Football Governance - Culture, Media and Sport Committee Contents


Written evidence submitted by Mark Usher

SUMMARY

This submission has been provided by the author Mark Usher in a personal capacity. Mr. Usher is a lifetime supporter of Watford Football Club in addition to being an enthusiastic follower of the England National Football Team. As a result, part of this response can certainly be viewed from the perspective of a fan and a football community member at the club and country level. Mr. Usher has also been a consultant to private and public sector organizations for over fifteen years and, consequently, this response has also been written from the perspective of an individual whose professional responsibilities have focused on guiding organizations through transformative change.

The submission to the Select Committee's Inquiry into Football Governance has been provided in the form of answers to the following six questions posed by the Committee in its Call for Evidence:

—  Should football clubs in the UK be treated differently from other commercial organisations?

—  Are football governance rules in England and Wales, and the governing bodies which set and apply them, fit for purpose?

—  Is there too much debt in the professional game?

—  What are the pros and cons of the Supporter Trust share-holding model?

—  Is Government intervention justified and, if so, what form should it take?

—  Are there lessons to be learned from football governance models across the UK and abroad, and from governance models in other sports?

The first four of the above questions are answered by the responses in Paragraphs 1-4 below. The last two questions are answered in a combined form by the response in Paragraph 5 below.

1.  Should football clubs should be treated differently from other commercial organisations?

Numerous articles and reports have discussed the transition of football clubs from purely sporting and socially focused organizations within specific geographic communities to, in the cases of some top-flight clubs, commercial enterprises with global reach. One of the common themes—one with which I agree—is that the pendulum in English football has swung far too much towards commercial objectives as opposed to the social, cultural and sporting objectives that originally defined the very reason for existence of the first football clubs. Fans are now customers, clubs are now enterprises, and football is in the entertainment industry.

In the late nineteenth century when the Football Association saw commercialism rearing its head in the game it allowed all clubs in the Football League to form private limited companies but restricted the profits that could be distributed back to shareholders to a maximum of 5% of the value of shares held. This and an accompanying regulation that disallowed payments of salaries to directors formed the FA's Rule 34. The intent of Rule 34 was to enable football clubs to operate basically as non-profit businesses that served the ongoing social and cultural needs of their communities while delivering a fair but conservative rate of return back to their owners. The FA correctly believed that because football clubs were serving an important community purpose it was necessary to implement safety measures that ensured the majority of any profits generated were reinvested in the club and did not simply line the pockets of profiteering entrepreneurs. The very presence of these safety measures also meant that, generally, only true "football-loving" people would be interested in owning a football club during these early days.

In addition to Rule 34 the FA, in collaboration with the Football League, also implemented two other measures during this period that kept football in balance. The first of these was the maximum wage for players, set to prevent the escalation of costs that might occur if clubs had to increase their players' wages to prevent them being enticed away by competitors offering them more money. The second was revenue redistribution. This required that match day gate receipts—the only source of revenue for clubs at that time—be shared between the competing teams and that an additional percentage of the total receipts go into a pot for redistribution among all Football League clubs. The objective of revenue redistribution was to prevent smaller clubs being at a disadvantage to those clubs from larger towns and cities who could draw upon larger fan bases.

From the turn of the twentieth century to the early 1980s, Rule 34 and revenue redistribution succeeded in preventing over-commercialism and profiteering within football. Throughout this period the social and cultural needs of communities and fans were successfully and affordably met by their local football clubs. Even when the maximum wage was (rightly) abolished in 1961 there followed a further 20 year period when the big clubs were still able to pay the higher wages that many of their top players demanded without drowning in red ink and the small clubs were still able to match their cost structures to their revenue bases. And every now and then one of the smaller clubs would manage its limited resources particularly well and rise through the divisions to become, well, a big club. This was important since it demonstrated that enough of a level playing field existed to allow the smaller club lacking the revenue generation power of its larger neighbor to still harbor hope of achieving parity in sporting terms. It should also be noted that it was during the sixties that the additional revenue stream of TV licensing rights became available to clubs. These early TV rights deals were negotiated by the Football League and, regardless of which team's match highlights were shown, the revenue from these deals was distributed equally among all 92 clubs.

If this story ended at 1980 then one would have to say that the FA and the Football League had successfully established a model that proved football clubs could be run as financially healthy commercial organizations that put the social, cultural and sporting needs of their communities first. In other words for almost 100 years football clubs were indeed treated differently from other commercial organizations and it worked. So what went wrong? Well, two things basically—greed and weakness. Greed on behalf of a number of the larger clubs who, in response to massive TV deals that were on the table, decided to break away from the Football League and its revenue redistribution policy and keep all the TV money to themselves. And weakness on behalf of the FA who allowed this breakaway to happen. Prior to the breakaway which ultimately led to the formation of the Premier League the FA had also shown weakness some years earlier in 1983 when they allowed clubs to circumvent Rule 34 by forming holding companies, a loophole that enabled clubs to siphon off unlimited profits in excess of the FA's limit on shareholder distributions. This earlier lapse in the FA's resolve to protect the sporting and cultural integrity of English football proved to be the first breach in the dam that eventually led to the mutiny of the big clubs and hyper-commercialism of the game.

Returning to today, the fact that the Premier League places its emphasis squarely on commercial rather than social and community objectives does NOT prove the rule as some might think that football clubs can indeed be treated like any other commercial organization. On the contrary, the Premier League proves that the 100% commercially focused football club is NOT a financially sustainable model due to the nature of its ever escalating cost structure driven by player wages, the high risk associated with an over-dependence on a single source of revenue (TV deal money), and the commonplace practice of football club owners using leveraged debit to finance the acquisition of clubs. The Premier League has comprehensively validated the fact that football clubs MUST be treated differently than other commercial organizations not just to protect the social and cultural heritage of our game but also to put in place the safeguards needed to protect clubs from the potentially suicidal financial strategies of their owners.

2.  Are football governance rules and the governing bodies which set and apply them fit for purpose?

2.1  Reason 1: The vision and mission for the governance of English football are at best unclear and at worst completely undefined

The "Who We Are" and "What We Do" pages of the FA's web site read like a laundry list of roles and responsibilities and give no indication of the FA's most important and urgent priorities. The closest to a vision statement that can be found on the FA site is "we are committed to making football accessible, enjoyable and safe for everyone, regardless of race, religion, gender, sexuality, background or ability". This is a commendable goal but surely represents only one dimension of the FA's reason for existence. It is also stated that the FA is responsible for "developing and regulating the game at all levels...". Again this is clear in meaning but does not define specific objectives or depict any ideal end state against which the FA's efforts can be evaluated.

So how do we know if the FA's litany of responsibilities listed on their web site are the right ones? Which are most important? Which are a waste of time? We don't know unless a powerfully incisive vision has first been created that describes in crystal clear terms the "perfect result" we are aiming for in English football, eg a professional game refocused on social and cultural objectives as opposed to purely commercial goals, a resurgent national football team, and integration of football into a broad spectrum of community development activities and programs. Once this vision has been developed only then can the primary purpose and reason for existence of the governing body—its mission statement—actually be defined. In the case of the FA a mission flowing from a vision as described above could potentially revolve around a need to manage with a firmer regulatory hand the over-commercialism of the game, to place increased focus on youth development, and to increase the degree to which clubs actively work to develop and improve the communities of which they are part.

So how does the FA go about developing the "correct" vision for English football upon which to base its mission and ultimately its key roles and responsibilities? Well, I would argue that the most compelling and relevant vision for English football will result by polling the opinion of that constituency for whom the first football clubs were originally created—the community. By engaging with community stakeholders at the club level (those with a vested interest in how policy decisions will impact their local team), at the national level (those with a stake in how the England National Team will be affected) and the broader community level (social, cultural, infrastructure, health and education for example) the governing body will ensure it is structuring a vision, mission and related set of roles and responsibilities that genuinely reflect the needs and wants of those people for whom the game of football was by definition created.

If a compelling and relevant vision is developed from the ground up for English football then we are certainly on the right path to creating a governance model capable of bringing the commercial and community aspects of the game back into balance. This on its own its own will not be enough however. To successfully evolve even the most powerfully motivational vision into reality we must also grapple with the fundamental structures and relationships of the bodies that govern football in this country. This will be the subject of tomorrow's post.

2.2  Reason 2: Effective leadership and governance of English football is impossible with the current structure and make-up of the FA Board of Directors

Let us assume for one moment that the FA has taken the advice in my previous post and reached out to a broad spectrum of community stakeholders to develop a vision for English football and a corresponding mission and set of responsibilities for itself in implementing this vision. Let us also assume that that the community-centric approach has resulted in a vision and mission that are elegantly "balanced" along the dimensions of commercialism, social objectives, and community values. As a last suspension of disbelief let us imagine that the FA management team develop a set of policies and regulations based on this mission that if implemented would result in a near-seismic shift in the landscape of football in this country. Examples could include re-instituting revenue redistribution (eg sharing EPL TV money among all Football League clubs), repealing the holding company loophole that sidestepped the FA's Rule 34, or restricting foreign ownership of English clubs to below 50%. These are particularly draconian examples (certainly from the view of the EPL) but they are just to illustrate a point.

With the current FA governance structure such a set of policies and regulations would be dead on arrival in the FA boardroom. Why? Because half of the current FA board of directors responsible for approving policy represent either EPL or the Football League (the other half are from the FA). Clearly any new proposed policies or regulations that are not in the interest of the EPL or Football League will never be implemented (typically these would be any proposals that attempt to reign in commercialism and revenue generation), just as any proposals not in the FA's interest would be blocked by the FA's own board members. So in fact the current FA governance model is permanently gridlocked with the professional league representatives and the FA representatives each protecting their turf. The current situation is complicated further by the absence of an FA Chief Executive (equivalent to a corporation's CEO) since Ian Watmore left last year. Theoretically a strong FA Chief Executive could lend some additional weight behind FA-recommended policies that might not be palatable to the professional game representatives.

One commonly proposed solution to the gridlock of the FA board is to introduce independent directors who are not affiliated with the FA or either of the professional leagues. The idea is that the independent directors provide a balanced view free of conflict of interest while the non-independents directors provide the necessary input (but not steamrollering input) from parties with a stake in the outcome. The new recently elected FA Chairman David Bernstein is "quasi-independent" in my view. Formerly Chairman of Wembley Stadium, an FA subsidiary, Bernstein was actually proposed to the board by Phil Gartside, one of the Premier League representatives on the FA board. You figure that one out. If you believe that Chairman-Elect Bernstein is genuinely independent (which I don't) even then we have a ratio of only one independent board member to eleven non-independent board members. Such a board structure would make it nigh impossible for any truly transformative policies and regulations to see the light of day since by definition transformative policies have a habit of upsetting at least one stakeholder group. So, until such a time that we have more independence on the FA board it's going to be very tough to "rebuild the English game from the ground up".

What to do then? Well, if we accept the premise that the ultimate stakeholder for both the FA and the professional leagues should be communities then the structure and make-up of the FA board should be such that there must never arise a situation where policy proposals with a community benefit are automatically shot down arbitrarily by a negatively impacted party. To guard against this eventuality there must enough independent representation on the board to allow proposals to be evaluated impartially without conflicts of interest perpetually leading to gridlock. To avoid the possibility of "across the aisle" secret deals between non-independent board members from the FA and the professional leagues this means that the total number of independent directors on the board must exceed the total number of non-independent board members by at least one. This goes further than the Burns report which, although recommending an increase in the number of independent board members relative to the board make-up today, allowed the total number of non-independent board members (including executive directors) to outnumber the number of independent directors. This still leaves open the possibility of secret deals and the shutting off of any new strategies or policies that work against the interest of FA and/or professional league stakeholders.

So, there we have it. It's a lot easier said than done but nevertheless the task is clear if the organization responsible for governing English football is to lead us all towards a new dawn. If we are to kill gridlock and neutralize conflict of interest.

We need our own Independence Day.

2.3  Reason 3: Those responsible for football governance today at the club, league and FA levels regularly act in their own interests and not in the interest of the broader stakeholder community

At the heart of my third reason why the governing bodies of football in this country are not fit for purpose is the Principal-Agent Problem. The Principal-Agent problem refers to when a Principal delegates authority to an Agent to carry out a task in the Principal's interest but the Agent decides instead to use its assigned authority to act in its own interest. A common example in the business world occurs when shareholders hire a board of directors to govern their business and the board of directors, once installed, pursues policy that works counter to the objectives of the shareholders rather than for them. Reasons why Agents will act in their own interest include a lack of transparency into the Agent's actions, misaligned incentives between the Principal and the Agent, the absence of any perceived threat of punitive action being taken against the Agent by the Principal, and in some cases a genuine de facto power through the board themselves owning the majority of the shares. Among the strategies that some shareholder groups will take to avoid the Principal-Agent problem are mandatory reporting requirements, performance incentives to encourage board members to act in shareholders' interests, and a clearly communicated threat to remove board members whose actions work counter to shareholder objectives.

In the world of football governance the Principal-Agent problem is observable at the club and governing body level. At the football club level the fan community is analogous to the shareholder community in the business example in that the community acts as a Principal who has assigned authority to an Agent (the club owner or major shareholders) to operate the football club in its best interests. Whether the club's fans are actually shareholders of the club or not (some may be) is irrelevant. Each fan is a stakeholder in the club through his or her emotional and financial investment and as such those responsible for governing the club should be answerable to them. Can a Principal-Agent problem arise in this situation? Sure it can! Take the very recent example of Tottenham Hotspur. The major shareholder of Spurs is an investment company ENIC International. ENIC wants to move the club from its North London home to the Olympic Stadium in the East End after the completion of the 2012 Games. Not surprisingly a significant majority of the Spurs fan community want the club to stay put at White Hart Lane. Even though the fans are the Principal in this case, they are unfortunately at the whim of the Agent (ENIC) when it comes to deciding the future of the club. Unfortunately there are far too many other Agent-wagging-the-Principal stories like Spurs around today and not just in the top flight. In the House of Commons Debate on Football Governance on 16 December 2010, Labor MP John Mann described brilliantly the case of Worksop Town and Mansfield Town playing their FA Trophy tie on the ground of a recently liquidated neighboring club because both clubs' owners had locked them out of their grounds.

A desire to wrest back some control from owners has led supporters of some clubs to form supporter's trusts, not-for-profit organizations of fans who raise financing to secure significant share ownership and potentially seats on club boards. Today over half of Premier League and Football League clubs have supporters trusts although for only a small number of these clubs does the trust have a meaningful influence over club governance. Most of the latter situations are for smaller clubs where supporters stepped in to save the club from bankruptcy (or resurrected the club altogether after bankruptcy had already happened). Where successes have occurred the achievements of those supporters involved must certainly be applauded. For example, the supporters' trusts at Brentford and Exeter City both have outright ownership of their clubs. For the larger Premier League and Championship clubs, however, it is much more difficult for a supporters' trust to attain significant influence over owners and boards. When we look broadly across the game the truth is that unless a completely new club governance model can be found that facilitates genuine community influence over major policy decisions effecting the club then there will be little hope of achieving balance between commercial and social considerations.

The Principal-Agent concept can be applied just as relevantly at the governing body level. Surely it cannot be a stretch to say that the FA together with the Football league and the Premier League exist to develop and implement a policy for football in this country that serves the interests of all of those communities having a stake in the game? Whether the community in question is Manchester, Scunthorpe, Worksop Town, or the England National side? Or women's football? Or the disabled? Or inner city kids? Is it not the case then that we—all we communities—have in effect hired the management teams of these three organizations to work together in support of our individual and collective objectives related to the game? We are again a Principal, this time assigning responsibility to an Agent in the form of the FA and the two professional leagues, effectively the FA Board from a decision-making point of view (since the FA Board is made up of representatives from all three organizations). To act in our interest this particular Agent needs to accomplish a greater number of things across a far broader spectrum than in the previous case where the individual football club was the Agent. In the case of the FA Board we as a collective community will require more rigorous due diligence of potential buyers of clubs, control over rising ticket prices, bringing financial stability back to football, improving consistency of refereeing decisions, improving supporter representation, and building an England national side capable of winning a World Cup.

It is as clear as day that just as a Principal-Agent problem exists at the club level it is also present with the governing bodies of English football. Why? Well, for many of the same reasons as we see everywhere else. In the case of the professional leagues—particularly the Premier League—it is about misaligned incentives. The game is TOO successful right now from a financial point of view for the leagues to take a breath and worry about, oh, those social and cultural objectives. And the England team? Just an annoying distraction. With the FA it's about an absence of any perceived threat of action. A complete lack of accountability. The public and the government may moan and groan about us but it's just sticks and stones, see. My bones are fine.

In my remaining responses to the Select Committee questions over the next few days I will begin to frame a solution for tackling the Principal-Agent problem in football. For rooting out the misaligned incentives and hammering them back into alignment again. For instilling some long-needed accountability into a performance-free zone. For giving us a voice again. The solution I'm talking about won't be popular with everyone, but then being popular is not the point. Bringing football back to us is the point. Bringing it back to our communities. Where it belongs.

3.  Is There Too Much Debt in the Professional Game?

Back in the seventies my father operated a very successful bakery shop in St. Albans, just outside of London. One day he decided he wanted to expand the business and buy a second shop in Harpenden, about five miles away. My father went down to the High Street to see his bank manager about getting a loan for the second shop. Before the bank manager would give my father, or tell him how much of a loan he could have, he wanted the answers to the following four questions:

1.  What is the operating profit of your business today?

2.  What interest payments are you making on debt do you already have, if any?

3.  What additional sales will the second shop bring in?

4.  What additional operating expenses will the second shop incur?

The bank manager asked the above questions because he wanted to assess whether my father would be able to cover the loan payments with the operating profits from the business. The first question about the profitability of the business today was to see whether my father was capable of running a fundamentally sound operation that made money in the first place. The second question was intended to reveal how much of his profits were already allocated to servicing existing debt and the third and the fourth questions were to confirm that the second shop—the new asset that would be financed by the loan—would generate positive incremental profits that, together with the profits my father's original shop, would successfully service the loan charges. With the answers my father provided the bank manager determined that the total profits from the two shops would indeed cover the loan charges and my father got his loan.

How does the above story help us answer whether there is too much debt in football? Well, it doesn't so much answer the question as tell us that we are asking the wrong question. The right question should be is the debt in football good debt or bad debt? To know this we need to ask the following:

1.  Are English football clubs running fundamentally sound businesses today that are generating sufficient cash from operations to service the debt they have today?

     Any debt for which the interest payments cannot be covered by profits from current operations is bad debt. For example, if a club has £100 million in total debt and £50 million of it cannot be serviced from operations then the £50 million is bad debt.

2.  Are English football clubs that take on additional debt doing it for the right reasons?

     Any debt that is taken on to pay expenses as opposed to investment in assets is also bad debt. For example if a club invests £10 million in stadium improvements and another £15 million in player's wages then the £10 million is good debt whereas the £15 million is bad debt.

Notice by the way that it is possible for debt to be covered by cash from operations (which would seem to make it good debt) but that if is it subsequently used to pay expenses it is still bad debt.

Now let's look at Premier League and Football League clubs and determine whether, on average, their debt is good and bad. The numbers below are approximate only and are based on financial data presented in the highlights of Deloitte's Annual Review of Football Finance 2010 (for the 2008-09 season).

Premier League Clubs

Total Revenue £1.981 billion.

Total expenses £1.902 billion (£1.327 billion wage costs + £582 million non-wage costs).

Operating profit £79 million.

Interest charges £184 million.

Debt Liability £3.3 billion of which about £1.4 billion is "soft" interest-free debt from owners.

 

Football League Clubs

Total Revenue £550 million.

Total expenses £625 million (£475 million wage costs + £150 million non-wage costs).

Operating loss £75 million.

Interest charges Over £50 million.

Debt liability Over £500 million

From the above it can be seen that there is a significant amount of bad debt in English football. Based on the 2008-09 season, £105 million of the Premier League's total interest charges of £184 million cannot be met by the combined operational profits of the 20 clubs. Who is paying the £105 million then? Benefactor owners and directors through so-called "soft loans" that generally require no interest payments today but which can be called in at any time should the benefactor eventually tire of his or her return-free investment. Calling in of soft loans is one of the most common triggers for sending a club into administration.

The Football league is far worse—the 72 Football League clubs make a combined loss of £75 million before any interest payments are made. So all of the Football League's debt is, by definition, bad debt. By far the single biggest problem in the Football League is the fact that players' wages represent an unmanageably high percentage of revenues (86% in 2008-09). With non-wage costs (rent, utilities, maintenance, food, players' kit & equipment, general supplies, etc) usually representing around 15-25% of revenues this means that it is fundamentally impossible to run a profitable club in the Football League. This is why insolvencies and administrations have been all too commonplace in the lower leagues for some time now and will continue until a sustainable financial model is adopted that is capable of consistently generating positive cash flow from operations.

In summary then, the question of whether there is "too much debt in football" is at best moot and at worst irrelevant until the fundamental operational model of English football is addressed. This means finding a way for Premier League and Football League clubs—particularly the latter—to bring their cost structures more into line with their revenue models. Managing the wage bill is part of this but so is managing revenue in terms of estimating it better, diversifying revenues sources and being generally more conservative about revenue before aligning costs against it. Only when you are running a business that is consistently putting "more money in the till" than is being paid out should it make any sense for you to be asking for a loan. It should make even less sense for someone to actually lend it to you. And perhaps that's the main point—all debt is bad debt if you shouldn't have it in the first place. That's what my Dad would have said!

4.  What are the pros and cons of the Supporters' Trust share holding model?

The Supporters' Trust model was a noble effort to counter the tide of commercialism in football by providing opportunities for fans to own blocks of shares in their clubs and thereby—theoretically—to increase their influence over board decisions. In essence the Supporters' Trust model attempts to mitigate the impact of the Principal-Agent problem discussed in one of my earlier responses whereby club owners and boards will generally make decisions in their own interest rather than those of the broader stakeholder community at large. The ultimate goal of any Supporters' Trust is to achieve an adequate level of share ownership such that the Trust is able to secure its own seat on the board and indeed a number of Trusts have succeeded in this. Some Trusts have even taken ownership of their clubs but this has usually been in situations where the club faced extinction (or had actually been made extinct already). There are even cases where Supporters' Trusts have started up new clubs in direct opposition to an existing club's owners as with FC United, born as a result of supporter dissatisfaction with the Glazer regime at Manchester United.

The primary drawback to the Supporters' Trust model is the difficulty and the cost involved in securing an adequate number of shares to achieve meaningful influence over the decisions of the board, particularly for the larger clubs. Even with the help of money from the UK government's Supporter Direct initiative it requires a ludicrously large amount of cash to buy a seat on the board of a Premier League club. It is obviously easier with smaller Football League clubs but then the issue here is that the Trusts in these cases are often taking over after the previous owners have driven the club into the ground. Clearly for the supporters of these clubs the Trusts have saved something worth saving but should we really be satisfied with the ultimately evolved role of Supporters Trusts being to clean up the mess of asset stripping former owners? Again I draw attention to the very current case of Tottenham Hotspur's owners wanting to take over the 2012 Olympic Stadium after the Games. A model that gave Spurs fans more influence over board decisions than their Supporters Trust currently does would have given the club's North London-based supporters more of a voice in the outcome. The Tottenham example illustrates what I believe will be a continuing dilemma for those fans of larger Premier League clubs who still associate their club with the local community. As top flight football becomes ever more global in its reach it is only natural that club owners, if allowed to drive their decisions based on purely commercial criteria, will continue to de-emphasize the needs of a club's "indigenous" fan base. The current Supporters' Trust model will have less ability to influence this trend than a rafter in white water can avoid going over the falls with only spoons in his hands for paddles.

In my final two posts tomorrow and Wednesday I will introduce a governance model that, in my opinion, strives for identical objectives as the Supporters' Trust model but without the Trust's limitations. It is a model that would support the governance and operation of competitive and financially healthy football communities at the highest levels of both the domestic and the international game. It would not be possible to implement this model without resistance from some quarters but then my understanding is that this Inquiry is not about making friends. My understanding is that it's about doing what it takes to get our game back. Agents beware, the Principals are re-taking the asylum!

5.  Is Government Intervention Justified and Can Lessons Be Learnt from Other Governance Models?

In my previous responses to the Select Committee Call for Evidence questions I have discussed many of the underlying reasons why the governing bodies of football in our country are not fit for purpose. I have addressed the issue of rampant over-commercialism that has relegated the social and cultural aspects of football to an afterthought and brought the game to near financial meltdown. I have also talked about the misaligned incentives and conflicts of interest that plague the FA board and the inability of the FA to implement effective policy through its lack of vision, leadership and accountability.

Apart from the above, all is well.

No, seriously action is required and not the type of action that involves further root and branch reviews, a fat report and a promise that action will be taken. The type of action needed is the type that will produce measurable results. Results such as local communities being able to keep their football clubs (whether the football club in question is Worksop Town or Tottenham), clubs only being owned by persons with the club and community's best interests at heart, and a successful England national side. What these results all have in common are communities. Each result, when it happens, is in the best interest of a community whether the community in question is that of a non-league club, a Premier League club, or the whole country for the national side. So the litmus test of any proposed action plan resulting from the Select Committee Inquiry must, in my opinion, be "will this action plan with 100% certainty benefit all football communities?"

The challenge with plans intended to benefit communities is that communities generally wield little power. Particularly football communities. It's been said that football clubs possess greater brand loyalty than, well, anything. How many times have you said after your team has played like drains again "that's it! I'm done with this lot!" only to return loyally the following week. Football clubs have monopoly power in their communities so fans themselves have next to no leverage when it comes to unscrupulous owners taking advantage of their beloved club.

What this all means is that we will need help from a higher power to make any changes in football governance that primarily benefit supporter communities. And yes, this means regulation. But it doesn't have to be heavy handed regulation that places all kinds of draconian restrictions and reporting requirements on the entities in question. All it has to be is low-touch regulation that protects the interest of the stakeholder groups least able to protect themselves—fans and the broader communities within which clubs are situated. This regulation specifically needs to make sure that the assets and profits of the club are retained primarily for the benefit of the football club and its community as opposed to profiteers with little real interest in the game. The regulation still needs to allow investors in the club to make at least a conservative return though, and it should still be possible to pay the salaries required to hire the players, coaches and management staff required to produce a competitive team. And there should be no barrier to the club generating handsome revenues and making attractive profits provided again that the majority of these profits are reinvested in the club.

Well guess what...I just happen to have just such a low touch regulated governance model handy. It's called a Community Interest Company. Community Interest Companies (CICs) are limited companies created specifically for the use of people who want to conduct a business or other activity for community benefit, and not purely for commercial gain. CICs operate to all intents and purposes like normal commercial enterprises with the exception that certain built-in safeguards exist to ensure that the majority of profits are reinvested in the community. The ability to form CICs has only been around since 2005 when the UK government introduced them under the Companies (Audit, Investigations and Community Enterprise) Act 2004. A surprisingly readable online CIC Fact Pack providing a detailed description of the CICs business form and how to form a CIC has been published by the government's CIC Regulator. The benefits and advantages of the CIC business form over can also be found online here. There are currently 4,491 CICs registered (including 10 football clubs) and a list of all CICs can be found on the Community Interest Companies web site. Although no Football League sides have yet adopted the CIC form there is absolutely no reason why any English professional club or for that matter any football governing body could not operate under the CIC model. To all intents and purposes the clubs and the FA could operate like any other private business meaning they could:

Generate as much revenues and make as much profit as they want.

—  Hire the best people (whether players, coaches, management, marketing, finance or other job types needed at football clubs and governing bodies) at whatever salaries the job market demand that they be paid.

—  Raise capital by selling shares and access the debt market for loans and bonds.

Are there catches? Yes, two. But both catches are designed to protect the community stakeholders for which the CIC is designed. The first is an asset lock which basically ensures that the CICs assets cannot be transferred out of the community (for example to a holding company, the loophole that killed the FA's Rule 34) and the second is a cap on dividend distribution. To encourage investment (but not profiteers) the dividend cap is 35% of distributable profits, not actually that restrictive. For investors who care about football but still like the idea of an attractive return this isn't a bad deal.

An example of how CICs could work in English football is shown in Figure 1 below with all 92 clubs in the Premier league and Football league operating as CICs together with the England National team. The idea is that the professional league clubs and the England side would still operate as profit generating businesses but with the controls that would ensure both that the profits flowed back into the respective communities and that community stakeholders had a strong say in the direction of the club. Again, these controls would apply for the Arsenal and Walsalls of the world as much as they would for England.

The other key element of the suggested organization structure in Figure 1 is the reporting relationship between the professional leagues and the FA. In the structure shown the Premier League and the Football League report into a FA Corporate entity that is responsible for setting the vision, mission, strategy and policy of the English game. This model is similar to the German Football Association which has succeeded in maintaining control of the German professional league the Bundesliga. The benefit of this for German football is that no conflict exists between the Bundesliga and the German national team. When the German national side suffered a temporary dip in form in the late 1990s/early 2000s the German Football Association (with the involvement of former Germany world cup player Jurgen Klinsmann) worked closely with the teams in the Bundesliga to implement a new playing style that would be suitable for the German national side. This resulted in a resurgence of form for Germany and an excellent run to the semi-finals of the 2006 World Cup. The failure of the FA to prevent the breakaway of the Premier League from the Football league in 1992 has resulted in the Premier League having too much influence over the direction of English football. The strategy pursued by the German Football Association and Jurgen Klinsmann would not be possible today in England because the Premier league would not allow it. The absurdity of the current football governance model in this country is highlighted by the fact that Sir Dave Richards is both Chairman of The Premier league and of Club England. It is absolutely essential that the Premier League has no role in matters concerning the national side if the problems surrounding England's performance at international level are to be resolved.

In summary the combination of the CIC business model and the bringing of the professional leagues under a FA Corporate entity will address both the over-commercialism of English football and the misaligned incentives and conflict of interest at the root of the problem with football governance in England today. Such a transformation will undoubtedly meet much resistance from certain quarters but this must not blunt the resolve of those powers possessing the authority to implement such change. Anything less than a complete overhaul of today's football governance model will be guaranteed to result in business as usual. The heritage of our beautiful game and the legacies of the proud footballing communities that have gone before us deserve far more.

Figure 1

SUGGESTED ORGANIZATION STRUCTURE FOR FOOTBALL GOVERNANCE IN ENGLAND





 
previous page contents next page


© Parliamentary copyright 2011
Prepared 29 July 2011