Documents considered by the Committee on 12 March 2014 - European Scrutiny Committee Contents


10 Financial services: benchmarks

(35328)

13985/13

+ ADDs 1-2

COM(13) 641

Draft Regulation on indices used as benchmarks in financial instruments and financial contracts
Legal base Article 114 TFEU; co-decision; QMV
Department HM Treasury
Basis of consideration Letter from the Commission of 26 February 2014
Previous Committee Reports HC 83-xxi (2013-14) chapter 5, (20 November 2013) HC 83-xix (2013-14), chapter 4, (30 October 2013)
Discussion in Council Not known
Committee's assessment Legally and politically important
Committee's decision Not cleared; further information requested

Background

10.1 The draft Regulation, known as the benchmark Regulation, concerns indices used as benchmarks in financial instruments, financial contracts or to measure the performance of investment funds. In summary, it seeks to improve governance of the benchmark process, prevent conflict of interests of benchmark administrators and contributors, enhance the quality and accuracy of input data and methodologies used by administrators and ensure adequate protection for consumers and investors using benchmarks.

10.2 The House of Commons issued a Reasoned Opinion on this Draft Regulation following a debate in European Committee on 28 November 2013. It was the only national parliament to do so. We recommended the Reasoned Opinion because we considered, partly on the basis of strong evidence from the UK financial services sector, that the supposed benefits of EU level action (second limb of the subsidiarity principle) — the enhancement of the single market, the promotion of cross-border transactions and the protection of consumers — were outweighed by potential disadvantages. These included:

·  harmful consequences of the broad application of a detailed, harmonised solution to the wide range of benchmarks (particularly as the rules are not fully aligned with International Organisation of Securities Commissions (IOSCO) principles);

·  burdens imposed on administrators, contributors, regulators and others, which could result in the discontinuance of some existing benchmarks and impede the creation of others;

·  the risk to the independence of national statistics authorities; and

·  lack of provision for use of non-EU benchmarks within the EU.

The Commission's response

10.3 In his letter of 26 February 2014, Maroš Šefèoviè, the Vice-President of the Commission (Inter-institutional Relations and Administration) says that the Commission remains of the view that the proposal is justified. However, he says that the Reasoned Opinion of the House of Commons will be considered as part of the ongoing political dialogue. The full text of the Commission's response is annexed to this Report.

10.4 The Commission reiterates its justification of the proposal on the first limb of the subsidiarity test (that Member State action alone is insufficient to achieve the purpose of the proposal) which was set out in its original impact assessment and explanatory memorandum:

·  that the benchmark industry is international and that benchmarks are particularly important for pricing cross-border transactions; and

·  that few benchmarks are national in use or production (nor could their use be so restricted and that national rules would create divergence between benchmarks.

10.5 On the second limb of the test (EU added-value of the proposal), the Commission again refers back to original justifications in its impact assessment and explanatory memorandum. These partly rehearse the above arguments on the first limb of the test. In addition, the Commission:

·  states that consistent, common EU rules based on and "aligned" with (as the proposal is) IOSCO principles (endorsed by the Financial Stability Board and the G20) will avoid manipulation, avoid variation in reliability and robustness and enhance the single market;

·  suggests that the burdens on administrators and contributors will not be as significant as argued by the House of Commons since the requirements of the proposal broadly align with IOSCO principles;

·  states that any additional costs caused by administration and registration are unlikely to result in the discontinuation of benchmarks, instead resulting in enhanced competitiveness and reliability;

·  comments on how cost of compliance is calculated (which does not seem to relate to the concerns raised in the Reasoned Opinion); and

·  states that, if necessary, the requirements for statistical authorities (whose benchmarks also fall within the scope of the proposal) can be adapted to suit their special features and thus ensure independence.

Our assessment

10.6 Much of the Commission's response to the Reasoned Opinion consists of rehearsing assertions initially made in its impact assessment and explanatory memorandum. There is some attempt made to address the specific points raised in the Reasoned Opinion on the disadvantages of EU-level action, but much of the Commission's reasoning in dismissing these concerns is based on the Commission's subjective perception of the proposed Regulation's "broad" alignment with existing international standards, contrary to the view of the UK Government.

10.7 We also find it hard to understand the Commission's logic on how the objective of harmonisation of benchmarks can be achieved if there is to be the degree of flexibility suggested in relation to statistical authorities and wonder whether that flexibility will be illusory. Finally, we do not understand the relevance to our Reasoned Opinion of the Commission's comments about the cost of compliance and to which specific ground of our Reasoned Opinion this relates.

Wider "benchmark industry" concerns

10.8 There has been some wider interest in the Reasoned Opinion on the benchmark Regulation. In addition to a specialist press inquiry, we have also received a query from APX, an Anglo-Dutch energy exchange, which operates electricity financial markets in the Netherlands, the UK and Belgium.[31] It raised with us the level of British "benchmark industry" concern about the draft Commission Implementing Regulations on capacity allocation and congestion management (CACM) network code and governance guidelines. These CACM Regulations form part of the European Network Codes.  

10.9 The concerns we have raised were specific to the context of a subsidiarity assessment within the meaning of Protocol No. 2 to the EU Treaties. Considerations unrelated to that assessment which might be raised in relation to Implementing Regulations in general, for example, in respect of competence, legal base, proportionality and, unlawful sub-delegation of powers could not be included in the Reasoned Opinion. However, it is possible that the disadvantages of the proposed EU-level action that were identified in the Reasoned Opinion could have some relevance to industry objections to the draft CACM Implementing Regulations.

Conclusion

10.10 Before responding to the Commission, we ask the Government for:

·  its view of the Commission's response; and

·  an update on the progress in the negotiations of the proposal and whether the UK's concerns about the proposal are shared by other Member States.

10.11 We also ask the Government to deposit, in due course, the proposed text of the Council Implementing Regulations on capacity allocation and congestion management (CACM) network code and governance guidelines.

Annex: The Commission's Response

Brussels, 26.2.2014

C(2014) 808 final

Dear Mr Cash,

The Commission would like to thank the House of Commons for its Reasoned Opinion concerning the Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on indices used as benchmarks in financial instruments and financial contracts {COM (2013) 641 final}.

The Commission would like to respond to the points raised in the Reasoned Opinion.

The House of Commons argues that there has been a failure by the Commission to comply with the principle of subsidiarity as well as with essential procedural requirements in Article 5 of Protocol No. 2. The Commission considers that it has provided sufficient reasons leading to the conclusion that the objectives of the proposal can be better achieved at Union level, both in the explanatory memorandum and in the impact assessment accompanying the proposal.

Regarding the first limb of the subsidiarity test ("if and in so far as the objectives of the proposed action cannot sufficiently be achieved by the Member States"), and the argument that the proposal does not address a common issue in all Member States, both the explanatory memorandum and the impact assessment explain that the benchmark industry is international and benchmarks are in particular vital for pricing cross border transactions. Action by Member States could address some of the problems at a national level; such an approach could, however, not achieve wider European objectives because a patchwork of divergent national rules would result in an inconsistent and uncoordinated approach and impede the cross border use and provision of benchmarks. While national approaches could tackle problems with entirely national benchmarks, few benchmarks are entirely national in their production and use. Nor would it be permissible for a benchmark provider to restrict the use of a benchmark to its own Member State and thereby ensure that it remained subject to national legislation. In practice, it would therefore be difficult for a set of national approaches to achieve the objectives of this proposal.

Regarding the second limb of the subsidiarity test ("but rather, by reason of the scale or effects of the proposed action, be better achieved at EU level"), the impact assessment provides strong and clear evidence that benchmarks are used to price a wide variety of cross border transactions, in particular in the mortgages, interbank funding market, commodity and derivatives areas. As a result, the impact assessment as well as the explanatory memorandum conclude that a patchwork of national rules would impede the provision of cross border benchmarks and therefore impede cross border transactions. This need has been recognised by the G20 and the Financial Stability Board (FSB), which charged the international standard setter International Organisation of Securities Commissions (IOSCO) with producing a global set of principles to apply to financial benchmarks. Common EU rules based on the IOSCO principles will help enhance the single market by creating a common framework for reliable and correctly used benchmarks across different Member States, subject to the same rules.

The Commission would like to point out that the wide scope of the proposal is aligned with that of the Principles on Financial Benchmarks issued by IOSCO and endorsed by the FSB and the G20. A narrower scope would result in an inconsistent application of the international standards to the provision and use of different types of benchmarks in the EU Thus, the reliability and robustness of different types of benchmarks would not be consistent across the EU which would negatively impact the single market. In addition, the risk of manipulation across different types of benchmarks evidenced in the impact assessment would not be effectively addressed.

The Commission considers that the administrative burdens for benchmark administrators and contributors to benchmarks would not be as significant as argued by the House of Commons, since the requirements of the proposal are broadly in line with those of the IOSCO Principles for Financial Benchmarks and existing industry good practice. Furthermore, any additional costs relating to administration and registration are unlikely to result in the discontinuation in the provision of some benchmarks, as their reliability and competitiveness will be enhanced.

The Commission's impact assessment does not base the calculation of the total costs of compliance on the total number of benchmarks provided in the EU as the key requirements, and particularly those carrying potential additional costs, apply to the benchmark administrators and contributors and not the benchmarks themselves. Thus, the aggregate costs depend more on the aggregate number of administrators than on the total number of benchmarks.

Benchmarks provided by statistical authorities also fall under the scope of the proposal as they share the same risks and vulnerabilities identified for other types of benchmarks in the impact assessment. If necessary, the requirements for statistical authorities can be adapted to take account of their specificities in order to ensure their independence.

In the light of the above, the Commission remains of the view that the proposal is justified in terms of subsidiarity and that a European framework for the provision and use of benchmarks is necessary to ensure the robustness and reliability of benchmarks provided and used in the EU and to prevent manipulation.

The Commission hopes that these clarifications address the concerns raised by the House of Commons and looks forward to continuing our political dialogue in the future.

Maroš Šefèoviè

Vice-President


31   APX group. Back


 
previous page contents next page


© Parliamentary copyright 2014
Prepared 26 March 2014