Written evidence from HS2 Action Alliance
(HSR 153)
1. What are the main arguments either for
or against HSR
HS2 (and probably HSR in general) offers "poor"
value for money in the UK because:
Benefits
rely upon an exaggerated value of journey time savings, as time
on trains is not wasted (section 3.2), this also has implications
for DfT's system of valuation (section 4).
Demand
modelling has substantially overestimated rail demand growth (section
3.4).
Use
of an unrealistic "do minimum" case causes HS2 to have
artificial benefits (section 3.5).
Failure
to consider competition overestimates revenues and understates
overall costs.
Improving the existing rail network is a better alternative
(section 3.6):
Alternatives
can deliver all the forecast demand required.
It
is cheaper and better value for money.
It
can be implemented in stages and quickly when required, avoiding
crowding and the risk of over-provision from relying on long term
forecasts.
Technical uncertainty (section 3.3) with HS2:
DfT
do not acknowledge or explore issues of deliverability of the
Y "stem" train frequencies.
No
adjustments are made to the forecast benefits to reflect the risk
of undeliverability.
Capacity
on HS2 trains running on the classic network is insufficient to
carry forecast traffic.
Specification and route (section 4) choices:
Journey
time savings being worth much less removes the rationale for very
high speed, with the trade-off between the benefits and disadvantages
of speed needing reappraisal.
Route
selection and station decisions are similarly in need of revisiting.
Environment (section 6):
Carbon
impacts are higher than DfT suggest in particular because of the
re-use of runway capacity and the carbon intensity of the electricity
generation HSR requires.
High
speed is destructive of the countryside as it departs from existing
transport corridors.
HS2
can have only a limited impact on domestic aviation, as it is
relevant only for the London - Scottish lowlands routes.
HS2
cannot successfully compete with short-haul European services,
as the market is too small for trains to provide a service frequency
that can match smaller capacity aircraft.
Priority:
HSR
should not be a UK priority as we already have fast frequent intercity
rail services,[175]
and HSR time savings do not provide the step change typical of
overseas HSR experience
HSR
is a curious target for subsidy, as it encourages additional travel
and is regressive because the affluent are the main users of long
distance rail (section 5)
HSR is unlikely to rebalance the economy:
Faster
connections between the regions and London are, on balance, more
likely to favour the economic development of London over the regions
(section 5).
It is not practicable to discuss all these topics
in this submission. A fuller discussion can be found at "Review
of February 2011 consultation business case for HS2", HS2AA,
May 2011.
3. Business case
3.1 Robustness of assumptions and methodology:
There are a number of serious methodological errors
and omissions in DfT's assessment of HS2. When these are corrected,
the economic case for HS2 disappears, with both the London to
West Midland phase and the full "Y" network becoming
poor value for money (with benefits less than the subsidy required).
Annex 1 provides a reworking of the benefit cost ratios (BCR).
DfT's assessment of HS2 is a form of social cost
benefit analysis. It is not a commercial business case, and accepts
that HS2 requires a subsidy. The revenues generated involve substantial
abstraction from the existing network revenues (as most passengers
are expected to transfer), resulting in the incremental revenue
unable to cover the cost of the investment.
This means that economic and welfare benefits are
needed to justify the subsidy. In the case of HS2, for the full
"Y" £44 billion of social benefits are claimed
against a subsidy of £17 billion. However there are serious
issues with:
The
value given to the journey time savings from higher speeds, and
the consequence this has for the best approach to HSR.
The
technical delivery of the service pattern and the absence of any
mention of this issue, or its implications in the case for HS2.
The
level of rail travel forecast and the manner in which this forecast
was derived.
The
failure to develop a best alternative to HS2, and use of an unrealistic
"do minimum" that implies there is no real alternative
to HS2 and artificially inflates its benefits.
Ignoring
competition with the existing rail network.
3.2 Benefits
The largest benefits of HSR are on-board journey
time savings: 40% (£18 billion) of HS2's £44 billion.
Productivity: DfT's benefits
appraisal framework ignores that mobile technology is transforming
the productive potential of travelling on trains. This is important
as £14 billion of the £44 billion (see Annex 1) relates
to the productivity benefit of reducing journey times: DfT assume
that every minute taken off the journey time creates an extra
minute of productive time.
The process of time on trains becoming productive
(and more enjoyable) is an on-going one. Currently there are
weaknesses in radio coverage (that reduce efficiency), and while
market penetration has proceeded beyond early adopters, it is
not complete especially for mobile internet and ultra portable
systems. But when considering the benefits of a project starting
more than 15 years hence, it would be expected that all travellers
would have access to such advanced technology as they need to
be able to spend their time effectively.
Of course not all time on trains is or will ever
be fully productive. People need to find there seats, unpack,
pack up again and get ready to disembark. But journey time savings
do not effect such unproductive time, rather the duration of the
time in the middle.
Some business travellers on long distance trains
also use their time to take refreshments, a cup of coffee or a
meal. Such time is not productive, but reducing the journey time
does not generate productive time unless the coffee or meal is
forgone.
DfT correctly observe that the value of time should
not be altered in isolation,[176]
and there are consequential adjustments that need to be made.
What is required is an extensive re-think on the values of time
saving and the costs of crowding from those settled a decade ago
on even older data. It is clear that crowding can result in rendering
time unproductive and materially less enjoyable, hence crowding
values should be changed.
However DfT are mistaken about the specific implications
of these changes for HS2:
HS2
only appears to relieve crowding against an unrealistic comparator.
It has no crowding benefits compared with the best alternative
which is its proper comparator (see section 3.5).
Adjusting
the value of time for journey time reductions also has serious
implications on decisions about how fast high speed railways should
be designed to go, and the trade offs inherent in this and route
choices. This is discussed at section 4.
DfT
suggest that modal transfer from air and car would restore the
benefits, as those swapping would gain productive time. But air
will shortly have facilities for full use of mobile technologies.[177]
And for car, the 7% of HS2 passengers transferring from car could
not possibly off-set the loss of benefit from the others. DfT's
methodology (with some logic) attributes new rail passengers with
half the value of benefits of existing rail passengers swapping
from classic rail to HS2. This implies the new passengers gain
no value from productivity, if HS2 has no productivity benefit
over classic rail.
DfT
offer an alternative defence. They claim that decisions made
by business travellers maximise their overall productivity and
reveal the value business travellers actually place on time savings.
They claim this indicates even higher values for time savings.
But such decisions may reveal many things quite unrelated to
productivity: business travellers generally do not bear the cost
of their travel and so their choices may be driven by other motives
than business efficiency. Their decisions may relate to matters
of minor personal convenience or prestige, and reflect the extent
to which business travel is managed within their organisation.
It is hardly reasonable to base a £30 billion investment
on speculation on what business travellers' choices may or may
not reveal without any systematic analysis.
DfT's case for HS2 relies on valuing time savings
in a manner that is now outdated. They have failed to appreciate
that it makes a material difference to how they should assess
HSR.
It is not satisfactory to justify public subsidy
on a benefit that there can be no confidence will exist when HS2
commences services. DfT cannot rely on an increasingly outdated
view of how people can work or on speculation that time savings
may yet be highly valuable if assessed in some other as yet undeveloped
manner. This is an issue for any high speed railway that needs
to be justified on productivity and welfare benefits.
Unit value: DfT use a
value of business time that relates to 10 year old data. The
earnings relate to a very high point in the earnings distribution,
equivalent to about £70,000/a in 2009. It is 40% more than
the figure for car drivers and 96% higher than for car passengers.[178]
DfT escalate the value of business time by the expected increase
in real earnings throughout the appraisal period, and so assume
that business travel remains the preserve of the earnings elite.
Given that long distance rail travel has increased
by 60% since 2000, and the forecasts for HS2 project a further
quadrupling (against a population increase of only 22%), DfT expect
about a six-fold increase in business demand over when the original
data was collected.
The major increase in the use of rail for long distance
business trips means it is not credible that all the journeys
could be made by such elite earners. Nor is the rail earnings
differential above car drivers credible given that this growth
will mainly be by modal shift from cars. If we assume that the
relative earnings of rail business travellers reduce to the average
(mean) of "managers and senior official" this reduces
earnings by a third, but this figure is still in the top decile
of earnings.[179]
This in itself would materially reduce expected benefits
(by £7 billion out of £44 billion as it affects all
time savings and reliability benefits, see Annex 1), but many
of these benefits are also subject to downward adjustments for
other reasons.
3.3 Technical deliverability
The service pattern assumed for the "Y"
Network requires running 18 trains/hr on the Y "stem"
(London West Midlands section) in the peak, but:
No
services to Heathrow or running onto HS1 have been included in
the 18 train paths.
18
is problematic as it seems that with existing technology 15 trains/hour
is the maximum.[180]
If some of these services cannot be run, then the
assumed passenger numbers, revenue and social benefits (including
reliability) will be unobtainable. If new technology needs developing
rather than buying standard equipment, then the costs may prove
higher.
This is unsatisfactory in several respects:
Risk:
no consideration is given to the risk to delivery or discount
applied to the potential benefits. No sensitivity tests reveal
what happens if the Y is limited to 15 trains/hour.
Solutions:
DfT have presented no evidence that it will be technically achievable.
There is a report[181]
suggesting that HS2 Ltd do not expect that there will be a technical
solution, so that the projected benefits will only be obtainable
at the cost of building another HSR line.
The issue has been known for
a long time eg work for Greengauge21 drew attention to it in 2009[182].
The March 2010 documentation[183]
and Autumn 2010 Technical seminars both acknowledged that new
technology would be required. But the May/June 2010 workshops
(attended by DfT, HS2 Ltd and technical experts) concluded:
"So, the better approach,
as anticipated by HS2 Ltd, would be to presume that there will
need to be a second north-south high-speed line in due course
and plan accordingly. While this creates a fresh set of planning
challenges, it has a demonstrable business case, and resolves
the problems associated with the thinking in Cm 7827."
A suggested solution was that
HS2 trains would operate under computer control, but it was recognised
that this is unlikely to be viable given the interfaces with the
existing network (that HS2 would have).
Misinformed:
despite the previous documents the public
consultation materials contain no reference to these technical
uncertainties. Indeed DfT suggest[184]
the opposite:
"Any new high speed
lines would also be based on proven European standards, technology
and practices, reducing the risk of unanticipated technical problems."
Heathrow spur: The decision
in December 2010 to include a spur to Heathrow further worsens
the line capacity problem, because Heathrow services would need
to take the paths of some of the 18 services in the "Y"
specification, and the junctions will also reduce capacity
Phase 1: The London-West
Midlands phase of HS2 is not so reliant on new technology, with
only 14 trains/hour in the peak, albeit within this 14 none are
included for services onto HS1 and through to the Continent.
However, with a benefit cost ratio of only 1.6 (or 2.0 with Wider
Economic Impacts (WEI)) and the same vulnerability to benefit,
demand and comparator issues, a case for Phase 1 alone is not
sustainable. On DfT's own re-working of the economic analysis
of the alternatives of upgrading the WCML, "Rail Package
2" (RP2) has a better benefit cost ratio 1.9 (without WEI)
- and DfT acknowledge that this underestimates its benefits.
Reliability: HS2 is assumed
to deliver improved reliability, contributing almost £6 billion
of the £44 billion benefits (see Annex 1), as each minute
of improvement is taken to be worth three minutes of on-board
journey time.[185]
A self contained new railway running trains of the same type
is expected to achieve high levels of reliability. However, HS2
is not an isolated railway, as classic compatible trains are planned
to run services from the classic network with mixed traffic, where
it can be expected to experience delays. Because HS2's service
pattern requires intensive usage, with no proposed means of isolating
itself, it can be expected to import unreliability. This makes
the claimed reliability improvements unrealistic.
Insufficient capacity on classic network:
the HS2 trains that will run onto the classic network will have
fewer seats than those they replace, and hence be incapable of
handling the increased growth. It is understood there are difficulties
in how to run more than one train per hour to Scotland. HS2 is
therefore unlikely to be capable of carrying the passengers forecast
for it.
3.4 Demand
DfT forecast rail growth doubling on WCML by 2043
(102% increase over 2008, an annual growth rate of 2%) to just
over trebling with the HS2 uplift (219%).
But their approach to demand forecasting is unsound
because:
Link
between wealth and travel decoupled: DfT
assume a relationship between economic growth and long distance
domestic travel for 35 years into the future, despite evidence
that the relationship has already weakened, if not expired entirely
(see Figure 1).
Sensitivities:
DfT fail to show that the investment in HSR is robust to a lesser
or less enduring linkage with economic growth - including not
following their own (webtag 3.15.4) guidance on conducting sensitivities
that would have shown the fragility of the case for HS2.
Outdated
model: DfT continue to employ a version
of the forecasting model that exaggerates growth in longer distance
journeys, failing to adopt their own draft guidance, the latest
version of the model, or heed the results of research that they
commissioned that show that their approach on this specific issue
(use of a distance addition) is now wrong.
Long
term 35 year forecast: DfT use the forecasting
model to predict rail demand over far too long a period in order
to "justify" a demand increase (a "doubling")
that they determined independently. If they had retained the
25 year cut off they used in their own 2010 forecast, then their
own analysis shows HS2 would be "poor" value for money
(ie BCR below 1).
HS2
uplift: this depends on journey time relationships
from the rail model that pre-date making time on trains productive,
and hence over values reducing journey times.
Link between wealth and domestic travel:
DfT assume a continued link over the 35 years that they forecast
demand increases. This is surprising as there is already evidence
that for both domestic travel (as in Figure 1) and long distance
domestic travel that this linkage has weakened and may have ended.
This decoupling of economic growth and domestic travel has also
been observed in other European countries.[186]
Figure 1
TRAVELLING TIME, TRIPS AND DISTANCES PER
PERSON (COMPARED WITH REAL GVA/CAPITA[187]
The trips per person have been constant (see Figure
2), but the DfT forecast assumes the over 100 mile trips will
increase from 7 to 9.5 by 2043 (by 36%).
Demand has grown with population. However, population
growth has been and is forecast to be relatively small (22% to
2043), explaining only a fifth of DfT's rail forecast (of 102%
to 2043).
With overall long distance demand showing saturation,
rail has grown strongly since privatisation in the mid 1990s.
But this needs to be put in context:
While
rail demand grew strongly from 1995, there was no growth from
the early 1950s to the mid-1990s at all.
There
are specific reasons that favoured rail growth (increased investment,
improved services, airline style pricing and mobile technology
making time on board more useful and enjoyable). But rail's modal
share cannot expand indefinitely.
In this situation, at minimum DfT should be concerned
that a major investment such as HSR is robust to the possibility
that long distance travel demand will cease growing with the economy
much earlier than 2043. In fact they fail to even consider the
lesser gearing of demand on economic growth that is required by
their own guidance.[188]
What DfT do show is that should demand stop growing at 2033, the
subsidy exceeds the benefits.
Out dated rail model:
DfT used an old version (PDFHv4.1) in which the "income elasticity"
factors forecast longer rail journeys to grow more quickly than
shorter ones. National Rail Trends data in fact shows the reverse:
the average long distance rail journey is now 16% shorter than
in 1995. PDFHv4.1 also has larger values for journeys to London
than those originating in London. For 1% more income, people
in Birmingham are expected to spend 2.48% more on travel to London,
whereas in Glasgow it is 2.80% more. This issue is recognised
as a problem:
DfT
issued Draft Guidance (but still to be adopted) which imposes
a cap (at 2.5%).
The
current model, v5.0, which was adopted in August 2009, removes
the distance factor eg an elasticity of 1.9% applies to both journeys,
but the HS2 forecast still used PDFHv4.1.
The recent research (for DfT and others) has now
confirmed that no distance addition is appropriate for longer
rail journeys,[189]
yet it has still been used to produce the DfT forecast.
Sensitivities: It has
already been noted that DfT require in their webtag guidance that
different elasticities be used as a sensitivity test. These are
substantially lower than not just v4.1 but also the latest PDFHv5.0
values. These tests were not conducted.[190]
Projecting demand increases too long:
The demand model used is inherently best suited to making short
to medium term rail forecasts. This is because it is a fixed
elasticity model that assumes people spend ever increasing proportions
of income on travel. It is normal to cap the period to reflect
market saturation. The use of a 35 year growth period is hard
to reconcile with:
DfT's
normal horizon for growth increases of 2026[191]
ie 18 yrs (2008-26)
Sir
Rod Eddington's view that a 10 year period was long enough.[192]
Network
Rail who see a cap as essential,[193]
although express concerns about using PDFH for long term forecasts.
PDFH was calibrated during a period of rapid rail growth, and
has been amended five times to reflect behavioural changes
DfT
who used a 25 year period (to 2033) for their March 2010 forecast,
justified on the HS2 completion date, rather than the capabilities
of the model.[194]
Given the cap concerns the "background growth" (not
induced demand), and the project's completion date does not effect
the durability of the current elasticities,[195]
this extension is difficult to understand
If
rail growth is considered over the preceding 35 years (ie from
1974, see Figure 3), only the last 15 years show any growth in
rail travel at all.
In fact DfT admit that they do not use the demand
model to forecast demand, but to estimate how long it would take
to double.[196]
"
..For our earlier work we capped
growth of rail demand in 2033, at a level of demand in the WCML
corridor that is slightly more than double current levels. With
the lower current GDP forecasts, this cap would now be hit later,
in 2043."
The "doubling" in demand has been preserved,
despite it having no basis in the 2011 analysis.
DfT do consider the effect of growth finishing earlier
(albeit in the context of it stopping both later and earlier than
2043), and say that growth is needed until 2034 before Phase 1
has benefits greater than the subsidy. So if DfT simply reused
the same 25 year cut-off as in the 2010 forecast (ie 2033) they
would have concluded that HS2 is "poor" value for money
(BCR under1).
Induced travel: HSR is expected to induce additional
travel and modal shift because journey times are shorter. The
uplift forecast (for HS2 (Phase 1) represents a 54% increase over
those transferring from classic rail. This is likely to be overestimated:
PDFHv4.1
is used to make the forecast, and it is based on journey time
relationships that pre-date the new technologies making time on
trains more productive
DfT
say that there was a 36% increase in demand for an average 34
minute reduction in journey time[197]
for WCML. HS2 journey time saving will be on average smaller
for the first phase of HS2. WCML could only partly reflect the
reducing value of journey time savings. Even 36% is therefore
a high estimate of uplift.
An "indicative revised forecast".
Tables showing the consequences of adjusting the demand forecast
to be based on more realistic assumptions are included at Annex
1. For demand we assume PDFH5.0 income elasticities, demand growth
capped at 25 years (2033), and the same level of uplift from HS2's
shorter journey times as that reported for WCML by DfT (36%).
This produces an "indicative demand forecast"
of 81% increase over 2008 for WCML for 2033 and staying at this
level (compared to DfT's 209% for 2043). Annex 1 col 8 shows
this reduces the BCR for the full "Y" to just 1.0 (including
WEI), and less for phase 1.
3.5 Comparison basis
The "do minimum" comparator assumes no
improvement in capacity or services beyond those already committed.[198]
It is unsuited as a basis against which HS2 can be assessed:
There
is no pretence that the "do minimum" case is realistic,
the forecast demand growth could not be sustained without capacity
development. Demand is forecast without regard to supply, with
the result that the capacity of the "do minimum" case
is insufficient.[199]
The
£5.1 billion benefits from relieving the high levels of crowding
in the "do minimum" case are entirely artificial and
result from its unrealistic nature (which is recognised by HS2
Ltd),[200]
with realistic alternatives having lower crowding than HS2 (as
discussed at section 3.6)
Proper
assessment needs to be based on comparing HS2 with the best alternative.
DfT
failed to develop a best alternative, making no attempt to produce
an optimised case.[201]
Using a "do minimum" case for reference
may be reasonable for short lead time projects, where little else
may happen in the timeframe. But to assume that the railway network
will be effectively unchanged for a period of over 30 years is
unreasonable and unrealistic. It also implies ignoring all the
opportunities for improvements that extensive renewals would offer.
Comparison with the best alternative potentially
increases some benefits because of how DfT value the benefits
from induced demand. But this effect is diminished by the reduction
in value of journey time savings and the questionable basis for
anticipating reliability improvements.
3.6 Alternatives
DfT fail to properly consider the alternatives to
a new railway, making no attempt to produce the best options that
match demand in terms of quantum and when it occurs and at minimum
cost.
The best alternative to the London-West Midlands
phase that was developed (RP2) has been repeatedly misrepresented,[202]
although it produces all the capacity needed (151% on DfT's numbers
over the 2008 base) and with a better benefit cost ratio.
In fact it is possible to develop a better alternative
than RP2, which requires less work on the track and is considerably
cheaper. Similar low cost solutions are available for the Midland
Main Line and ECML, which make up the suite of alternatives to
the full "Y" network.
The table is based on work by Chris Stokes[203]
that develops best alternatives to HS2 for WCML, Midland Mainline
and ECML. The table below gives the case for WCML (ie against
the London-West Midlands phase of HS2). It shows that greatly
more capacity is provided than is required on DfT's demand forecasts
(with a 102% increase to 2043), through various rolling stock
changes, and minimal investment in infrastructure.
BEST ALTERNATIVE FOR WCML
Interventions |
Daily
trains | Daily
standard
class
seats
| % increase above
2008 base
| Comments |
| | | Standard
class
| total | |
Train investment with no/little infrastructure investment
|
HS2 2008 Base | | 59,298
| | | Base used by DfT for evaluation of HS2. Predates full WCML upgrade timetable.
|
Current timetable | 286 |
81,924 | 38% | 36%
| Includes Voyager services (30 daily) |
Evergreen 3 | [68] | [28,900][204]
| | | Committed scheme - complete in 2011
Illustrative numbers -excluded from totals
|
Committed lengthening project | 286
| 105,924 | 79% | 63%
| Committed scheme - implemented from 2012 |
December 2013 additional services | 306
| 113,769 | 92% | 75%
| Additional hourly off-peak train each way |
First class reconfiguration | 306
| 134,379 | 127% | 84%
| One car converted from first to standard |
12 car sets (except Liverpool) | 306
| 166,908 | 181% | 121%
| Major physical constraints at Liverpool |
Infrastructure investment |
Additional services | 336 |
184,326 | 211% | 144%
| 30 additional daily trains following investment to relieve pinchpoints
|
Eddington[205] referred
extensively to the advantages of improving existing infrastructure
noting:
"
Upgrading rolling stock and lengthening trains
on congested rail links, combined with changes to timetables to
increase frequency can significantly increase the effective capacity
of existing rail lines. Evidence of illustrative interventions
to increase variable capacity on inter-urban links into London
by investing in new rolling stock, for example, suggests strong
returns are possible from well-targeted interventions, with wider
BCRs ranging between 1 and 13 and costs between £50 and £500
million but more typically between1 and 3.28. The higher returns
are largely driven by the ability to add variable capacity with
minimal infrastructure requirements
.."
The main advantages of the upgrade approach are:
Crowding:
because of the incremental character and short lead times, upgrades
can be made that prevent serious crowding from developing. It
has been repeatedly asserted that WCML will be full by 2020 -
only upgrading the existing services can address this problem.
HS2 has a loading factor of
58% which is higher than DfT's own RP2 alternative (52%) or the
best alternative shown in the table (also 52%).
With
a new recognition that crowding may stop time on trains being
productive (or enjoyable) - rather than being a minor annoyance
as DfT currently assess it - the benefits of preventing crowding
are much more important.
Cost:
the best alternative described above is considerably cheaper than
HS2, with an infrastructure cost of £2 billion instead of
£18 billion for the first phase of HS2. It is likely that
demand to 2043 could be entirely satisfied by rolling stock measures
avoiding the need for infrastructure investment.
Value
for money: most of the additional capacity
is achieved through more rolling stock and extra seats per train.
It is likely that the changes could be made on a fully commercial
basis, where the additional fares will pay for the investment.
If a subsidy is required it is likely to have a very high benefit
cost ratio.
Fast
and Incremental: upgrades remove the risk
associated with needing to forecast demand for long periods as
upgrades can be done in stages and relatively quickly.
Capacity:
Despite assertions to the contrary, upgrades of the existing
network have massive potential to increase capacity (as shown
in the table above). These increases are larger than that DfT's
forecast for demand to 2043 (102%). This means that upgrades
can meet capacity requirements for at least the next 35 years,
on DfT's forecasts. With more realistic forecasts they would
meet demand indefinitely.
Connectivity:
Unlike new HSR, the existing long distance rail network is highly
integrated with local transport. This is a major advantage over
HSR, as parkway stations have little or no existing connectivity
with public transport, new city centre station like Birmingham
Curzon Street are also remote from the existing transport hubs,
while connection into the existing networks are highly disruptive,
as with the approach into London and the rebuilding of Euston
Station needed for HS2.
Unlike HS2, uprating the existing
network does not bypass many major cities, with a resultant worsening
of their rail services. Despite statements implying the contrary,
the case for HS2 involves £5.4 billion saving from reducing
existing rail services. The effect of most passengers migrating
to HSR creates spare capacity (because existing services will
reduce), but any additional local services would be likely to
require additional subsidy.
Disruption:
despite assertions to the contrary, the best alternative would
result in very little disruption. Even RP2 which is more reliant
on infrastructure improvements than the best alternative, would
be far less disruptive than HS2
Environmental
impact: upgrades are environmentally preferable,
the lower speeds give rise to lower carbon emissions, they follow
existing rail corridors and so do not require the sacrifice of
an AONB or tranquil countryside.
The disadvantages that are often cited:
Less
benefits: the journey time savings will
be less than HSR, but they are also considerably over valued.
It is suggested it will achieve less modal shift from air However,
HS2 is unlikely to result in much shift, as the only domestic
routes susceptible to switching are the London - Scottish lowlands
routes. There are no air services between London and Birmingham
and Leeds. Rail already has 79% of the Manchester market, HS2's
journey times for 2033 to Newcastle will not improve on the fastest
train to London in the summer 2011 timetable. It is unlikely
that the lowlands of Scotland will have sufficient traffic to
represent as large a shift as DfT predict (equivalent to 95% of
the Heathrow/Scottish lowlands market for phase 1 and double for
the full Y) especially as the market is declining.
Worse
reliability: DfT strongly emphasise that
continued increases in services on the existing rail network will
result in deterioration in reliability. Lengthening trains is
unlikely to have such an effect, and addressing pinch points tends
to improve journey times and improve reliability. The evidence
is that as the railway has become busier, reliability has actually
been improving since Hatfield, with Network Rail hailing the Public
Performance Measure exceeding 90% for 2009, reaching the highest
level achieved.
Not
practical: RP2 has been said not to be
practical, as it involves intensive all day operations, rather
than just peak. This is an unsatisfactory argument as:
RP2
was developed for the 2010 White Paper by Atkins and timetabled
by Robert Watson Associates, both reputable consultancies, and
signed off by DfT.
RP2
was again included in the February 2011 consultation materials
as the WCML element of the upgrade alternative to HS2 Scenario
B, which indicates that DfT continue to believe it is a viable
option.
3.7 Lessons learned from previous projects
WCML Route Modernisation Project was originally specified
to deliver a new signalling system that allowed higher speeds,
more capacity, and lower costs than conventional signalling.
It eliminated lineside signalling equipment and was to use a yet
to be developed radio controlled moving block signalling system.
The new system has still yet to be developed, and the route modernisation
had to be successively respecified and de-scoped, eventually being
completed with conventional signalling and a lower top speed than
originally intended.
The delivery of the "Y" Network service
specification requires 18 trains/hour in the peak. The specification
has no trains available for Heathrow or HS1, which requires either
more train paths or fewer London services. 18 trains/hr is apparently
not achievable with current technology, as HS2 Ltd admit. It
seems that HS2 Ltd believe that it will be achievable with new
technology, although expert advise seems to be that HS2 should
not in prudence be assumed capable of more than 15 trains/hour.[206]
If HS2 needs to be de-scoped, even on DfT's assessment, the "Y"
Network would not be viable.
The Eddington Transport Study[207]
2006 noted:
"history has shown that for large-scale infrastructure
projects that rely on emerging technological solutions, costs
tend to increase by an order of magnitude against original estimates."
4. The strategic route
DfT's failure to adjust their evaluation framework
to recognise that time on long distance trains has been becoming
useful is important in the context of specification. While greater
speeds bring shorter journey times, they also bring disadvantages:
Higher
capital costs.
Higher
energy consumption (and carbon emissions).
Higher
maintenance costs.
Inability
to follow existing transport corridors (greatly increase the adverse
effect on landscape and local impacts).
Greater
noise pollution.
The decision on the optimal speed is therefore the
result of a trade-off between the benefits from journey time savings
and the adverse impacts. If the value of any given level of journey
time saving is substantially reduced, the best balance is likely
to favour a lower speed. To illustrate, if there are no productivity
benefits from the reduced journey time, and all travellers value
journey time savings at half the level leisure travellers did
before their time became more useful, the time saving is worth
only about 15% of its previous value.[208]
While revaluing time savings does not necessarily
change the preferred speed, the substantial reduction in value
calls into question decisions made on the previous basis. It
also invalidates the route selection process that HS2 Ltd have
operated, as this too involves trading-off journey time savings
against other factors. The likely effect of a revised approach
is:
To
prefer a speed specification more able to conform to existing
transport corridors.
Make
station stops more attractive.
Make
uprating existing infrastructure more attractive, as the inability
to deliver large journey time savings becomes a smaller consideration.
Case for HSR: Without
a high value of time savings for social benefits, the case for
a subsidy to build a HSR is likely to be weak. While this does
not affect a commercial case, a commercial case for a HSR is unlikely
to work in the UK, due to the existing fast and frequent train
services that would compete. While it is conceivable that a
case for a new railway could be made on the grounds of capacity,
in practice there are plentiful opportunities to increase the
capacity of the existing infrastructure at much lower cost, effectively
for the indefinite future.
Building from London:
Building HS2 in stages from London is likely to be best in that
it services the greatest potential demand first. However, as
the work on a possible Maglev study showed,[209]
this is likely to direct the economic benefits to London and South
East, compared to building from the north first.
Connections to Heathrow and HS1:
There is insufficient demand to justify frequent rail services
to Europe, without which HS2 could not successfully compete against
air (which with small planes can have frequent flights that are
near to full). This position is demonstrated by HS2 Ltd work
of 2010, summarised and extended in the work for 51M work (by
Chris Stokes)
5. Economic rebalancing and equity
While strong claims have been made about the benefits
of HSR in stimulating regional economies, there is no good evidence
that HSR will help bridge the North South divide.
HSR supporters (eg Greengauge 21) have commissioned
studies that purport to demonstrate large economic benefits for
the regions.[210]
However the methodology has problems that cause the results to
be overstated, according to a review[211]
by leading academics in this area. Similar criticism of the methodology
were raised in a review of the literature on the economic impacts
of HSR by Professor Tomaney.[212]
It seems that the balance of evidence suggests that
improving north south connections tends to favour London and the
South East, because of the draw of London and its greater efficiency
in financial services. To quote the Tomaney work:
"Overall, the report suggests that the impacts
of high speed rail investments on local and regional development
are ambiguous at best and negative at worst. It is very difficult
to find unambiguous evidence in support of the contentions that
are being made by the government about the potential impacts of
HS2 on the cities and regions of the UK."
This was also the conclusion of the Eddington Transport
Study[213]
after extensive review and discussion that "
..The
evidence for transformational benefits is at best unproven. .."
As there is only weak evidence of benefits, regeneration
should be a secondary consideration in route selection. If the
objective is to achieve regeneration, addressing the primary impediments
to growth - eg lack of skills, will be more relevant. If the
objective is to achieve regeneration through transport, local
and intra-regional schemes that improve the efficiency of local
economies would be more attractive.
Locations and socio-economic groups benefiting:
The places most likely to benefit are London and the South East
as HSR will giving improved access to Midlands and Northern markets
for financial services. The evidence suggests:
Station
sites and their immediate vicinity are likely to benefit from
redevelopment because they will become attractive as retail and
office locations. This is demonstrated by the work done for HS2
Ltd.
DfT
figures state of the 30,000 new jobs around stations, 73% are
in London. It seems generally accepted that such jobs are mainly
relocations rather than net additions, with the gains balanced
by losses in the station's hinterland.
HS2
Ltd's demand model implies leisure trips to London will outweigh
those starting in London - tourism can therefore be expected to
benefit London rather than the regions.
In regard to the potential beneficiaries, the main
beneficiaries will be the traveller or their employer. Assuming
that HS2 users will be similar to the long distance rail users
of today, the travellers will be predominantly drawn from the
most affluent sections of society (see Figure 4).
However, the productivity benefits to business would
be modest, because business travellers can be expected to be fully
productive on long distance trains well before HS2 is built, so
the reduced journey times would not represent a productivity benefit.
But businesses whose employees travel on HS2 would benefit from
the fares being below the full cost.
Beneficiaries contributing to costs:
The issue of getting beneficiaries to contribute to costs, thus
reducing the burden on tax payers who will not benefit directly,
is appealing. The presumption that there are large benefits that
will, without special measures, arise as significant windfall
gains to specific groups is incorrect, if those benefiting from
the line's construction and supply of the trains and equipment
are excluded.
Even local authorities benefiting from the new stations
may suffer counterbalancing detriment, as the new shopping centres
and offices will draw jobs from nearby but less favoured locations
rather than generate truly additional jobs.
An effective means of making those who benefit contribute
more would be to charge higher fares. But, while premium fares
might get those gaining the benefit to contribute more to the
cost, it would further concentrate users into the higher income
groups. Additionally, this may worsen the overall economics,
with high speed trains quite empty and the competing classic services
retained to carry those unwilling to pay higher prices.
6. Impact
Are the environmental costs and benefits correctly
accounted? The NATA framework quantifies those costs and benefits
suited to be monetised and includes them in the calculation of
the benefit cost ratio - other dimensions are assessed but not
reduced to a money value.
For HS2 there are several unsatisfactory features
in the accounting of environmental impacts:
Despite
the assumption that runway capacity will be constrained for London,
the carbon consequences of re-use of freed-up runway capacity
is not assessed or included in the quantified assessment - this
greatly understates the potential for increasing emissions.
The
potential reduction of aircraft emissions is unchanged from the
White Paper assessment, despite fewer passengers transferring
from air to HS2 and despite (by implication) some of air's demand
being suppressed demand.
The
emissions from electricity generation are stated to be the annual
all generation average, despite HS2's electricity requirements
being day time and peak.
The
spoil calculations greatly underestimate the volumes of spoil[214]
excavated from tunnels and cuttings in the Chilterns, causing
construction traffic to be similarly underestimated.
Annex 1
ECONOMIC SUMMARY TABLES
ADJUSTED DFT RESULTS FOR LONDON -WEST MIDLANDS
(PHASE 1): REVISIONS TO BENEFITS ONLY, DEMAND ONLY AND EFFECT
OF REVISING BOTH
All £bn NPV at 2009 prices
| DfT Feb 2011 (Phase 1) |
Revisions to benefits
only (see basis in
table below)
| Revised
demand
only
| Revisions
combined
|
Col 1
| 2 | 3
| 4 | 5
| 6 | 7
| 8 | 9
|
| Business
| Leisure/ commut |
Total | Business
| Leisure/ commut |
Total | Total
| Total |
1.1 Rail journey time saving | 5.7
| 1.7 | 7.3 | 0.4
| 0.8 | 1.2 | 4.5
| 0.7 |
1.2 Improved reliability | 1.8
| 0.5 | 2.3 | 1.2
| 0.5 | 1.7 | 1.4
| 1.0 |
1.3 Reduced crowding | 0.7 |
1.9 | 2.6 | 0 |
0 | 0 | 1.6 | 0
|
1.4 Waiting time | 1.4 |
1.4 | 2.8 | 0.9 |
1.4 | 2.3 | 1.7 |
1.4 |
1.5 Other impacts eg access | 0.3
| 0.4 | 0.6 | 0.2
| 0.4 | 0.6 | 0.4
| 0.3 |
2. Road decongestion | 1.2 |
0.6 | 1.8 | 1.2 |
0.6 | 1.8 | 1.1 |
1.1 |
3. HS1 link | |
| 0.4 | | |
0.4 | 0.2 | 0.2 |
Total transport user | 11.1 |
6.4 | 17.9 | 3.9 |
3.7 | 8.0 | 10.9 |
4.9 |
Reduced tax | |
| -1.3 | | |
-1.3 | -0.8 | -0.8
|
Net transport benefits | |
| 16.6 | |
| 6.7 | 10.1 | 4.1
|
4.1 WEI - agglomeration | |
| 3.0 | |
| 3.0 | 3.0 | 3.0
|
4.2 WEI - imperfect competition |
| | 1.0 | |
| 0.2 | 0.6 | 0.1
|
Total WEI | |
| 4.0 | | |
3.2 | 3.6 | 3.1 |
Total net benefits incl WEI |
| | 20.6 | |
| 9.9 | 13.7 |
7.2 |
Additional revenue | |
| 13.7 | | |
13.7 | 8.4 | 8.4 |
Capital and operating cost |
| | 24.0 | |
| 24.0 | 24.0 |
24.0 |
Net subsidy | |
| 10.3 | | |
10.3 | 15.6 | 15.6
|
Benefit cost ratio (excl WEI) |
| | 1.6 | |
| 0.6 | 0.6 | 0.3
|
Benefit cost ratio (incl WEI) |
| | 2.0 | |
| 1.0 | 0.9 | 0.5
|
Basis of revisions to benefits (col 5-7), to demand (col 8)
and combined effect (col 9)
1.1: Business: productivity gain from shorter on-board
journey time reduced to zero. Time savings valued at the adjusted
leisure value. Leisure: time savings value is halved to
reflect the usefulness of on-board time.
Business time unit value is reduced by one third to reflect
less elite nature of rail business travellers with the major increases
in business volumes. Affects items 1.1, 1.2, 1.4, 1.5 and 4.2.
1.2: Reliability benefits for phase 2 assumed to be halved
due to issues about achievability of 18 trains/hour. No adjustment
is made to phase 1 (when 14 trains/hour).
1.3: Crowding benefit removed: realistic comparator of
uprating WCML eg RP2 is less crowded than HS2.
1.4: Waiting time is not reduced although a realistic comparator
would have higher train frequency than "do minimum",
as RP2 does.
4.2: This item reduces automatically as valued at 10% of all business
time savings and reliability benefits.
Benefit adjustments (col 5-7): DfT demand forecast unchanged
(ie +209% increase); effect of applying revisions to basis of
benefits is pro rata to DfT demand for all items except 1.6, 4.1
and costs.
Demand adjustments: (col 8): DfT benefits basis unchanged;
uses an "indicative revised forecast" of 81% increase
over 2008 base (incl. *background growth and **HS2 uplift), instead
of DfT forecast of + 209%.
Revisions combined (9): the effect of revising the basis
of both DfT benefits and DfT demand forecast.
*"Background growth": 38% at 2033 and remaining
at this level (compared with DfT 102% at 2043); based on PDFHv5.0
income elasticities; DfT 2011 annual growth rate capped at
2033. **With HS2 uplift: 38% is increased to 81% (with
HS2 uplift) at 2033 and remaining at this level (compared with
DfT 209% at 2043); based on WCML uplift of 36%.
ADJUSTED DFT RESULTS FOR FULL "Y" NETWORK: REVISIONS
TO BENEFITS ONLY, DEMAND ONLY AND EFFECTS OF REVISING BOTH
All £bn NPV at 2009 prices |
DfT Feb 2011 (full "Y")
| Revisions to benefits
only (see basis in
table below)
| Revised
demand
only
| Revisions
combined
|
Col 1
| 2 | 3
| 4 | 5
| 6 | 7
| 8 | 9
|
| Business
| Leisure/ commut |
Total | Business
| Leisure/ commut |
Total | Total
| Total |
1.1 Rail journey time saving
| 14.1 | 4.3
| 18.4 | 0.9
| 2.2 | 3.1
| 11.2 | 1.9
|
1.2 Improved reliability
| 4.4 | 1.3
| 5.7 | 1.5
| 0.6 | 2.1
| 3.5 | 1.3
|
1.3 Reduced crowding |
1.5 | 3.6
| 5.1 | 0
| 0 | 0
| 3.1 | 0
|
1.4 Waiting time | 2.0
| 2.0 | 4.0
| 1.3 | 2.0
| 3.3 | 2.4
| 2.0 |
1.5 Other impacts eg access
| 0.5 | 0.6
| 1.2 | 0.4
| 0.6 | 1.0
| 0.7 | 0.6
|
1.6 Released capacity benefits
| | | 1.3
| | | 1.3
| 1.3 | 1.3
|
2. Road decongestion |
2.7 | 1.3
| 4.0 | 2.7
| 1.3 | 4.0
| 2.4 | 2.4
|
3. HS1 link |
| | 0.4 |
| | 0.4
| 0.2 | 0.2
|
Total transport user |
25.2 | 13.1
| 39.9 | 8.3
| 7.3 | 15.1
| 24.9 | 9.7
|
Reduced tax |
| | -2.7 |
| | -2.7
| -1.6 | -1.6
|
Net transport benefits |
| | 37.3
| | | 12.5
| 23.3 | 8.1
|
4.1 WEI - agglomeration
| | | 4.1
| | | 4.1
| 4.1 | 4.1
|
4.2 WEI - imperfect competition
| | | 2.4
| | | 0.8
| 1.3 | 0.4
|
Total WEI |
| | 6.5 |
| | 4.9
| 5.4 | 4.5
|
Total net benefits incl WEI
| | | 43.8
| | | 17.3
| 28.7 | 12.6
|
Additional revenue |
| | 27.2
| | | 27.2
| 16.6 | 16.6
|
Capital and operating cost
| | | 44.3
| | | 44.3
| 44.3 | 44.3
|
Net subsidy |
| | 17.1 |
| | 17.1
| 27.7 | 27.7
|
Benefit cost ratio (excl WEI)
| | | 2.2
| | | 0.7
| 0.8 | 0.3
|
Benefit cost ratio (incl WEI)
| | | 2.6
| | | 1.0
| 1.0 | 0.5
|
May 2011
175
"Evidence that UK already has a fast national railway network"
HS2AA January 2011 Back
176
"Economic Case for HS2" February 2011, section 7.3.3,
page 51 Back
177
See Sunday Times article 27 March 2011 (In Gear) The breakthrough
is in providing connectivity without interfering with, or dependence
on, ground based transmitters Back
178
Webtag Unit 3.5.6, Table 1, based on 1999-2001 NTS data. Back
179
ASHE April 2009 survey. Back
180
"High Speed Two Interfaces" Greengauge 21, July 2010,
section 4a, page 6 (obtained under FOI) Back
181
"High Speed Two Interactions" Greengauge 21, July 2010,
section4a, page6 Back
182
"Fast Forward A High Speed Rail Strategy for Britain"
2009, Appendix B, Sections2.4-2.6 Back
183
"HS2 Technical Annex" HS2 Ltd, December 2009, section
2.3.2, page 6 Back
184
"High Speed Rail - Investing in Britain's Future" DfT,
February 2011, section 2.46 page 51 Back
185
"HS2 Demand Model Analysis", February 2010, section
3.4 Back
186
See Transport at the Crossroads EEA Report 3/2009, for decoupling
in Europe using Eurostat data, and "The Prospects for Inter-Urban
Travel Demand", Y Crozet-Discussion Paper 2009-14-OECD/ITF,
2009, section 2.2 Back
187
Based on analysis by Dr Metz based on NTS 2008 Table 2.1 with
GVA/capita trend added Back
188
Webtag unit 3.15.4 (section 6.1.1 page 7), states the alternative
elasticities to be used for sensitivities Back
189
The findings of research by Oxera and Arup were publicly presented
at Transport Economists Group in February 2011 (by Oxera, Arup
and DfT) Back
190
The fact that Webtag 3.15.4 sensitivities were not used was confirmed
by HS2 Ltd (Mark Weiner 12 May 2011), although an FOI response
(received 16 May 2011) said they did not hold the information Back
191
Webtag unit 3.13.1 Section 3.3. DfT August 2007. It says central
case should cap growth at 2026 Back
192
"Inter Urban Rail Forecasts" section 3.17. Whilst the
trends may be a consistent basis for forecasting forward through
time, they do not account for saturation of demand in the rail
market, and as such, confidence in such an uncapped forecasting
procedure must reduce considerably for forecasts beyond 2016.
Eddington, 2006 Back
193
"Network Route Utilisation Strategy: Scenarios and Long Distance
Forecasts" Network Rail, June 2009, Section 4.2 page 30;
and also Section 5.2 page 34 Back
194
"HS2 Demand Model Analysis", HS2 Ltd, February 2010,
section 3.2.6 page 31 Back
195
HS2 Ltd state the limits purpose as "
proxy for market
maturity and the long term lack of certainty in the forecasting
methodology.." HS2 Demand Model Analysis' HS2 Ltd, Feb. 2010,
section 3.2.6, page 31 Back
196
"Economic Case for HS2" February 2011, section 3.2.9
page 14 Back
197
"Demand for Long Distance Travel" April 2011, section
6.19 page 16 (the 36% relates to 2006 to 2009) Back
198
On WCML this involves extending part of fleet to 11 car, four
new sets and IEP. It however excludes Evergreen 3, that reduces
the Birmingham London journey time on Chiltern Railways, that
will win business from WCML, delaying the requirement for any
additional WCML capacity Back
199
"Baseline Forecasting Report: A Report for HS2", Atkins,
February 2010, section 2.64, page 19. "
.Do Minimum
matrices for rail (and road) are estimated by uplifting constrained
(ie ex-post/observed) 2007-8 demand for exogenous influences only,
with no attempt to estimate levels of underlying unconstrained
demand, or the effects of changes in supply/congestion occurring
after 2007." Back
200
Baseline Forecasting Report: A Report for HS2, Atkins, February
2010, section 2.64, page 19 Back
201
DfT conceded that Rail Package 2 had not been optimised, but that
it was irrelevant because it provided insufficient capacity, 20
September 2010 (letter Jonathon Mitchell to Bruce Weston) Back
202
Review of February 2011 Consultation Business Case, May 2011,
HS2AA section 5 Back
203
Chris Stokes, former SRA director and independent rail consultant Back
204
Illustrative Evergreen 3 figures assume Chiltern trains currently
four car class 168 units (275 seats), lengthened to six car class
168 (425 seats) Back
205
Eddington Transport Study, December 2006Volume 3, page 207, 4.164 Back
206
"High Speed 2 Interfaces" Greengauge21, July 2010, section
4a, page 6 Back
207
Eddington Transport Study, December 2006, Volume 3, page 109,
4.173 Back
208
Using 2009 values from "Technical Seminar QA77483" HS2
Ltd, 2010. Back
209
"UK Ultraspeed Evidence to the Eddington Review" part
of "UK Ultraspeed Factbook | Expanded 2nd Edition, October
2006", page 120 Back
210
for example, "High Speed Rail in Britain Consequences for
employment and economic growth", KPMG, 2009, and "High
Speed Rail Consequences for employment and economic growth",
KPMG, March 2010 Back
211
"Review of methodologies to assess transport's impacts on
the size of the economy", James Laird and Peter Mackie (ITS),
September 2010. Back
212
"The Local and Regional Impacts of High Speed Rail in the
UK: A Review of the Evidence", John Tomaney, Pedro Marques
and Penny Marshall, April 2011. Back
213
Eddington Transport Study, December 2006 Volume 3, page 133, 1.33 Back
214
By 18 times according to Steve Roderick, Chief Officer of the
Chiltern Conservation Board Back
|