3 The public finances
Changes announced in the Autumn
Statement
42. The impact of measures announced in the Autumn
Statement is summarised below. The Government estimates the fiscal
impact to be savings of £3.97 billion in 2012-13, with an
increase in spending over receipts of £910 million in 2013-14.
Over the forecast period, the net impact is a saving of £6.47
billion.Table
2: Overall fiscal impact of Autumn Statement measures
| £ million
|
| 2012-13
| 2013-14
| 2014-15
| 2015-16
| 2016-17
| 2017-18
|
Total tax policy decisions
| -870 | +180
| -2,385 | -905
| +295 | +305
|
Total spending policy decisions
| +4,840 | -1,090
| +1,465 | -
| - | +4,635
|
TOTAL POLICY DECISIONS
| +3,970 | -910
| -920 | -905
| +295 | +4,940
|
Source: HM Treasury, Autumn Statement 2012, 5 December 2012, Table 1, p 9
| | |
Performance against the fiscal targets
THE FISCAL MANDATE
43. The OBR is responsible for assessing the Government's
performance against the fiscal mandate and the supplementary target:
The Charter for Budget Responsibility defines the fiscal
mandate as "a forward-looking target to achieve cyclically-adjusted
current balance by the end of the rolling, five-year forecast
period". This means that total public sector receipts need
to at least equal total public sector spending (minus spending
on net investment) in five years time, after adjusting for the
impact of any remaining spare capacity in the economy. For the
purposes of this forecast and the spring 2013 EFO [Economic
and fiscal outlook], the five-year horizon ends in 2017-18.
The Charter says that the supplementary target
requires "public sector net debt as a percentage of GDP to
be falling at a fixed date of 2015-16, ensuring the public finances
are restored to a sustainable path." The target refers to
public sector net debt (PSND) excluding the temporary effects
of financial interventions.[79]
44. The OBR stated in its December 2012 Economic
and fiscal outlook that there was a greater than 50 per cent
chance of the Government meeting the fiscal mandate, albeit by
virtue of extending austerity measures a further year into 2016-17.
The cyclically-adjusted current budget was forecast to be in surplus
by 0.9 per cent of GDP in 2017-18the current target year
for the purposes of the mandateand by 0.4 per cent in 2016-17.[80]
THE SUPPLEMENTARY TARGET
45. The OBR forecast that the Government is unlikely
to meet its supplementary target. Public sector net debt (PSND)
is forecast to rise by 1 per cent of GDP in 2015-16 and then fall
by 0.8 per cent in 2017-18, thereby missing the target by one
year. The OBR had forecast that the target would be met in its
March 2012 EFO, but has since revised down nominal GDP
growth, revised upwards net borrowing and factored in the effect
of reclassifying Bradford and Bingley and Northern Rock Asset
Management as public sector liabilities. The effects of these
revisions are offset to a degree by the transfer to the Treasury
of the surplus balance in the Bank of England's Asset Purchase
Facility (APF).[81]
46. The Government has chosen not to implement
further cuts in order to meet the supplementary target. The Chancellor
effectively acknowledged that doing so could harm the economy.
He stated that:
one of the central judgments of this Autumn Statement
was not to chase the debt target, in other words, to accept that
we had missed the debt target, and had we chased the debt target,
that would have required significant cuts or tax rises over the
next couple of years.[82]
[
]
[
] faced with this choicehit the target
and potentially damage the economy in doing so, or miss the target
and help the economyI decided to help the economy.[83]
The Autumn Statement says that:
At this time of rising debt, the Government will
restore debt to a sustainable, downward path and will retain the
existing supplementary debt target. As set out in the June Budget
2012, the Government will set a new target once the exceptional
rise in debt has been addressed.[84]
47. Mr Mortimer-Lee stated that the existence
of a fiscal framework was in principle valuable but that:
[t]he fiscal framework should be a guide to action
and should constrain the Government's ability to come up with
policies that suit the short term but not the long term. The rule
helps to achieve that but it is not set in stone. We don't fall
off the end of the earth if we go past it.[85]
48. The Government is forecast
to meet the rolling fiscal mandate by cutting non-investment spending
as a share of GDP for a further year, but not the supplementary
target. It has decided not to propose further spending cuts or
tax rises in order to meet the latter. The possible failure to
meet the supplementary target raises the question of the continuing
credibility of that target. Successive governments have committed
themselves to, but then failed to meet, their fiscal targets.
For a fiscal target to be credible, it must be durable, and therefore
not subject to frequent revision as circumstances change. It must
also be capable of accommodating conditions different from those
at the time the target was first formulated. Nor should a fiscal
target be open to manipulation. It is not the case, though, that
a target is valuable only so long as it is met. A target can remain
credible, and so constrain a government's choices, even if it
is not being met, so long as the political commitment that created
it continues to inform policy decisions.
49. The supplementary target
remains in place for the moment. The Government has said that
it will set a new target, but its timetable is vague: it will
do so "once the exceptional rise in debt has been addressed".
When the Government does decide to create a new fiscal framework,
it should do so only after full public consultation.
The Committee will return to this issue.
Credit rating
50. We questioned witnesses on the likelihood
and impact of a downgrade of the UK's AAA credit rating. Mr Hayes
and Professor Booth both thought that a downgrade was likely.[86]
Mr Hayes, when asked if there would be a downgrade in 2013, replied:
I think it is quite likely. There are two reviews
coming up that we know of. Early in the year, probably January,
Moody's is looking to revisit this, and in March I think Fitch
are looking to review also. In particular as I understand it with
Fitch, we are on negative outlook, and on their criteria that
implies more than a 50% chance of a downgrade. That was instigated
in February this year, I think, since when things have got worse.
So it seems to me that things are moving clearly in that direction,[87]
51. As to the potential impact of such a downgrade,
both Professor Booth and Mr Johnson stated that the rating agencies
based their decisions on the same information available to the
broader market and that therefore any expectations of a downgrade
would already be priced into the cost of UK debt.[88]
Mr Hayes noted that France did not appear to have suffered material
rises in borrowing costs following the downgrades of its sovereign
debt. Mr Hayes stated that "the likelihood of a leap in bond
yields from a rating downgrade is negligible."[89]
52. The weight that the Government places on
maintaining the UK's AAA rating has shifted over time. The Chief
Secretary to the Treasury stated in June 2012 that the "UK
government [
] has re-established our country's financial
credibility. And the credit rating agencies rate the UK as triple
A. The low interest rates today of 1.8 per cent are a consequence
of this."[90] In
contrast, the Chancellor now maintains that the relevant measure
is the rate at which the UK can borrow in the international capital
markets: "the ultimate test is what you can borrow money
at."[91] Mr Mortimer-Lee
agreed on the relative unimportance of the rating itself:
The AAA rating to me doesn't matter that much. What
matters is what the UK can borrow at and that we have the right
policies. Having a label attached to us might be nice in some
sense, but does it really matter? I don't think it does. I would
agree that the cost to the UK might be about 25 basis points on
borrowing costs of losing it, but we should do the right things
for the right reasons and not just because the rating agencies
will mark us down.[92]
UK cost of borrowing
53. The Committee heard conflicting evidence
on the reasons for the UK's low borrowing costs. Mr Portes of
NIESR stated that:
we do not observe any observable correlation between
changes in deficits for countries like us, which have floating
exchange rates and an independent monetary policy, and gilt yields.
So long as the markets perceived the Government as having some
reasonable plan to balance public finances in the long-term, the
particular form that plan took was not relevant.[93]
In Mr Portes' view, economic theory suggested that
the Government's borrowing costs should in fact rise as the economy
improves:
If you thought that falling gilt yields or falling
spreads reflected increased confidence in UK plc, increased confidence
in the economy and all the rest of it, then you would have to
believe that, when gilt yields fell, the stock market would do
well. That is pretty simple. Is that what we observed? It is absolutely
not what we observed. If you look at day-to-day movements, especially
around the time when we were going through this supposed crisis
during 2010, the correlation between gilt yields and equity prices
goes exactly the wrong way. In other words, when gilt yields went
up, equity prices went up as well. In other words, when people
were feeling more optimistic, gilt yields went up. When people
were feeling less optimistic, yields fell. It is not about credibility,
it is about what you think is going to happen to the economy.
Economic weakness leads to low long-term interest rates. This
is really very basic macro-economics.[94]
54. In contrast, Professor Booth, whilst recognising
that there were several factors contributing to the UK's low borrowing
costs, believed that one factor was "reasonable credibility
with regard to the Government's financial plans."[95]
But witnesses noted the difficulty of decomposing the factors
explaining the rate at which the UK currently borrowed,[96]
with Mr Chote stating that "what is in the price clearly
is the sum of the market's views of current policy."[97]
Asset Purchase Facility transfer
55. On 9 November 2012, it was announced that
the cash surplus held in the Bank of England's APF was to be transferred
to HM Treasury. This means that any surplus or deficit generated
as a consequence of the operation of the Bank's quantitative easing
(QE) programme is reflected in the public finances on an ongoing
basis rather than as a one-off change when QE is unwound. The
Government and the Bank both maintain that this decision was simply
a matter of efficient cash management, and similar to the practice
of the Federal Reserve in the United States.[98]
56. There was some discussion concerning the
effects of the transfer on the fiscal mandate and supplementary
target. Public sector net debt will be reduced during the spending
review period by £71 billion, though as monetary policy tightens
and QE is unwound, this will reverse and will lead to an increase
in net borrowing.[99]
The OBR estimates that the net impact upon completion of the unwinding
of QE will be a small gain to HM Treasury of approximately £55
billion. In assessing this potential impact on public sector net
debt and the eventual outcome of QE's unwinding, the OBR was constrained
by the fact that the Office for National Statistics has yet to
state how it will treat the transfer in the national accounts.
The OBR presented in its
forecasts the effect of the Asset Purchase Facility transfer,
and set out its assumptions in modelling the unwinding of Quantitative
Easing. This transparency is welcome.
57. The Governor acknowledged to us that the
transfer of the APF surplus was equivalent in effect to further
monetary stimulus, stating that "it certainly affected monetary
conditions, in the sense that it was broadly equivalent to a stream
of asset purchases over the next year of £37 billion."[100]
On 8 November 2012, the Bank of England issued a press release
following the monthly meeting of the MPC in which no further QE
was announced. The press release did not mention the APF transfer
or its effect on monetary conditions.[101]
The Governor confirmed to us, however, that the MPC had known
about the APF transfer at the time of its November meeting.[102]
The information about the APF transfer became public the following
day, with the release of letters between the Chancellor and the
Governor detailing the transfer.[103]
58. This raised questions as to whether the Treasury
had usurped the role of the independent Monetary Policy Committee
in implementing monetary policy. Chris Giles, in a piece for the
Financial Times entitled "Policy ploys risk UK economic credibility",
argued that:
What about the independent Bank of England? Sir Mervyn
King confirmed yesterday that the interest rate setters viewed
the Treasury's actions as equivalent to £37bn of monetary
policy easing in the first year. So the Monetary Policy Committee
appears to have acquiesced in an easing it had not initiated,
after misleading the public that it had kept monetary policy unchanged
when it took its monthly decision last Thursday. Allowing the
Treasury to initiate monetary policy suggests the MPC has lost
the plot; it certainly does not know how to communicate changes
in monetary policy any more.[104]
59. When questioned about this possible infringement
of the MPC's independence, the Governor said that the transfer
did not cause concern for him as it was within the MPC's power
to negate its effects.[105]
Dr Martin Weale and Dr Ben Broadbent, both members of the MPC,
likewise did not feel that HM Treasury's decision affected their
capacity to reach independent decisions about monetary policy.[106]
Indeed, they both noted that they had in fact been minded to support
further QE, but on being informed of the APF surplus transfer
had decided there was therefore no need for further QE.[107]
Yet Mr Wells argued that the way the decision was communicated
was also important:
I think it was communicated rather clumsily. I think
it should have been thought of well in advance of when it was
done, because it could have perhaps been announced during a Bank
of England inflation report and explained very clearly. As it
was, the day after quite a big policy announcement, suddenly being
announced and then the MPC saying, "Oh well, if we had wanted
to offset it, we knew it was coming; we could have changed",
I think was slightly unsatisfactory.[108]
60. The Governor acknowledged that the perception
of the MPC's independence was important in its own right:
it is very important that we go beyond [independence]
and ensure that not only is our independence not compromised,
which I think is the case, but has not been seen to be compromised.
That also matters [
][109]
But when we questioned the MPC on why it had not
published any announcement on the APF at the time of the 8 November
press release, the Governor argued that it was not in the MPC's
gift to publicise the transfer.[110]
The Governor conceded that, in relation to the timing of the announcements,
"I think it is unfortunate if people were misled, and I think
that is a matter for regret".[111]
61. The perceived independence
of the MPC is of paramount importance for the effective execution
of its duties. We acknowledge that the MPC had the opportunity
at its November meeting to take steps to negate the impact on
monetary conditions of the APF transfer. The MPC's actual independence
was therefore not threatened. But by not announcing the monetary
easing that arose from the APF transfer to the Treasury at the
time of its regular November press release, the MPC gave the impression
that the Treasury was undertaking monetary policy, rather than
the MPC.
62. The MPC needed to be in
a position to publicise the transfer at the time of its press
release in order to fulfil its duty to act transparently and to
demonstrate its independence. Had the MPC decided that it needed
to negate the effect of the APF transfer by reducing QE, it would
have had to reveal the APF transfer in order to be able to explain
its decision. Deciding not to cancel out the effect of the APF
transfer was also a decision that the MPC took which deserved
public explanation, especially as we know that the transfer influenced
MPC members' decision-making. The Bank of England should, therefore,
have ensured that the MPC was in a position to make the fact of
the APF transfer public at the time of the publication of its
November press release. A satisfactory alternative would have
been for the Treasury to have announced the transfer at the same
time as, or before, the release of the MPC's minutes. The Treasury
and to some extent the Bank were at fault for failing to coordinate
the announcement of the APF transfer with that of the November
MPC press release, the date of which was known well in advance.
This failure created difficulties for the reputation of the MPC.
This should not be repeated.
79 Office for Budget Responsibility, Economic and
fiscal outlook, December 2012, p 173 Back
80
Office for Budget Responsibility, Economic and fiscal outlook,
December 2012, p 18 Back
81
Office for Budget Responsibility, Economic and fiscal outlook,
December 2012, p 18 Back
82
Q 290 Back
83
Q 311 Back
84
HM Treasury, Autumn Statement 2012, 5 December 2012, p
31 Back
85
Q 141 Back
86
Qq 145, 151 Back
87
Q 145 Back
88
Qq 152, 200 Back
89
Q 142 Back
90
Speech by Chief Secretary to the Treasury, Rt Hon Danny Alexander
MP; Glasgow Chambers of Commerce, 21 June 2012 Back
91
Q 322 Back
92
Q 144 Back
93
Oral evidence to the Treasury Committee, National Institute of
Economic and Social Research Quarterly Review, October 2012, Q
13 Back
94
Oral evidence to the Treasury Committee, National Institute of
Economic and Social Research Quarterly Review, October 2012, Q
44 Back
95
Q 159 Back
96
Q 159 Back
97
Q 91 Back
98
Oral evidence to the Treasury Committee, Bank of England November
2012 Inflation Report, HC 767, Q 66 Back
99
Office for Budget Responsibility, Economic and fiscal outlook,
December 2012, p 15 Back
100
Oral evidence to the Treasury Committee, Bank of England November
2012 Inflation Report, HC 767, Q 39 Back
101
Bank of England, Press release: Bank of England maintains Bank
Rate at 0.5% and the size of the Asset Purchase Programme at £375
billion, 8 November 2012 Back
102
Oral evidence to the Treasury Committee, Bank of England November
2012 Inflation Report, HC 767, Q 45 Back
103
Letter from the Chancellor to the Governor, HM Treasury website
9 November 2012; letter from the Governor to the Chancellor, Bank
of England website, 9 November 2012 Back
104
Financial Times, Policy ploys risk UK economic credibility, by
Chris Giles, 14 November 2012 Back
105
Oral evidence to the Treasury Committee, Bank of England November
2012 Inflation Report, HC 767, Q 39 Back
106
Oral evidence to the Treasury Committee, Bank of England November
2012 Inflation Report, HC 767, Qq 74, 75 Back
107
Oral evidence to the Treasury Committee, Bank of England November
2012 Inflation Report, HC 767, Qq 74, 76 Back
108
Q 131 Back
109
Oral evidence to the Treasury Committee, Bank of England November
2012 Inflation Report, HC 767, Q 97 Back
110
Oral evidence to the Treasury Committee, Bank of England November
2012 Inflation Report, HC 767, Q 46 Back
111
Oral evidence to the Treasury Committee, Bank of England November
2012 Inflation Report, HC 767, Q 71 Back
|