Smart meter roll-out - Energy and Climate Change Contents


9  Annex- Summary notes from committee visit

Summary note of the working dinner hosted by PG&E

Tuesday 19 March

MEMBERS PRESENT:

Mr Tim Yeo (Chair)
Dr Phillip Lee
Albert Owen   
John Robertson
Sir Robert Smith
Dr Alan Whitehead

PG&E REPRESENTATIVES PRESENT:

Cliff Gleicher, Senior Director, smart meter programme
Brian Rich, Vice President PG&E
James Meadows, Director, smart meter programme

INTRODUCTION

Mr Tim Yeo made an opening speech regarding the Committee's inquiry into a smart meter roll-out in the UK and the possibility of learning from the experience in California. Some of the differences between the UK and California were noted—for example that PG&E does not have pre-pay meters. Committee members enquired about policies focused on the use of gas and PG&E stated that there is no advance pricing on gas meters; instead, a reading is given every hour so that computers can calculate the billing.

PG&E ROLL-OUT AND BARRIERS TO ROLL-OUT

PG&E outlined that California's policy discussions about a smart meter roll-out started approximately 10 years ago. Approximately six years ago (from November 2006), PG&E had begun installing smart meters, and roll-out was now 96% complete. With opt-outs (initiated in 2012), the number of meters accounted for was 50,000 higher as of March 2013.

Much time and effort had been spent addressing issues that had not been anticipated. Several cities had attempted to ban smart meters through local measures, but this was unlawful because the State had ruled to implement smart metering. Early on there had been concerns about smart meter accuracy, but PG&E said that many complaints about overcharging had been found to be due to a broken pool pump or other source of high electricity consumption that the customer did not know about and that the smart meter had helped them find. In some cases when customers had thought that their smart meter was overcharging, PG&E suggested that in fact their previous, older analogue meter had slowed due to weather and had become inaccurate and had undercharged them, and that was why their bills were now higher. Very few customers had raised concerns about privacy, which was heavily regulated in California.

HEALTH CONCERNS

The main issue of concern for some consumers, and the most publicised subject of discussion in California, had been around radio frequency (RF) and electro-sensitivity. PG&E reported that scientists believed that although people who claimed to be electro-sensitive genuinely experienced symptoms, those symptoms had not been found to be attributable to RF or smart meters. It was also noted that many of those who protested against smart meters used cell phones and microwaves. PG&E did not know of any credible evidence linking smart meters to any of the claimed health effects.

PG&E had retained scientists formerly or presently with the International Commission on Non-Ionizing Radiation Protection (ICNIRP), the World Health Organisation (WHO), and the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) to advise it and report on RF and the claimed adverse effects associated with smart meters. In addition, it noted that the FCC and the California Council on Science and Technology (CCST) had found that current standards were well under the limits known to cause thermal effects, and the CCST reported that studies had not confirmed any negative health effects from non-thermal sources. However, opponents argued that it would be at least 10 years before any non-thermal effects were known.

CONSUMER BACKLASH AND THE OPT-OUT APPROACH

A consumer backlash against smart meters had not been anticipated. Benchmarking reflected that sending a letter or leaving a door hanger on people's doors would be sufficient advance information about smart meter installation, but this had turned out not to be the case for some customers. In some parts of California, localities imposed ordinances against the installation of smart meters. In one small town, it had been suggested that PG&E staff attempting to install smart meters should be arrested. This revealed the intensity of certain viewpoints.

In November 2011, PG&E had responded to some customers' concerns by proposing that customers be permitted to opt out, with those opt-out customers paying the overall costs of opting out. PG&E proposed to enable customers to opt out of having a smart meter by paying a one-time charge of $270 and a monthly charge of $14, but this had not been accepted by the regulator (the CPUC) which had reduced the one-time charge to $75 and had introduced a lower monthly charge of $10. Low-income customers paid a $10 one-off charge and $5 per month. This system had been implemented in February 2012.

Other jurisdictions in the United States have taken a different approach: in Naperville, mid-west Chicago, police had accompanied smart meter installers on installation visits and people had been arrested for interfering with smart meter installation. Some utilities had said that they were not going to have an opt-out programme, but then experienced similar issues and chose to offer an opt-out alternative.

When asked whether PG&E could have refused to supply electricity to homes that would not agree to have a smart meter, PG&E advised that its tariffs allowed for that, but that it would not have been good customer relations. It reported that the regulator was examining whether whole communities should be allowed to opt out.

For people whose meters repeatedly were not accessible when a meter installer visited their home to install a smart meter, PG&E had the ability to invoice the bill payer for the opt-out charge. That way the customers ultimately had to decide either to pay the opt-out fee or have a smart meter. If people failed to pay the invoice charge, they could be disconnected. Prior to opt-out, for customers who were uncertain about smart meter installation, PG&E had kept a 'delay list' and had come back to them after meters had been installed in properties where there was no objection. Once these customers had found out about the opt-out charges, many of them had ended up accepting a smart meter after all.

There were many anti-electromagnetic field (EMF) organisations in the US, with many in northern California, southern California, Texas and the north-east (including Maine and Chicago), but there were few such places in-between. Interestingly, the areas that PG&E had expected to be most pro-smart meter—liberal urban environments—also had many anti-smart meter customers.

PG&E felt that the tide was now turning with public opinion regarding smart meters being higher due to the introduction of the opt-out system, which had given customers a choice that they had not previously had. There has been much less change among those who had opted out, and some of those people still were not satisfied with the opt-out system because they did not want their neighbours to have smart meters either. Overall, about 35,000 of PG&E's customers had opted out of having a smart meter—less than 1% of its 5 million electricity customers.

THE PRACTICALITIES AND COST OF ROLL-OUT

A street-by-street roll-out approach had been adopted by PG&E, which was the sole electricity supplier in its area. This approach had also been followed to some extent with gas meters, but these were more difficult to install and so some of these installations remained outstanding. On the whole, there had not been too many difficulties with gaining access to meters as most of them were on the outside of the property, but there had been an occasional locked gate or basement to access. In one day, more than 18,000 smart meters had been installed in an urban area. It had been reported that one workman could install 30 to 40 per day. However, this was less feasible in rural areas. Replacing old meters with smart meters was not always simple due to the complexity of having different meters to replace. PG&E had trained its own staff and contractors, who had different levels of expertise to address different installation types.

It was less expensive to read smart meters remotely than to read meters manually, and the cost per meter of manual meter reading had increased now that those meters were less common and therefore further apart.

CONSUMER BENEFIT

Committee members commented that consumer benefit was a central focus of roll-out in the UK and asked what benefits were being realised by consumers in California. PG&E's initial focus in its business case had been about reducing operational costs, particularly from discontinuing manually reading meters. Reductions in operational costs contributed, as did other efficiency enhancements, to maintaining affordable rates. PG&E was also looking at consumer benefit. The idea was that the savings from smart meters would be passed on to consumers and that consumers would have the benefit of being able to view their energy use information to inform their choosing new rate plans to save money. PG&E is now piloting the installation of in-home displays (IHDs), which all its smart meters had the capability to communicate with.

PG&E supported a move towards customers using the internet to check their usage. Some 45% of PG&E customers now had an online "My Account." PG&E also used print mailers with energy efficiency tips and mobile phone SMS energy alerts. For example, customers could be sent an energy alert by text to let them know when their usage had reached a certain pre-agreed level or when their usage was moving them into a new pricing tier. These communication methods were also useful for informing customers about outages and when these were being dealt with. Before smart meters, companies had needed customers to report outages, but now smart meters let them know when there was a problem. Smart meters also had the ability to receive signals to: generate a usage profile; provide a current analysis and progressive analysis; and implement smart usage of devices.

PG&E was interested in enabling people to put their usage information into a system which then told them which of PG&E's approximately 170 tariffs would be best for them. Committee members commented that the number of tariffs available in the UK was being reduced because having a large number of tariffs had not been found to increase competition. PG&E suggested that the rate analysis option that could be offered with the information gleaned from smart meters would give consumers the best tariff based on behavioural use.

TIME-OF-USE TARIFFS AND DEMAND RESPONSE BENEFITS

PG&E emphasised the potential green benefits of smart meters in reducing consumption. More aggressive pricing led to better demand response. For example, a critical peak pricing shift from 40 cents per kWh to $1 per kWh encouraged commercial customers in particular to alter their usage. Some 80,000 domestic PG&E customers had opted into a critical peak-pricing tariff and 400,000 PG&E customers overall, including commercial customers, were on time-of-use tariffs. PG&E had also introduced a programme under which customers' air-conditioning units could be cycled on and off to smooth out demand during periods of peak demand.

Committee members asked about inclining block tariffs, which had been legislated for in California. When asked whether smart technology was used to send signals to electric vehicle charging points, saying when was the best time to charge, PG&E reported that the capacity to do this was there but it was not currently used. More information was needed about how many cars were near to a transformer.

SMART GRID

PG&E has been beginning to integrate smart meters into smart grids. So far, this has been used for remote billing, remote meter reading, and remote connection when a customer moved house or disconnection when bills were not paid. Smart meters allowed PG&E to collect more granular data, which helped with demand planning for gas and electricity.

The smart grid allowed for the remote use of switches to diagnose and fix problems. However, as yet there was no data interchange between smart meters and substations. PG&E described "incredible outage benefits", and also reported that the revenue theft network monitoring possibilities were excellent. There were three high-powered transmission grids across the state, balanced through an independent system operator which utilities sold to and bought back from. Utilities had to do wholesale and retail load forecasting, and smart meters made this easier. Smart meters also had advantages for self-generators, including the 60,000 solar customers who were able to export the energy they generated to the grid more easily. For this purpose, net metering as opposed to feed-in tariffs were used, which enabled forecasting of the net contribution of a household to the grid.

CONCLUSION

PG&E representatives agreed that customer communication was key and that PG&E had not anticipated that when it started its smart meter programme. If it was beginning a roll-out now, PG&E would focus on communications, particularly to help customers to better understand smart meter benefits early on. Holding meetings with electors, city halls and other stakeholders was a good way of promoting such communication.

Summary note of the Committee's meeting with the California Energy Commission (CEC)

Wednesday 20 March 2013

MEMBERS PRESENT:   

Mr Tim Yeo (Chair)
Dr Phillip Lee
Albert Owen
John Robertson
Sir Robert Smith
Dr Alan Whitehead

CEC REPRESENTATIVES PRESENT:

Drew Bohan, Chief Deputy Director, Office of the Executive Director
Kevin Barker, Advisor to Chairman Robert Weisenmiller
David Ashuckian, Deputy Director, Efficiency and Renewable Energy Division
Roger Johnson, Deputy Director, Siting, Transmission and Environmental Protection Division
Mike Gravely, Manager Energy Systems Research Office, Energy Research and Development Division
Ivin Rhyne, Manager, Energy Systems Research Office, Electricity Supply and Analysis Division

INTRODUCTION

The Chair of the Committee, Mr Yeo, explained that the Committee was conducting an inquiry into smart meter roll-out in the UK and was therefore interested in California's smart metering experience, and also outlined Committee's wider interest in energy efficiency.

Drew Bohan, Chief Deputy Director, Office of the Executive Director, gave an overview of utilities in California, with three investor-owned utilities and about 40 public/municipal utilities. He also outlined the CEC's role, including its responsibilities for granting licences for solar developments.

SMART METER ROLL-OUT IN CALIFORNIA

CEC representatives explained that smart meter roll-out was nearly complete for the domestic sector in California, and that roll-out for the industrial sector had been completed 10 years ago. The Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory (LBNL) was doing research on how well smart meters had been accepted.

PUBLIC CONCERNS ABOUT ACCURACY AND CHARGING

There had been problems in one particular area—the Bakersfield Revolt—when consumers' bills had gone up and people had thought they were being charged more by smart meters.

David Ashuckian had worked with the Division of Ratepayer Advocates when he had worked at the California Public Utilities Commission (CPUC). He explained that the first smart meter roll-out in Bakersfield had coincided with a rate rise but people had not realised and so had blamed smart meters for their increased bills. There had also been complaints about accuracy, but some utilities had responded that smart meters were more accurate than the old analogue meters, some of which must have been inaccurate, and that this accounted for any apparent change in consumption levels. However, the DRA and CPUC had heard about some cases of inaccuracy, with about 100 meters transferring erroneous information to suppliers. In one case, a farmer had had a meter on a pump, which had not been turned on but for which he had received a bill for thousands of dollars. It turned out that smart meter accuracy could fluctuate slightly above or below the actual reading, and because this meter had not gone above nought, a fluctuation to slightly below the actual reading had resulted in a false reading of minus 1, but this had been expressed as 999 kwH, instead of minus 1 and so a large bill had been generated as a result.

Dynamic and tiered rates were relevant because they could cause bills to go up. There was therefore a perception that smart meters would cause higher tariffs and it was a substantial public image challenge to address this. The Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory had done some research in this area. On the whole, opposition to smart meters in California opposition seemed small and was based on misperceptions.

PUBLIC CONCERNS ABOUT HEALTH

There had been some public concerns about health impacts, similar to those about cell phones, due to the two-way communications system. However, no convincing evidence had been found to support those concerns. Some public utilities took a more proactive approach and this was thought to be an issue primarily of education.

COMMUNICATIONS AND CONSUMPTION DATA

Smart meters in California used ZigBee Smart Energy Profile (SEP) wireless technology, rather than WiFi, and there had been some throughput issues. The transfer of information had been so great that the system had not been prepared for it.

Smart meters could be used to give consumers a good analysis of their consumption data to show their habits and how they could reduce their consumption. There had been much more public outreach of this sort among non-investor-owned utilities such as the Sacramento Municipal Utilities District (SMUD), whose customers had received smart meters much positively as a result of better provision of information from SMUD.

It was a challenge to sort through all the data that came from smart meters in a useful way and some utilities had been struggling with this. Consumers could use a green button on energy company websites to release their data to any third party offering to help them reduce their energy demand.[295] Other challenges with smart meters included: developing products that would be of use to consumers; managing the standard of communications and how open should this be; and addressing privacy issues.

PUBLIC CONCERNS ABOUT PRIVACY

There had not been much concern among consumers about data privacy. There was good data encryption with smart meters, but most meters had not had the home area network (HAN) capability initiated anyway because consumers did not have in-home displays (IHDs).

OPT-OUT

Before the opt-out had been introduced, about 200 customers at a time would parade in front of utilities protesting about smart meters.

BEST PRACTICE FOR ROLL-OUT

Other companies or areas commencing roll-out would be well advised to:

  • give consumers sufficient information about smart meters and the practicalities of roll-out, explaining potential benefits and addressing potential concerns.
  • use local groups, the company website, customer relations staff and correspondence to communicate with customers about roll-out and how to benefit from smart meters.
  • phase in dynamic rates and use an opt-in system for critical peak pricing.
  • ensure that privacy is protected and that data is secure.
  • ensure the technology is robust and interoperable through testing and that it can be updated remotely as far as possible.
  • be proactive about avoiding some of the pitfalls that have occurred elsewhere.

SMART GRIDS

Committee members asked whether there was potential for the smart grid to help reduce demand among heavy users and whether there was a need for new generating capacity for peak supply.

CEC representatives explained that while California was a world leader on energy efficiency, it was not as advanced when it came to demand response. It would be helpful to use the smart grid to shave off use at peak load times, but this was complicated operationally. Shaving peaks would not obviate the need for new power stations, but would allow existing plant to operate more efficiently and enable better distribution.

Electricity demand in California peaks in the summer and troughed in winter. Many consumers managed their energy well. However, some people wanted greater use of solar energy and electric cars, which would make demand response even more important in managing peaks. The technology required for greater use of electric cars existed already, but the grid was not currently capable of managing the demand that would be created.

On demand response, more had been done with flexible demand than with day-ahead demand. The CEC had been working with the military to help them achieve their emission reduction targets. The smart grid in itself did not achieve aims in relation to energy consumption, but it was a tool to help increase efficiency. Currently, about half of meters' capability to interact with smart technologies had not been used and the utilities had not initiated this functionality.

The concept that energy flowed one way to the end user was changing. Solar PV was being used more widely but this created new problems in smart grids with real-time information flow and interconnection.

ENERGY STORAGE

There was more interest than ever at investor, state and national level in energy storage. Following the passage in California of AB2514, the Energy Storage Bill, research was being done on whether batteries could be put into homes to store energy and whether local networks could work in this way.

Home storage and distribution systems were being implemented as part of micro grid. Systems were now entering the 5-10 MW range. Such systems were very versatile but cost was a big factor. Demand response offered a fast change and efforts were being made to use storage facilities to offer fast response as well. However, this solution was more expensive and so different technologies were being explored.

ENERGY EFFICIENCY

Legal and policy interventions

Various legal and policy interventions to increase energy efficiency in California were in place, including:

  • Executive Order S-20-04, signed on 14 December 2004, which required State of California buildings to be graded LEED (Leadership in Energy and Environmental Design) silver or better.
  • The Global Warming Solutions Act 2006, which introduced a target to reduce greenhouse gas emissions to 1990 levels by 2020.
  • The 2009 California Scoping plan, under which homes had to be zero net energy by 2020, State of California buildings had to be zero net energy by 2025 and commercial buildings had to be zero net energy by 2030.
  • The loading order for electricity resources, under which energy efficiency and demand response came first, new generation from renewable energy and distributed generation resources came second, and clean fossil-fuelled generation and transmission infrastructure improvements came afterwards.

On demand response, things were not really there yet. There was a desire to be able to cycle people's freezers off for short periods on peak days. However, demand response solutions would not necessarily mean that new power plants did not have to be built.

Energy efficiency drivers

Energy efficiency drivers included greenhouse gas targets. Regulation, rather than a market-led approach had been key to increasing energy efficiency. Regulations had saved California $74 billion in energy savings, and California's per capita energy consumption had been flat for the past 30 years whereas the national average has increased—this was thought to be mainly due to energy efficiency savings. Before new regulations were implemented, it had to be shown that their aims could be achieved cost-effectively, so there was a strong link to available technology.

Regulations on energy efficiency in appliances

Appliance efficiency regulations usually related to performance, but sometimes applied to design. Without such regulations, many manufacturers would not have been producing goods that achieved energy efficiency aims. TVs had been made more efficient as a result of regulations—for example, by reducing the number of diodes—and this had had quite an effect given the number of TVs now in use.

California's use of regulation did not conflict with the market. Regulation created a level playing field for competitors and set parameters. Many Californian standards had been taken up in other states and the Californian economy had continued to flourish. This was because regulations applied to products being sold in California, not just to those manufactured there (it did not have a large manufacturing base), so manufacturers elsewhere made products to meet those regulations and sold the same products elsewhere as well. Making a product more efficient did not necessarily use any more energy during manufacturing, but the energy efficiency gains are large.

Building regulations on energy efficiency

Building energy efficiency standards had first been adopted in 1978 and were updated every three years. These standards were developed in an open, public process involving regulated industry, utilities and other stakeholders. Examples included requirements regarding heating and cooling, lighting, roofing and water heating.

Under the 2009 California Scoping plan, homes had to be zero net energy by 2020, State of California buildings had to be zero net energy by 2025, and commercial buildings had to be zero net energy by 2030. This meant that buildings would have to have a solar panel or other renewable energy source on site to ensure they achieved zero net energy over the year.

Renewable targets

There was a regulation on utilities to meet 33% of their load requirements through renewable by 2020. This target did not include large hydro power, which was considered to be environmentally damaging. Negotiations for 6,000 MW of combined heat and power were ongoing and there was a moratorium on new nuclear power stations.

Members of the Committee asked whether consumers were concerned about the renewables targets, particularly in relation to cost. CEC representatives explained that this was not the case yet, although utilities had started to say that the smart grid would cost consumers more.

The stringent air quality standards in California meant that oil-powered stations could not be used. Under the Renewable Portfolio Standard (RPS), power from plants outside California also had to meet the same standards. California had the most aggressive renewable targets in the US.

There was no official state policy on energy independence, but discussions were ongoing about increasing the renewables standard and having a 50-80 % emissions cut by 2050 which might bring about de facto independence.

Summary note of the Committee's meeting with the Sacramento Municipal Utilities District (SMUD)

Wednesday 20 March 2013

Members present:

Mr Tim Yeo (Chair)   
Dr Phillip Lee   
Albert Owen
John Robertson
Sir Robert Smith
Dr Alan Whitehead

CEC representatives present:

Jim Parks, Programme Manager, Smart Grid
Anita Clay, Economic Development and Partnerships

Introduction

Jim Parks, Programme Manager, Smart Grid gave some brief background about SMUD, which he said served an area of 900 sq miles with a population of 1.4 million and had 600,000 customers. It was the second-largest municipal utility in California and the 6th-largest in the US. SMUD provided only electricity (no gas or water) and had a peak load of 3,299 MW.

Mr Parks explained that SMUD had a monopoly in the area that it served but that its prices were 26% cheaper than those of local investor-owned utilities, so SMUD customers did not mind the monopoly. It received about $1.4 billion in revenues in 2011, but was a not-for-profit organisation so revenues were reinvested. It had an elected board of directors and therefore was not regulated by an external body as the investor-owned utilities were by the California Public Utilities Commission (CPUC). Anyone except SMUD employees could stand for election to the board.

Emission reduction aims

SMUD had set itself the ambitious target of reducing greenhouse gas emissions by 90% from 1990 levels by 2050. This was more ambitious than the state goal of achieving an 80% reduction by 2050. Its projected resource mix for achieving this included hydro, natural gas generation (until 2037), energy efficiency measures and renewable. However, these projections showed an energy gap starting in 2019 and widening out to about 8,000 GWh a year by 2050; SMUD did not currently know how it was going to fill this gap if it was to achieve its 90% reduction target.

Smart grid vision

Mr Parks presented SMUD's smart grid vision, which included a microgrid and local energy production and storage facilities. One source of local energy in the vision was the "poop to power" biogas digesters that would use cow manure to generate electricity. SMUD had also considered using fat, oils and grease (FOG) to generate electricity at one of the dairy digesters, but had rejected this idea because of air quality issues. FOG has been used on other generation projects. Residential homes in the vision had smart meters, home area networks (HANs), smart appliances and electric vehicles. Commercial buildings had energy management systems and their car parks had electric vehicle charging stations.

In October 2009, SMUD had received $127.5 million of Department of Energy Smart Grid Investment Grant (SGIG) money towards its $308 million smart grid project. This grant made up 65% of the $203 million SGIG money that went to California.

Smart meter roll-out

SMUD had now completed its roll-out of smart meters, having installed more than 620,000 smart meters. It had started its roll-out in rural areas and dense urban areas, but had halted its programme after 60,000 installations when PG&E had started having problems with customer refusal. At this point, SMUD had rethought its approach, trained staff to give presentations on smart meters and gone to local government and city council members to solicit support. Before recommencing roll-out, SMUD had embarked on a large consumer engagement campaign, telling people about smart meters and getting local city councillors involved. The fact that SMUD was community owned may have helped with consumer trust. PG&E has made some blunders over the years and so trust levels had been low before roll-out. However, if it had done more community engagement that would have helped significantly.

During roll-out there had been some concerns among consumers about privacy and the effect of electromagnetic frequencies on health. Customers had been given the option of postponing having a smart meter installed and initially 2,500 had done this. These had been moved to the end of the programme and many of them had eventually had smart meters installed when they had seen them elsewhere. There had been a small but vocal minority linked to nosmartmeters.org, who had particular concerns about health, including a man who said he had got throat cancer a month after getting a smart meter.

Opt-out

By the end of roll-out, 313 customers (0.05%) had decided to opt out of having a smart meter and most of these had a smart meter with the smart functionality switched off. However, 54 customers had refused this option and wanted an old analogue meter. SMUD was going to let them do this because of their persistence in regularly speaking up at board meetings.

Opt-out programmes were costly but were still subsidised by other customers. SMUD customers opting out had initially been charged an up-front fee of $127 and a monthly fee of $39.40. However, SMUD had since moved to quarterly rather than monthly meter reading for non-smart meters and this had allowed it to reduce the monthly fee to $14. In contrast, the fees that investor-owned utilities were able to charge had been set by the regulator, the CPUC, at $75 up-front and $10 a month. However, SDG&E and SCE had requested the ability to charge higher fees and the CPUC was expected to rule on this in April 2013.

Communications strategy

SMUD's advice to another utility rolling out smart meters would be to do as much communications as possible in advance, to have a communications strategy and to use local forums for communicating with the public. Its communications strategy had included:

  • discussions with customers long before the first meters were installed
  • focus groups with customers
  • web information about roll-out, including an interactive meter installation map
  • regular public committee and board meetings
  • more than 200 community presentations
  • direct communication with customers.

Smart meter and smart grid usage

SMUD took hourly reads from smart meters, and customers could access their consumption data online the next day. They benefited from having secure online access to daily and hourly energy usage information, faster reconnection upon moving house, shorter outage periods and from having in-home displays and time-based tariffs. Customers could also receive messages by email, SMS or a message on their thermostat to let them know when they had reached a certain point in their consumption, eg $75. Large differentials in off-peak and on-peak pricing (eg 7.5 cents to 75 cents per kWh) would be likely to bring about behaviour change.

Under the current tariff structure, higher users were subsidising lower users because of the step up from one tier to the next. Time-of-use (ToU) tariffs and critical peak pricing were being tested with 8,000 customers. It was likely that they would be mandatory in future as customers would be expected to reduce their consumption. SMUD's current rate process proposes mandatory ToU tariffs for all residential customers beginning in 2018.

SMUD had an automated demand response (ADR) system in use in buildings in which loads exceed 300 kW. One plant could be shut down completely on peak days. Another way of achieving load reductions was by cycling residential air-conditioning units on and off, or by raising the temperature on the thermostat. SMUD had been reluctant to use the air-conditioning cycling system since a problem when a member of staff not used to operating the system had turned off 100,000 residential air conditioners for four hours instead of cycling it every 15 minutes. This was on a hot day after a series of hot days and many residents did not want to continue being signed up to the air-con cycling programme after that.

Comparison between consumer-owned and investor-owned utilities

California had three investor-owned utilities and about 40 municipals. Mr Parks thought that consumer-owned utilities had a greater incentive than investor-owned utilities to encourage consumers to reduce their usage, as it was in their interests to benefit consumers.

Consumer-owned utilities were not regulated externally as investor-owned utilities were by the CPUC because they had an elected board of directors who were accountable to local residents.

Summary note of the working lunch with Senators at State Capitol

Wednesday 20 March

MEMBERS PRESENT:   

Mr Tim Yeo (Chair)
Dr Phillip Lee   
Albert Owen
John Robertson
Sir Robert Smith
Dr Alan Whitehead

SENATE REPRESENTATIVES PRESENT:

Senator Jean Fuller
Senator Carol Liu
Senator Kevin de León
Rachel Wagoner, Chief Consultant, Senate Committee on Environmental Quality
Henry Stern, Principal Consultant to Senator Pavley
Melinda Pickerel, Senate Office of International Relations
Kellie Smith, Principal Consultant, Senate Standing Committee on Energy, Utilities and Communications

INTRODUCTION

Senator Fuller reported that the smart meter installation had suffered from poor timing, as roll-out had begun in August when prices were high due to the hot weather. Senator Liu stated that consumer education was key to a successful campaign. The senators agreed that there was a political need to find the 'urban adopters', so that if there were a mishap the programme might still be salvaged.

The Chair Tim Yeo suggested that SMUD (Sacramento Municipal Utility District) was ambitious in its greenhouse gas reduction targets and enquired whether the senators had experienced any consumer resistance to such ambition. Senator de León confirmed that in the US there was also resistance and controversy generated by price rises and the subsidisation of industry. Senator de León described a 'tipping point' when price becomes an issue. The subsidy comes from government, and while those with the affluence to install solar PV do so, those on a lower income scale might not benefit. There might be a 'price point shock' for the consumer, who might not understand the wider, more abstract discussion of energy policies. A central concern was ensuring consumer support for policies.

John Robertson enquired how the senators had responded to complaints from constituents who were struggling with higher bill costs. Senator de León highlighted that constituents' primary concerns related to public safety, crime and education issues, particularly for the lower income strata of the public. Senator Liu reported that the government had used the income from utility companies to supplement general budgets.

John Robertson enquired what measures were being taken to assist vulnerable people, since it was often the case that little help was available and there might be a risk of disconnection. Senator Liu stated that there was a care programme available. John Robertson reported that the main problem was lack of understanding on the part of consumers. Senator Fuller responded that in general, lower-income consumers did not make complaints; additionally, if income was below a certain amount then a reduced rate was payable. The senators stated that taxes levied in the State responsibility area could be very unpopular, with a number of constituents having written letters to object. For Senator Fuller's counties, which covered a very large area, there was a rule service fee in place. Occasionally there were disconnections, and in this case, NGOs were available to assist people on a one-off basis. Water was a different issue: rates were rising and people are concerned by the 30% rise. The rate was increasing due to the need for infrastructure improvements, and the lack of a good water base.

John Robertson enquired whether smart meters had made a difference. Senator Fuller stated that currently it was too early to tell - some people were still concerned and others were less interested, since they were already aware of when peak times were. Senator Liu pointed out that SMUD provided a comparison between current use and the previous year's use, which was very instructive.

Albert Owen enquired how Senators had responded to health concerns about smart meters. Senator Liu highlighted that opponents were in a small but very vocal minority. It was agreed that there would always be individuals who objected and that the situation was easier now with the opt-out tariff in place. It was stated that press coverage of smart meters had focussed on the cost spike that accompanied their introduction, rather than the health issues. Coverage has also been limited to local rather than national press.

Senator Liu explained that there had been an agreement between the Public Utilities Commission (PUC, the regulator) and the utility companies to carry out smart meter roll-out. Dr Alan Whitehead enquired whether the company benefits involved had come to the fore of public debate on smart metering. In fact, it was reported that the focus had been more on job losses caused by operational cost savings, such as the laying off of smart meter readers in some cases. SMUD, for example, had been obliged to lay off staff. Senator Liu stated that companies might have saved money, which might not have been passed on to consumers as yet. It was agreed that lower-income customers were not so vocal on the need for consumer savings, but that those in the higher economic strata were vocal on this point. Senator de León stated that questions remained about the cost savings for rate payers and the relationship between the regulator and the state.

It was confirmed that the state goal was to be more energy efficient and address climate change through a formal proceeding of consultation which addressed cost and other issues. Regulators were much more powerful in the US, since they determined how much money a company could make. Dr Phillip Lee asked why the municipal utility companies had not taken over, given that the rates they offered could be much lower. Senator Liu reported that the municipals would have to raise their rates in time, and informed Members that the territories were determined by history. PG&E and SMUD had established their jurisdictions over time; SMUD would have to buy out the investor-owned utility if it wished to expand its customer base - a past attempt had failed due to the extensive litigation required and the lack of public support. PG&E had mounted a scare campaign warning of massive costs to existing SMUD customers, were SMUD to expand.

It was reported that gas prices were continuing to rise in California, despite the discovery of shale gas in the US. Senators stated that approximately 80 % of gas was imported, with oil deliveries to the Los Angeles and Long Beach ports, through two pipelines out of the Arizona area. Senators observed that shale gas would not affect prices if it could not enter the state.

In fact, California was more likely to gas price reductions from over-supply in states such as Alaska, for example. Senator Fuller explained that in California, development occurs very slowly due to extensive regulations. Nobody wanted a transmission line, or other piece of infrastructure, in their back yard although everyone wants the energy product. For example, the Monterrey coastline was very beautiful, and the public did not want to see interventions in this area. Dr Phillip Lee asked whether there were any concerns over the possibility of inducing earthquakes with fracking, due to the fault line. In Senator Fuller's area, this was not considered an issue, as oil had been pumped in the region for decades. By contrast, in North Dakota for example fracking was different, due to different conditions. There was some concern, but the main fear was that the aquifer could become polluted. Senator de León pointed out that the Los Angeles basin could have the richest in the world but regulations were too strict to explore the possibility. The Senators also pointed out that currently the State was grappling with the renewable portfolio; if fracking were to begin then this portfolio would not be fulfilled, and more ambitious goals for cap and trade and energy efficiency would not be reached. The key issue was how to soften the blow regarding increasing energy prices.

Chair, Tim Yeo, highlighted that in California, large-scale solar projects were decided centrally, unlike in the UK. The Chair asked whether there was any resentment or sense of disenfranchisement as a result. Senator Fuller explained that many planning regulations were already in place, which ensured that people could make themselves heard. Where there were acres of empty space, the State could exploit these areas first which tended to be less controversial. John Robertson pointed out that the Scottish mountains could be considered a desert equivalent, however after 14 years the required upgrade and transmission lines were still not in place.

Chair, Tim Yeo, enquired about the progress of the planned high speed railway across California, linking San Diego with San Francisco and Sacramento. Senator Liu explained that this was highly controversial due to the high costs involved and the perception that the rail would not in fact be fast enough to be termed "high speed".

Albert Owen raised the subject of opposition to nuclear power in the State. Senator Liu stated that there were mixed opinions on the subject, however there was currently no political would for nuclear new build. In addition, the US had not yet developed reprocessing of nuclear fuel. However, the general consensus was that alternative sources of energy were needed, such as the solar towers which Senators observed during a recent visit to Spain.

Summary note of the meeting with representatives of the Senate Committee on Utilities and Commerce

Wednesday 20 March 2013

Members present:

Mr Tim Yeo (Chair)
Dr Phillip Lee   
Albert Owen
John Robertson
Sir Robert Smith
Dr Alan Whitehead

Assembly representatives present:

Assembly Member Steven Bradford, Chair of the Assembly Committee on Utilities and Commerce
Sue Kateley, Chief Committee Consultant for the California State Assembly Committee on Utilities and Commerce
Davina T Flemings, Principal Consultant, Assembly Committee on Utilities and Commerce

Introduction

Mr Steven Bradford, Chair of the Assembly Committee on Utilities and Commerce, welcomed the Committee to California and gave an overview of the work of the Assembly Committee, particularly in relation to smart meters

Sue Kateley provided a presentation on the Committee's experience of smart meter implementation, in her capacity as the committee consultant on the Assembly side of the Legislature dealing with smart meter and energy efficiency issues.

The Committee on Utilities and Commerce addressed a broad range of climate change legislation and issues, in particular the issue of rates and rate reform. The Committee was examining the higher tier rates, which impose higher charges on high consumption, and exploring how this could be adjusted to balance the payment of tiers. Chair Steven Bradford also explained the difficulty of implementing new policies due to extensive regulation - in some cases, simply felling a tree could take many years. There were many challenges in this area.

Chair, Tim Yeo, pointed out that some of California's climate change targets were highly ambitious, and enquired about consumer pushback on such policies. Chair Steven Bradford agreed, explaining the need for policies to have tangible consumer benefits, such as the Proposition 39 on energy efficiency which had just been passed. Concerns remained that there would be a backlash which would undermine the state's tiered-rate model. Currently residential customers are able to opt in to time of use tariffs, however in future there may be a mandatory tiered time of use structure which may cause confusion for consumers.

In a more general discussion of renewable technologies, the Chair, Tim Yeo, reported that marine renewables remained about 10 years from commercial viability, and transmission issues were significant. Offshore wind remained unpopular due to its adverse aesthetic effects upon the coast line.

SMART METERS

Although smart meters appeared to have been implemented more widely in Democrat areas, it was reported that the penetration of smart meters in the US was a reflection of the readiness of technologies rather than a party political issue.

The delay to smart meter installation was largely due to privacy concerns. There was significant public concern about privacy issues relating to Home Area Networks (HANs), and also instances of predatory selling. There was a widespread concern that data regulation would somehow undermine entrepreneurship, leading to a reluctance to legislate in this area. Indeed, California deployed smart meter technology far before the standards, codes and regulations were in place.

Some studies seem to suggest there could be health impacts from smart meter radio waves, although public opposition had been largely overcome with the introduction of an opt-out.

The tiered system meant that energy prices went from 11 cents to 42 cents per KWh. Some consumers attributed the increase in rates to smart meters. PG&E had made the top two tiers the same rate, since the bottom two tiers were capped, which increased energy bills for more intensive users. In addition, some smart meters had given false readings, although this had happened only during initial deployment due to a short-term software malfunction. The loss of employment for meter readers as a result of remote reading was also a concern.

Public support for energy efficiency was high in California, but the costs of renewable contracts would be substantial, pushing energy rates up. Chair, Tim Yeo, pointed out that the benefits from smart meter roll-out appeared to accrue almost entirely to energy suppliers, which was likely to undermine public support. Indeed, one of Sue Kateley's reports questioned the benefits for consumers, particularly for natural gas consumers. An additional benefit, which could potentially be added to smart meters for gas would be the detection of gas leaks, but this feature was not currently installed. An unexpected benefit of smart meter installation was reduced vehicular accident rates, due to meter reader vehicles no longer being needed.

A wider issue in California related to whether the state regulator could manage the utilities. There was a lack of fiscal management of these companies, leading to concern that the California Public Utilities Commission (CPUC) might not be monitoring the accounts with the requisite care and attention. Another of Sue Kateley's reports examined the costs of smart meter roll-out for small-scale versus large-scale utilities. Further issues of interest included making data on energy efficiency programmes more transparent, so that outcomes of the $1 billion expenditure in this area were clear. A forthcoming Committee evidence hearing would examine the network security issue in more detail.

Visit to Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory (LBNL)

Thursday 21 March 2013

MEMBERS PRESENT:   

Mr Tim Yeo (Chair)
Dr Phillip Lee
Albert Owen
John Robertson
Sir Robert Smith
Dr Alan Whitehead

LBNL staff present:

Chuck Goldman, Head of the Energy Analysis and Environmental Impacts Department (EAE)
Mary Ann Piette, Head of the Building Technology and Urban Systems Department and Director of the Demand Response Research Centre (DRRC)

Introduction

Mr Yeo explained the purpose of the Committee's visit to California as part of its inquiry into smart meter roll-out in the UK as well as its wider interest in energy efficiency. He noted that there were some similarities between California and the UK, such as the vociferous minority of opponents to roll-out and the difficulty of convincing consumers of the benefits, particularly if they appeared to accrue mostly to suppliers. Dr Whitehead commented that the area-based approach to roll-out in the US might be better than the approach being taken in the UK, and added that it was surprising that the benefits appeared to accrue mainly to suppliers.

Chuck Goldman, Head of the Energy Analysis and Environmental Impacts Department (EAEI), gave some background about the Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory, his role and the energy landscape in the US, noting that about 15 states allowed retail competition and that the uptake had been significant among larger commercial/industrial customers, but much lower for domestic, residential customers.

Mr Goldman explained that he led the EAIA, which did work in several areas: energy efficiency policy and programme design; sustainable energy; electricity markets and policy; indoor environmental quality; international energy studies; and energy policy, modelling and efficiency in China. The China Energy Group had been doing work in relation to China for 30 years. He also managed a technical assistance programme targeted at state energy regulators for the Department of Energy in relation to energy efficiency and smart grid implementation issues. In that context, he had supported the regulatory commissions and their staff in regulatory proceedings and workshops in a number of states, including Michigan and Maine, on smart grid implementation issues, including on health and privacy aspects of smart meters and enabling technologies to facilitate demand response and dynamic pricing.

The Environmental Energy Technologies Division (EETD) was one of the largest divisions in LBNL, taking up about 10% of its staff and budget. In total, the annual budget was about $100 million, and 13 Nobel prize-winning scientists had worked at the lab since it was founded in 1931. Currently, most of its funding came from the Department of Energy, but some came from the State of California.

ENERGY EFFICIENCY

Mr Goldman outlined the benefits of energy efficiency as a resource, such as reduced consumption and costs, and noted that smart meters were not necessary for energy efficiency.

He explained that customers in the US contributed to energy efficiency programmes worth $5 billion and that they were informed what this money was spent on. They paid about one third of a cent per kWh towards these programmes, with retail electricity prices for residential customers ranging from 6 to 20 cents per kWh depending on the utility and state. However, 68% of this spending was concentrated in 10 states, with California having by far the highest spend on energy efficiency programmes (one fifth of the overall spend).

Certain states had particular policy and legislative requirements regarding energy efficiency. For example, six states required utilities to acquire cost-effective energy efficiencies, 15 states had energy efficiency resource standards, and 28 states required utilities to have demand-side management plans or energy efficiency budgets. However, spending on electricity and gas energy efficiency programmes in the US was expected to double or even triple (to $10 billion or $15 billion) by 2025. This kind of spending had the potential to nearly flatten load growth by 2025 in some states. Indeed, California's per capita energy consumption had been flat for the past 30 years, while average per capita consumption had risen steadily for the US as a whole. This achievement was largely a result of California's investment in energy efficiency measures, including appliance standards, building standards and obligations placed on utilities. Mr Goldman described a 'labyrinth of energy efficiency policies' in California, including the energy efficiency resource standard, the Renewable Portfolio Standard (RPS), and integrated resource planning. These measures were estimated to have saved $65 billion-worth of electricity and gas between 1976 and 2003, with 40,000 GWh of electricity a year being saved in 2003 (against 1976 levels).

A key aspect of the energy efficiency measures involved increasing the energy efficiency of buildings, but this had to be done cost-effectively. The most aggressive energy efficiency work had been done in the public sector, partly because of federal targets to reduce energy use in federal facilities. Every federal agency was ranked on its performance and given funding accordingly. Many military facilities wanted to be self-sufficient in terms of reliability and had attempted to procure on-site generation because they saw access to energy as a security issue. Much of this change in energy efficiency investments in the US had been driven by economics from the customer and utility perspective and not necessarily by concerns about climate change. For example, commercial landlords benefited from lower operating costs when they increased the energy efficiency of their buildings because they had obligations to keep certain comfort levels in buildings; increasing energy efficiency made it cheaper for them to do this. Mr Goldman pointed out that smart meters would not 'save the day' in terms of addressing poor housing stock, and that energy efficiency policies could be of use prior to the installation of meters.

ADVANCED AND SMART METERS

When putting forward their plans for implementing smart meters, utilities had had to show that what they wanted to do was cost-effective to utility customers in terms of either operational savings or peak demand/demand response benefits as part of a business case proceeding to state regulators. In typical business cases, most utilities projected that about 80% to 85% of the benefits of smart meters/the smart grid would come from operational savings, with demand response (e.g. peak demand savings, need to build fewer peaking resources) and smoothing making up a good portion of the remainder. Based on experience to date with rolling out smart meters, many utilities had reported that operational savings from smart meters had been realized in the field.

The EETD had been working with 10 utilities that were rolling out smart meters, including some that offered in-home displays (IHDs) and various types of time-based tariffs to customers, including critical peak pricing, time-of-use (TOU) tariffs, and peak time rebates. Part of this work involved randomised control trials with large numbers of households. In aggregate over the 10 utilities, about 150,000 households had been assigned to treatment and control groups. Aspects being studied included: what motivated customers to sign up to and stay on time-based tariffs; how customers responded to time-based tariffs; whether better results were gained when customers had to opt into having a time-based tariff or when they were automatically put on one and had to opt out if they wanted a different tariff. Studies and evaluations of dynamic pricing had also been done over the past seven to eight years at a number of other utilities, although in many cases with somewhat less rigorous experimental designs.

Many utility programme managers at these 10 utilities had reported, as they had been rolling out smart meters and time-based tariffs, that there were major gaps in consumer knowledge. For example, many customers did not understand why electricity cost more at peak times, and many did not fully understand the rates they were on. Some customers did not believe there should be a link between the cost of providing power and the rates they paid. Many consumers thought that all energy in California was clean and that energy from non-clean sources out of the state did not have an impact on them. Many did not know which appliances, other than air-conditioning units, used a lot of power. Mr Goldman suggested a large educational effort was needed to overcome consumer resistance.

Oklahoma demand response study

In Oklahoma, there had been a very successful roll-out of smart meters, and mechanisms such as variable peak pricing and ToU tariffs were being used. An Oklahoma Gas & Electric (OG&E) demand response study had looked at the energy savings achieved by customers using either: programmable thermostats; in-home displays (IHD); web-based consumption data; or all three. The study had found that those with the programmable thermostats saved the most, whereas those with IHDs saved the least—considerably less than those with the programmable thermostats. Customers with the web option saved slightly more than those with IHDs, and customers with all three saved slightly less than those with just programmable thermostats.[296] As a result, Mr Goldman suggested that information/feedback to customers was essential and that there were many delivery channels that could provide this information, such as web-based portals, IHDs and smart thermostats. However, at OG&E, the results from programmable thermostats seemed particularly promising in terms of cost-effectiveness compared to the current generation of IHD devices, because cost differences were not significant and summer peak demand savings appeared to be more predictable and larger. A policy issue to consider was the extent to which it was worth subsidising such control devices (eg, smart thermostats) in order to get better demand management.

Mr Goldman noted that historic billing practices in the US were very different to those in the UK for domestic customers. In the US, domestic customers were used to getting monthly utility bills, and 30 to 40 utilities now offered energy information/feedback programmes that provided information to customers on how their usage compared to that of their neighbours, identified energy saving opportunities and showed trends in usage and bills over time. Savings from these energy information programmes for large groups of customers had been in the 1% to 2% range, with rigorous experimental designs (randomised control trials with treatment and control groups) being used. In most cases, utilities presented this energy information/feedback to customers either through mail-marketing materials (eg bill stuffers in their utility bill) or through web-based portals.

US customers had received monthly bills and known about their energy consumption for a long time but this had not necessarily prompted behaviour change until utilities had started offering energy information/feedback programs. With the roll-out of smart meters, some of these energy information/feedback programs now had even more granular—hourly or daily—information, which showed how quickly and for how long customers responded to energy information/feedback messages. Many US utilities might decide to combine time-based pricing with energy information/feedback programs because initial research suggested that most of the behavioural response from domestic customers lasted only for days or weeks in the absence of emergency or crisis conditions.

Mr Goldman urged that the UK should seriously consider doing large-scale pilots using rigorous experimental designs to develop realistic estimates of the savings that might be obtained from time-based pricing, information/feedback devices such as IHDs and other enabling technologies such as programmable communicating thermostats, particularly given the historic differences in utility billing practices, consumption and usage patterns among domestic customers.

Home Area Networks (HANs) and gateways

The EETD had found from its smart meter research that having the HAN integrated into the smart meter was not an optimal strategy. For example, issues had been raised in relation to customer privacy, as the integrated home gateway could be accessed, and this system did not work well when the meter was far from the device, so it was not always reliable for demand response signals.[297]

An alternative system would be to install smart meters with lower functionality and to use gateway boxes rather than smart meters to provide a HAN. This system would require only one-way communication between the smart meter and the HAN would therefore be more secure. The gateway boxes could be used in conjunction with secure servers to provide customers with price signals, messaging and other information via the internet and smart phones rather than via an IHD. An internet-based gateway would also enable companies such as Siemens or Google to monitor price signals over the internet and build technologies and applications for consumers accordingly.

Gateway boxes had the advantage of being easier to upgrade and keep up with technology, and they would not need to use Zigbee, with which there had been some technical issues. Zigbee 1.0 was currently used in the US and the UK was expected to use Zigbee 1.2. The gateway boxes cost about $200 and they were already being used in the US to control appliances. The EETD recommended this gateway approach because it was more secure and because technology and software companies were better placed than smart meter manufacturers to design HAN hardware and software. Mr Goldman suggested that although manufacturers were currently using the specification SEP 1.0, SEP 2.0 should be used as standard for the next generation of meters.

Consumer ability to opt out of having a smart meter

As few as 2% of consumers had chosen to opt out of having smart meters and numbers tended to decline as the benefits of smart meters became more apparent. People's reasons for opting out were diverse but health concerns remained unproven and smart meters had been proven to be accurate. However, there was little to be gained from arguing with consumers about opting out and refusal could result in costly legal battles. A good compromise was to allow consumers to opt out and then to charge them according to what this cost the supplier.

Utilities could act to minimise concerns by engaging with consumers before roll-out; ensuring that expectations were realistic and that the accuracy of meters could be verified; and by helping to ensure that consumers would be able to derive the expected benefits from their smart meters.

DEMAND RESPONSE (DR) AND TIME-BASED PRICING

DR had been shown to shave the top off expected peaks in demand by a maximum of 1,191 MW or 2.9% of system demand in 2006. DR capability during peak times was now as high as 10% in a few states and could be as high as 16% by 2032. However, energy efficiency was still important in reducing consumption overall, as were static ToU tariffs, which allowed customers to alter their consumption patterns to take advantage of lower prices during off-peak times. Pilots to date showed that the opt-in approach to ToU tariffs favoured the status quo, with fewer than 20% of customers opting in. There had been less research on opt-out tariffs. Another option was mandated choice, with consumers having to make a decision.

Mary Ann Piette, Head of the Building Technology and Urban Systems Department and Director of the Demand Response Research Centre (DRRC) explained that the DRRC had developed open automated demand response (OpenADR) to help reduce peak load and prevent it from rising any higher. It was currently used mainly in commercial properties, and some utilities were able to get a 10% reduction on the peak when the price went up and commercial buildings took immediate action to reduce their consumption. For example, a bakery had bought extra pans so that it could turn the dishwasher off at those times. [NB, with this kind of dynamic pricing, customers receive price signals during peak demand periods and take immediate action to cut consumption, whereas with static ToU tariffs, customers know which times of day are cheaper and plan their everyday consumption patterns to take advantage of these cheaper periods.] Other possibilities for immediate responses to price signals included lighting that dims automatically during peak pricing times and automated thermostats that adjust by a couple of degrees at peak times but which can be overridden if the customer feels uncomfortable with the adjusted temperature.

Many organisations, small and large, were now using OpenADR, including Siemens, Honeywell and Mitsubishi. It was being used in Scotland and Japan, there were active pilots in Australia and China, and other countries were also interested.

The Demand to Grid (D2G) Appliance Research Lab was researching the use of OpenADR with appliances in the home.

Building Technology and Urban Systems Department

Mary Ann Piette gave an overview of the BTUS department's work. Homes in California would have to be net zero energy by 2020, and commercial buildings by 2030. The department had worked on several innovations that could help to achieve that aim. Successes included:

  • Energy efficiency windows, including for the New York Times building
  • Lighting sources and controls
  • Energy-efficient data centres - 2-5% of energy use in the US is from data centres.
  • Healthy homes - ensuring that energy efficient homes are properly ventilated so that emissions from carpets, etc, are released.
  • Automated demand response
  • Cool roofs - roofs that look dark but that reflect infra-red rays
  • DOE2 and Energy Plus - tools for low-energy design optimisation and retrofit analysis to support energy savings of 10-30% per building

The department was working on modelling buildings so that they did not need air conditioning, controlling the level of solar gain through windows, and enabling buildings to have more flexible energy use—although such platforms are currently expensive. This flexibility would be crucial when there was greater use of wind and other intermittent loads on the system.


295   http://energy.gov/data/green-button  Back

296   This research is expected to be published in summer 2013 Back

297   This research is expected to be published in summer 2013 Back


 
previous page contents next page


© Parliamentary copyright 2013
Prepared 27 July 2013