Documents considered by the Committee on 22 January 2014 - European Scrutiny Committee Contents


9 Public intervention and the internal electricity market

(35531)

15776/13

+ ADDs 1-5

C(13) 7243

Commission Communication: Delivering the internal electricity market and making the most of public intervention
Legal base
Document originated 5 November 2013
Deposited in Parliament 20 November 2013
Department Energy and Climate Change
Basis of consideration EM of 29 November 2013 and Minister's letter of 10 January 2014
Previous Committee Report None
Discussion in Council No date set
Committee's assessment Politically important
Committee's decision Cleared

Background

9.1 According to the Commission, the internal market is necessary to achieve the objectives of the EU's policy on energy, which it says include secure and competitively priced supplies, targets for renewable and climate change for 2020 and beyond, and a significant increase in energy efficiency. It also notes that Member States have agreed to complete the internal electricity market by 2014, and that it is widely accepted there is a need for some public intervention, which it notes can take different forms (such as state aid in the form of grants or tax exemptions, the imposition of public service obligations, and general regulation). It comments that, although such intervention can be useful, it must be well designed and adapted to changes in market functioning and technology over time, making it important to define its role, level and nature, bearing in mind that some Member States have announced significant public support for investment in new generating capacity, which, if not properly designed, risks distorting competition and investment signals.

The current document

9.2 The Commission has therefore produced this Communication, which assesses the main features of public intervention, and shows how these can be designed in order to increase their effectiveness. It also says that it will adopt in 2014 new Union guidelines on environmental and energy aid for 2014-20, on which it will soon launch a public consultation.

THE NEED FOR RE-THINKING PUBLIC INTERVENTION

9.3 The Commission suggests that, as the internal electricity market has developed, a number of issues have arisen which may justify public intervention. These include:

·  the growing importance of renewable energy, where the benefits are manifold, but most current support schemes were designed when the technologies were in their infancy and had negligible market shares;

·  the need for a more active demand-side response (through the use of smart distribution networks, smart meters and appliances, and electricity storage), and demand-response services (such as dynamic pricing, interruptible load- or dynamic-load capping contracts for industry, commercial businesses and households; participation in balancing markets; services aggregating; and optimising demand for households), which the Commission suggests can increase system flexibility, enable users to shift consumption to cheaper periods, and reduce the need for generation capacity;

·  the key need to take into account environmental externalities, arising (for example) from a phasing out of subsidies for fossil fuels and increased aid for renewable energy, including nuclear generation;

·  the need for adequate generating capacity, where market volatility has created uncertainty for investors seeking to upgrade today's aging systems, which has in turn led some Member States to consider public subsidies, not only for new investment, but to enable existing plants to remain operational; and

·  the extent to which the creation of the internal market means that public intervention in one Member State can affect prices, not only nationally, but in neighbouring markets, leading to both short term and long term distortions.

MORE EFFECTIVE AND EFFICIENT PUBLIC INTERVENTION

9.4 The Commission says that well-designed, targeted and proportionate public intervention allows policy objectives to be achieved without distorting markets more than necessary, but that this must be properly coordinated within and between Member States, in order to avoid higher costs for consumers and taxpayers, reduced opportunities for cross-border trade, or subsidy races.

9.5 It suggests that this involves:

·  identifying the specific problem to be addressed, and demonstrating that the functioning of the internal market on the basis of the existing acquis is unlikely to solve it without public intervention;

·  assessing the potential interplay with other policy objectives, in order to avoid a conflict between them, and taking into account possible trade-offs, with the need to ensure that prices reflect external costs being particularly important;

·  evaluating alternative options to national intervention, taking into account both the European dimension and demand side considerations, such as changing consumer behaviour;

·  minimising the impact on electricity systems and competition, and removing hidden subsidies;

·  keeping costs low by means of auctions, competition across technologies, and exploiting efficiencies at EU level and involving other Member States, particularly as regards support for renewables, in order to ensure that intervention is appropriate to the objective pursued and does not go beyond what is necessary;

·  considering the impact on consumer costs, particularly in relation to the global competitiveness of the EU's energy-intensive industries; and

·  the monitoring, evaluation and (where necessary) phasing out of support, whilst avoiding retroactive changes which undermine investor confidence.

SPECIFIC MEASURES

9.6 The Communication also seeks to provide guidance relating to specific forms of public intervention, noting that, in order to meet the requirements of the Electricity Directive (2009/72/EC), these need to be clearly defined, transparent, non-discriminatory, verifiable, and guarantee equality of access for electricity undertakings, with Member States having to show that, where public service obligations are imposed, there are necessary, proportionate and transitional in nature (and consistent with the provisions of the Electricity Directive). It also says that, where such intervention is not compliant with the acquis, and in particular state aid rules, it will launch infringement proceedings.

9.7 The Commission then addresses the following four areas:

Provision of adequate generation

9.8 The Commission comments that guaranteeing security of supply is a key public policy objective, and that the reliability of Member States' systems in inter-connected markets is interdependent. It nevertheless believes that the prevention of supply disruption should not go beyond what is strictly necessary, and that a comprehensive, facts-based assessment is needed prior to public intervention, with any such assessments being notified to the Commission. It adds that, where an assessment shows that inadequate generation is a serious problem, Member States should assess the alternative measures available, and properly identify why the problem cannot be remedied by the market alone. It also suggests that, if alternative measures do not solve the identified problem, a strategic reserve, a credibly one-off tendering procedure, or even a market-wide capacity mechanism, are possible options, subject to the caveat that Member States should take into account the objective of phasing out subsidies for fossil fuel generation by 2020.

9.9 The Commission says the mechanisms to ensure adequate generation should be open to all capacity — including that from other Member States — which can contribute effectively. It encourages Member States considering public intervention in this area to cooperate with others in their region to examine the potential of cross-border mechanisms, whilst also stressing that, in order to minimise market distortions, there should be no export charges or procedures to reserve capacity for the domestic market. It also suggests that distortions of competition and trade can be reduced by regularly reviewing the need for intervention, and it warns that, where it is called upon to examine public interventions in relation to either state aid rules or internal market legislation, it will require a thorough generation adequacy assessment from the Member State concerned. Finally, the Commission says that these interventions should not compensate for the negative impact of other subsidies or poor implementation of internal market rules.

Support schemes for renewables

9.10 The Commission notes that the Treaty requires EU policy to promote the development of new and renewable forms of energy, which it observes is also important for achieving environmental and climate objectives, but it recognises that, as markets are unlikely to deliver the desirable level of renewables in the near future, governments may want to intervene to support "infant industry". It says that this should be done in a stable, transparent, credible, cost-efficient and market integrating way, avoiding damaging retroactive changes, but adds that, as the sector and technologies mature and grow (and costs decline), production and investment decisions should be driven increasingly by the market, and not by guaranteed price levels determined by public authorities. In practice, it says that this means phasing out feed-in tariffs which shield producers from market price signals, and designing support which is more consistent with the Emissions Trading System (with support declining as ETS carbon prices increase). It also points out that renewables can require the use of equipment produced outside the EU and of biomass as feedstock, and it reminds Member States that "local content rules" might not be in line with the acquis.

9.11 The Commission draws attention to the crucial need to focus public intervention on research and development for emerging technologies, and for supporting non-commercial, decentralised production from individual households in specific ways: and it notes that, in addition to public intervention to promote electricity from renewables, balancing obligations, the design of balancing markets, the use interconnections, grid connection charges and grid use rules can be designed in a technology-neutral manner and allow appropriate cost signals to be passed on to all major producers and users.

Development of renewables

9.12 The Commission points out that the Renewable Energy Directive (2009/28/EC) provides for three kinds of cooperation mechanisms between Member States, which help them to achieve national targets most effectively, but regrets that little or no use has been made of these so far. It has therefore provided in an accompanying Staff Working Document more detailed guidance on the use of such mechanisms.

Demand response measures

9.13 The Commission suggests that the internal electricity market involves, not just producers and network operators, but consumers as well, who — with the help of supporting technologies — can play a significant role in making the system more flexible. It says that this requires an appropriate organisation of the retail market, which triggers investments in innovative products and services, as well as clear rules on data exchange and protocols, removing tariff elements which hamper active market participation, and the development of dynamic pricing. It says that it is currently analysing the smart metering roll-out plans received from Member States, and that further policy and regulatory work may be necessary at both Member State and EU level, including appropriate tariff design, removing price controls, strengthening price signals, and developing further rules for coordination, complemented by bringing enabling technology into the market.

The Government's view

9.14 In his Explanatory Memorandum of 29 November 2013, the Minister of State at the Department of Energy and Climate Change (Michael Fallon) says that the Government is supportive of a well-functioning internal energy market, and welcomes this non-binding Communication and the guidance it provides on public intervention. It also agrees that well-designed interventions do not disproportionately distort markets and may be necessary to ensure security of supply.

9.15 The Minister adds that the guidance set out in the Communication is acceptable to the UK, and should allow the implementation of existing and proposed support schemes, with the Government working with the Commission to ensure that the latter are developed in line with the general principles in the guidance. He also expects some of those principles to be included in the Commission's forthcoming energy and environment state aid guidelines, and says that the Government is keen for these to be aligned.

9.16 When we considered this document on 11 December 2013, we took the view that its contents were unexceptionable, but we also noted that the material circulated by the Commission runs to nearly 180 pages, involving considerable resource costs, not only in its production and printing, but also in its subsequent digestion by officials (and others) in 28 Member States. Given also that much of its content seemed to consist of statements of the obvious in areas in which Member States presumably possessed as much expertise and knowledge as the Commission itself, we found it difficult to see what useful purpose it served. Our Chairman therefore wrote to the Minister, asking him to comment on this, and to cite examples where the guidance says anything which competent authorities in Member States would not already be aware of, and to explain how the course of events in this area would be materially different, even if the guidance had not been issued.

9.17 He has now sent us the following reply:

    "You asked why I welcomed this Commission Communication, noting that, in your view, it consists largely of statements of the obvious of which Member States ought to be aware already. As you know, the UK is a strong supporter of the objective of completing the single market in energy and we have always developed any market interventions in line with this aim. While the Commission accepts that some public intervention in energy markets is needed, there is a risk of Member States taking action which potentially undermines the functioning of the single market. To mitigate this risk, the Commission considers it appropriate to set out clearly their views on how public interventions should be designed to avoid distorting markets beyond what is necessary. The Communication and its Staff Working Documents usefully includes a 'check list' for all Member States to consider ahead of intervening in the electricity sector. Interventions that can demonstrate they are in line with the Communication may assist in any state aid notification process. This is particularly helpful for the UK as we have a large number of state aid cases in the pipeline.

    "You also asked for examples of where the guidance says anything Member States are not already aware of and to what extent the course of events in this area is likely to have been materially different in the absence of the guidance. As mentioned above, the guidance aims to ensure that Member State interventions respect the principles of the single market as far as possible and the UK has been the first Member State to design innovative schemes that do that. For instance, we have committed in principle to open our new capacity market to foreign generation provided the conditions are right, and we are developing arrangements, in cooperation with the Commission and relevant stakeholders, to facilitate this. We have also signed a Memorandum of Understanding with the Republic of Ireland to jointly explore how Irish renewables might be developed to our mutual benefit, by making use of the cooperation mechanisms in the Renewables Directive. In both cases, we are developing innovative arrangements which might, moreover, subsequently be used by other Member States. Without the Commission's guidance it would be much more difficult to devise mechanisms which we can be sure the Commission will consider to be compatible with the development of the single market.

Conclusion

9.18 We are grateful to the Minister for his explanation, and, although it strikes us as unduly charitable, we would not wish to argue the issue further, other than to observe that, if this guidance really is necessary, it could, in our view, have been conveyed in a much shorter and simpler — and hence more effective — manner. Having said that, we remain of the view that the document does not raise any other issues requiring further consideration, and we are therefore clearing it.





 
previous page contents next page


© Parliamentary copyright 2014
Prepared 5 February 2014