortage of genuinely affordable homes,
is the chronic problem of the mismanagement of land policy in
relation to development land. Periodic instability and sharp credit-led
upward movements in house prices produce similar movements in
the price of development land; its value is determined by expectations
about sales revenue for houses built upon it by means of the "residual"
calculation.
30. Under arrangements in place since the 1947 Town
and Country Planning Act development land has thus been a speculative
commodity. Its value has often been massively increased by publicly-funded
infrastructure such as new motorways and mass transit lines, and
by the granting of development consents, and very little of this
"betterment" gain has been recouped in taxation for
the public purse. Typically large financial institutions with
long investment horizons, and/or major house builders, buy up
land at agricultural values even before it is zoned for development.
They then hold it to await the right time to develop, or perhaps
trade in it before development takes place. This means that in
some states of the development cycle house builders make more
profit from land speculation than from producing housing and this
helps to explain the lack of innovation and the outdated management
practices of the UK house building industry (compared to, for
example, those in Japan or Sweden).
31. The 1947 planning system has the inherent defect
that it seeks to "plan" development by the largely negative
mechanism of giving or withholding of planning consents. It has
very little power to mobilise the resources of land and investment
that actually need to be applied to produce new housing of a given
mix in a given period. In the past some positive powers have been
applied in the form of council house building programmes. But
there has been minimal funding for such programmes for many years.
A large-scale programme of publicly funded house building is now
urgently needed.
32. The model of relying on planning gain agreements
to provide "affordable" housing as a concomitant to
private housing developments has two fatal flaws. In periods of
market downturn and low confidence there is very little private
building anyway and even if the intended "affordable"
component is high it amounts to little in practice. 50% of very
little is very little.
33. The other fatal defect is that there is no meaningful
definition of the word "affordable". It was shown in
2008 that, using a variant of the Minimum Income Standard methodology,
it is possible to determine what price or rent is truly affordable
to households of any given type in any location. But this evidence
base is not used and "affordable" is taken to mean anything
less than market price or rent. This frequently leads to so-called
"affordable" housing being available at prices and rents
that only the rich locally can afford.
34. A comparative study in the late 1980s of housing
provision in "growth regions" in France (The Toulouse
area), Sweden (the E4 Corridor) and the UK (Berkshire) showed
that the Swedish system of land management, which effectively
precluded land speculation, performed better in terms of matching
housing output to employment growth than was the case in Berkshire.
In the E4 Corridor more housing was produced, at a greater range
of rents and prices to meet all incomes and with minimal effect
on development land values. The effects in Berkshire were totally
different. The output was lower, about 88% of it was speculative
for home ownership, thus narrowing choice, and both land and house
prices escalated. In other words the housing infrastructure to
support the growth of the local economy was much better managed
in the Swedish than in the UK case.
35. There are a number of policy steps that could
be taken to correct this long-term defect in the land supply system.
At a small scale much more development could take place using
some variant of the Community Land Trust (CLT) model which uses
for housing development land that has been cheaply or freely provided
from some source, is held freehold in some public or community
ownership and upon which housing for rent and sale is built on
a leasehold basis. The effect here is to remove the land from
the private market in perpetuity and to ensure that rises in value,
and future redevelopment rights, remain in public or community
ownership.
36. Since it would take some time and serious state
investment to develop the CLT model on a large scale some fiscal
steps to preclude or reduce land speculation are possible. One
would take the form of an annual tax levied at a very low rate
(maybe 5% or less) on the value of land zoned for development
but not yet built on. This would act as a strong disincentive
to potential development land being held for speculative rather
than development purposes.
CONCLUSION
37. Ironically a reduction in spend on housing benefit
and other demand side subsidies to housing would make perfect
sense as part of a long term programme to re-balance the supply/demand
ratio of support to nearer the 80:20 it was in the early 1980s
(the ratio is now the reverse). Demand side support works to bid
up prices and rents and landlords' profits supply side
subsidy in the form of cheaper land or finance, or similar incentives,
directly stimulates housing output and produces jobs in the construction
sector. The increase in supply would gradually reduce demand pressures,
dampen down prices and rents and reduce the call on housing benefit.
But this transition must not be achieved at the cost of placing
new burdens on the poor and vulnerable.
38. Capping the housing benefit before taking
steps to reduce prices and rents in relation to incomes, and to
stimulate the output of affordable housing, is the most recent
of decades of governmental decisions which have failed to provide
fair and affordable housing or to make the most cost-effective
use of scarce public resources. This is in no way the fault of
people who have been housed by local authorities in expensive
rented accommodation. Their incomes and their health should not
have to carry the burden of these policy errors by being forced
to pay off rent arrears against poverty incomes, and their lives
should not be disrupted by evictions which separate them from
their families or uproot them from their communities. This social
destruction contained in the budget is based on the false premise
that tenants in 'social housing' (whether local authority or RSLs)
are subsidised by the tax payer unfairly when it is the owner
occupiers who have received the greatest share of housing subsidies.
|