5 Devolved taxes and powers
Introduction
112. Fiscal devolution means greater
control over taxation as well as spending locally. We have already
made recommendations on broad principles of fiscal devolution.
Here we look at more detailed implications. The London Finance
Commission (LFC)[211]
and the Core Cities[212]
proposed that a suite of property taxes could be devolved and
we examine three: full business rates retention, council tax and
stamp duty. We also examine the LFC suggestion that Londonand
by implication "devolved" local authoritiesshould
have responsibility for setting the rates of those taxes and authority
over revaluation, banding and discounts[213]
and that they should also be able to introduce new smaller yield
taxes, such as betting, landfill and hotel duties, and to set
fees and charges for all discretionary services.[214]
We expect fiscal devolution to provide local authorities with
enhanced borrowing powers which we also examine in this chapter.
Control over business rates
113. The LFC proposed the full devolution
of business rates to London, which would mean:
· 100
per cent retention of business rates; (We considered the issue
of 100 per cent retention at paragraphs 44, 51 and 52.)
· freedom
to set and vary the business rate multiplier; and
· responsibility
for the timing of revaluations.[215]
In this chapter we examine rate setting
and revaluation.
RATE SETTING
114. The open market rental valuethe
rateable valueof a business property is calculated by the
Valuation Office Agency. The multiplierthe percentage of
rateable value that will be payable in business ratesis
set by the Government. The business rate payable to the local
authority is calculated by multiplying the rateable value by the
multiplier. The Government is responsible for the timing of any
revaluation, which historically has always been carried out nationally.[216]
115. Some witnesses suggested that local
authorities should be responsible for setting the business rate
multiplier. Leeds City Council said that cities should
set their own business rates, as
was the case prior to 1990. Even within city regions there are
diverse and complex economies which would be better managed by
combined or local authorities controlling the business rates.
This would eliminate the problems arising in relation to a nationally
set multiplier and encourage cities to come up with innovative
approaches to attract and support businesses.[217]
Cllr James Lewis from Leeds City Council
pointed out: "Cities are responsible organisations. We set
a council tax every year [
] I do not think the power to
set a rate is uncommon to us."[218]
Cllr Peter Box, from the Key Cities Group, told us:
if you are serious about devolution
and localism, sometimes local government will take decisions that
parliamentarians do not like. That is the nature of it [
]
we are accountable. I cannot see how any sensible local government
[
] is going to take a decision that is going to mean that
we have outrage and business and every individual constituent
complaining. It does not work like that. [
] We do not do
things and succeed by ourselves; we do it in partnership.[219]
116. Cllr Roger Lawrence, leader of
Wolverhampton City Council, had concerns, however. He drew our
attention to tax competition with Wales when Regional Development
Agencies still existed: "It was a dreadful waste of everyone's
time and effort, chasing that around. Clearly, we need to have
measures in place to prevent that."[220]
Stephen Hughes, formerly of Birmingham City Council, said "the
buoyancy should come [
] from building the tax base, not
necessarily by changing the tax rate". He added that "we
are too small a country, really, to have lots of different variable
tax rates. It does not do any good".[221]
Cllr Paul Watson, leader of Sunderland City Council, agreed there
was a lack of detail on the impact of rate setting locally on
rebasing business rates or revaluing rents nationally, and said
the mechanics of any scheme would have to be sorted out.[222]
117. Among business, the London Chamber
of Commerce and Industry said "with the right safeguards
and consultation with the business community, there is no reason
for LCCI to oppose the GLA or London [local authorities] being
given the power to determine the rate".[223]
The Greater Birmingham Chambers of Commerce disagreed, saying
new freedoms would bring "new opportunities for additional
taxes and levies aimed at business which could stymie the growth
of the private sector". It therefore could not support local
rate-setting.[224]
Liz Peace, chief executive of the British Property Federation,
said greater relocation of business rate collection rather than
setting was needed. Its members were
trying to balance one thing against
the other: a degree of nervousness in case a local authority went
mad and whacked up the business rates phenomenally, if they had
rate-setting powers, compared with the wish to see local authorities
having a degree of freedom to borrow.[225]
VARYING THE RATE
118. Whether or not the multiplier was
set locally, witnesses saw merit in being able to vary it within
their area. Cllr Nick Forbes, from Core Cities, said that the
"issue about business rates [...] is not so much about the
difference between local authorities; actually, it is within a
local-authority area where you might want to have some marginal
variation of business rates."[226]
Cllr Lawrence cited the Business Improvement District model, "where
a small supplement on the business rate in small areas is used
very explicitly for particular activities to help those businesses
and those businesses have a share in driving that forward".[227]
Sir Merrick Cockell added that small variations and increases
in business rates might be decided locally: "Areas might
be able to save 5% either way, and that would be down to those
areas to work with local businesses to agree what was right and
how that money was being invested."[228]
119. We consider that restoring the
ability of local authorities to set the business rate multiplier
to meet local circumstances, combined with the power to vary the
rate for specific projects and categories of business, will provide
authorities with a key lever in stimulating and fostering local
economic growth as well as guaranteeing that they work closely
with local business. It will ensure that local authorities have
to consult with, and focus on the needs of, local business. We
see a logic in the same multiplier being set across the devolved
area. We also recognise, however, that there may be a concern
about the potential for excessive increases in the multiplier.
One option to constrain that would be for local authorities in
a devolved area to be limited to increasing business rates by
no more than the increase in the average council tax in the devolved
area. The operation of the business rates levy would need to avoid
penalising authorities that, after full consultation with local
business, increase their multiplier.
REVALUATION
120. Although the national reassessment
of rateable values must take place every five years, the Growth
and Infrastructure Act 2013 changed the date of the next revaluation
from 2015 to 2017.[229]
While there has been some criticism of this change,[230]
the transfer of responsibility for revaluation to local areas
was not seen as the solution or as a prerequisite for fiscal devolution.
Sir Merrick Cockell said:
I do not think we are saying that
we would want to do the valuation [
] I am sure we could
create a system that operated within the current national body
working out the rateable value of businesses.[231]
But several witnesses wanted more frequent
valuations. Among business, LCCI noted that "revaluations
are frequently delayed",[232]
while Liz Peace suggested that, with modern technology, revaluation
could take place every two years and there would be fewer arguments.[233]
Three to four years was suggested by Lord Smith, Chair of the
Greater Manchester Combined Authority.[234]
On the other hand, Ed Cox, from IPPR North, suggested combining
the revaluation of business rateable values with a more general
rebasing of devolved fiscal measures and funding formulasa
comprehensive resetting. He said this might be carried out by
an independent body every 10 years.[235]
121. We detected little clamour for
transferring the revaluation of business rateable values to local
areas as part of the process of fiscal devolution. The main concern
has been the delay in holding national valuations. The time has
come to set a timescale for an independently commissioned national
business rate revaluation and, to ensure it happens, for it to
be set in primary legislation without the facility to change the
date through secondary legislation. We recommend it takes place
every five years, beginning in 2020, and within six months of
a general election. Revaluation could then coincide with the
resetting of the Business Rates Retention scheme, to which we
see a strong link. Subsequently, it could coincide once every
10 years with the resetting of any assessment of relative need
among local authorities, administered by the independent body
to which we have referred. In our view such a process would ensure
not only regular and fair equalisation and redistribution of resources,
but predictability, allowing local authorities to plan ahead.
THE INDEPENDENT OFFICE FOR LOCAL
GOVERNMENT FISCAL MANAGEMENT
122. In sum, the independent body
we recommend would introduce a substantial degree of objectivity
into local government fiscal management. Specifically, it would
be responsible for: assessing relative needs and resources every
10 years, starting in 2020 when the BRRS is rebased; evaluating
proposals when a fiscal agreement cannot be reached; and commissioning
the independent revaluation of business rates and council tax
every five years, starting in 2020.
Council tax
123. The LFC recommended that:
Council tax should be retained as
a local tax but London government should be given the power and
be required to hold periodic revaluations (undertaken by the Valuation
Office, according to national practice), to determine the number
of bands, to set the ratio of tax from band to band and to set
the tax rate.[236]
COUNCIL TAX REFERENDUMS
124. The Localism Act 2011 makes planned
increases in council tax, above a certain threshold set by central
Government, subject to a local binding council tax referendum.
In 2014-15 the threshold is 2%. Explaining the Government's thinking
behind the policy, the Minister, Brandon Lewis, told us that:
When I was a local government councillornot
when I was in control of the councilthe local authority
I was in had, back in the late 1990s and early 2000s, council
tax rises of 19%, 18% and 16%; they were generally quite regularly
in double figures. It is quite reasonable for central Government
to say, "We think the highest it should be is around 2%.
We want to try to help people with their bills."[237]
Mr Lewis added:
They (local authorities) have got
the freedom to go out, have a referendum, make the case and get
the agreement of their local residents to do it (raise council
tax).[238]
Sir Merrick Cockell said that:
local authorities should make their
case to those who elect them. It gives a good reason for people
to bother to vote [
] people who take those decisions should
be held accountable through the ballot box rather than through
a referendum.[239]
The Greater Manchester Combined Authority
said:
Whilst the principle of council
tax referendums provides direct accountability, the variable nature
of the referendum threshold set by central Government makes long
term decision making for local authorities problematic.[240]
When we asked Mr Lewis why the principle
of a referendum should not apply to other taxes, he said that
was "a very good question" but offered no further explanation.[241]
125. We found across local government
in England, if not a demand for full fiscal devolution in all
areas, a strong appetite for greater fiscal responsibility. The
Government is going to have to learn to have confidence in local
authorities in the same way it has confidence in the devolved
legislatures. For a start all local authorities should be trusted
with responsibility for setting the council tax rate in their
areas. We consider that all local authorities should have the
freedom to set their local domestic property tax rates. There
is no hard and fast rule that they will automatically use this
flexibility to increase their council tax rates, but if they do
they should be free to do so and then test local people's appetite
for it, as they do for a range of decisions, on local election
polling day.
REVALUATION AND REBANDING
126. Domestic properties in England
have not been revalued since 1991. The Government announced in
2010 that there would be no revaluation in this Parliament, as
according to the Secretary of State it "could have pushed
up taxes on people's homes".[242]
Similar excuses were used by the last Government when in 2005
it also postponed a revaluation, which had been planned for 2007,
after revaluation in Wales led to anger over council tax rises.[243]
The absence of any revaluation was of concern to witnesses. Lord
Smith, Chair of the GMCA, told us that "we have a council
tax system based in 1991 that has never been revalued. You buy
a new house where there are all these broadband facilities and
so on. How do you measure that?"[244]
The LFC called for London to be required to hold periodic revaluations
of domestic properties, carried out by the Valuation Office Agency.
Other witnesses recognised the importance of a general revaluation
but focused on smaller, incremental devolutionary measures that
might be taken. Wolverhampton City Council said that:
Even if the regulation of council
tax was relaxed, instead of fully devolved, the impact on Wolverhampton
would be positive. Re-banding properties and the removal of the
referendum threshold would give far greater freedom and enable
the local authority to respond to local needs.[245]
127. The LFC noted that council tax
did not operate on the basis of a full range of values:
Rather, all properties are attributed
to one of eight bands of value, based on capital values in 1991.
The ratio of tax paid from Band A (the lowest) to Band H (the
highest) is 1:3. Thus, a home in a London borough with a 2013
value of £25 million is likely to pay just three times the
council tax of one with a value of £250,000.[246]
IPPR said local authorities should be
allowed to introduce new additional council tax bands as they
saw fit, while the structure and number of council tax bands should
be reviewed.[247] Leeds
City Council agreed and said "the setting and adjustment
of bandings should be done by Combined Authorities". It added
local setting of bands would "more accurately reflect local
economic conditions".[248]
And in London the Mayor agreed that the introduction of extra
council tax bands, particularly for valuable properties, should
be examined.[249] The
Chair of the Assembly, Darren Johnson AM, said, while each borough
should be able to set its own council tax, decisions on banding
should take place across the whole of London.[250]
128. Council tax rates are based
on valuations made a generation ago, and those in the highest-banded
properties are limited to paying no more than three times the
tax of those in the lowest. The pretext for deferring revaluation-that
it would increase most people's council taxis erroneous
if the revaluation is carried out properly and is fiscally neutral
overall locally. Therefore a revaluation of itself must not affect
a council's income. If nothing is done, there is a risk that the
whole system will eventually collapse or, like domestic rates,
have to be replaced. If there is a case for a revaluation of business
rateable valueslast carried out in 2010the case
for revaluation of domestic rates must be greater. We recommend
that Government introduce legislation to ensure, for the purposes
of Council Tax, domestic properties are revalued every five years.
129. There is also scope for further
flexibility. We conclude that devolved areaswhich we envisage,
in the first instance, would be London or combined authority areasshould
be given the power to introduce new council tax bands at the top
end of the scale and to split existing ones. The national revaluation
will therefore need to be precise, citing a property's price not
just its band, so that any devolved local authorities wishing
to introduce a new band are able to include the appropriate properties
in it. Doing so might go some way to increasing fairness in the
distribution of the tax burden locally.
Stamp duty
130. Stamp duty is levied only on a
limited number of properties, concentrated in areas such as London
and the South East.[251]
London's stamp duty yield in 2012-13 accounted for 33% of all
stamp duty collected, about £2.8 billion out of a UK total
of £7.7 billion. Professor Travers noted that outside London
and South East, however, the tax
produces tens of millions, rather
than billions, of pounds in most places [
] of course it
would generate less money in the Sheffield city region, the Liverpool
city region or even the Manchester city region, by a long way
than it would in London. However, even there, it would leave those
authorities with a bigger tax base than they have today.[252]
The Greater Manchester Combined Authority
said there was a strong case for devolving stamp duty to its area:
Local authorities would be incentivised
to encourage economic activity such as house-buying in their area
if they retained some or all of the stamp duty due on a property
sale, and the funds could then be used to provide local services.[253]
Responsibility for stamp duty in Scotland
is due to be transferred in 2015.[254]
131. The yield from stamp duty
in London and the South East is a fiscal anomaly in England. Full
fiscal devolution of the tax in London could deprive the Exchequer
of a significant amount of revenue that could be used elsewhere
and for different purposes. As we have set out, to meet the principle
of equalisation, it could be devolved in London subject to a levy
requiring transfer of duty above an agreed threshold to the Exchequer.
On the basis of this requirement, which could apply also to other
devolved authorities, we recommend that stamp duty be included
in the fiscal devolution framework. In addition, we would expect
the Department for Communities and Local Government to monitor
and review lessons that can be drawn from devolution of stamp
duty in Scotland to inform its introduction in England.
Other taxes and charges
132. We noted in the first chapter how
under new devolution arrangements Scotland and Wales will be given
the power to introduce some taxes.[255]
The LFC suggested the creation of tourism, environmental, alcohol
or betting taxes might be permitted under devolution to the capital.[256]
The LGA said such powers could reduce the dependence on council
tax and business rates and allow areas to reduce the tax burden
on local taxpayers.[257]
When in France we heard that Lyon had a tourism tax of around
1 per night, dependant on the type of accommodation used.
Tom Riordan noted how Leeds, the venue for the start of this year's
Tour de France, might have benefited from levying such a tax.[258]
Professor Andy Pike, of Newcastle University, however, warned
that other taxes, such as environmental or betting levies, were
volatile and often unpopular and were a route to increase taxes
outside the control of a centralised system.
LOCAL INCOME TAX AND VAT
133. The Scotland Act 2012 introduced
the Scottish rate of income tax (SRIT), which is expected to be
implemented in April 2016. The rate paid by Scottish taxpayers
will be calculated by reducing the basic, higher and additional
rates of Income Tax by 10 pence in the pound and adding a new
Scottish rate set by the Scottish Parliament. A SRIT of 10% would
mean no change from the UK rates. However, a SRIT of 9% would
mean the rates paid by Scottish taxpayers were lower and a Scottish
rate of 11% would mean they were higher.[259]
IPPR North recommended this arrangement in England:
Ten per cent of the income tax take
in each of the combined authorities should be assigned to those
authorities with a corresponding reduction in the central government
grants to their constituent local authorities.[260]
Another suggested local tax was VAT.
Stephen Hughes said it was a better incentive, because "VAT
is much more directly related to value added. It is not dependent
on a particular type of growth".[261]
134. Arrangements have been developed
to allow the devolved nations to introduce new taxes, as well
to take control of business rates, stamp duty and, in the case
of Scotland, part of income tax. As we expect fiscal devolution
in England would in the short term be restricted to a handful
of areas the opportunity is available to replicate some of the
Scottish and Welsh arrangements in areas in England with the capacity
to take advantage of these resources and to implement projects
with the potential to generate good returns on investment.
At the minimum fiscal devolution should empower these authorities
to introduce relatively low-yield taxes. A range of suggestions
includes betting taxes and landfill and hotel duties.
135. Recognising what is happening
in Scotland and Wales we see a case in the long term for examining
the apportioning in a similar manner to Scotland a percentage
of income tax or VAT to groups of authorities covering significant
geographical areas in England. We recognise, however, this is
an extension of the fiscal devolution on which we have not taken
detailed evidence. We would not want consideration of devolving
income tax and VAT to hold up fiscal devolution of property taxes,
but Government and local authorities should evaluate the proposals.
Evaluation of devolution of these taxes could and should form
part of the comprehensive assessment of the operation of any fiscal
devolution and decentralisation we have recommended to be carried
out after the first wave of fiscal devolution has been implemented
and which we describe in the previous chapter.
FEES AND CHARGES
136. If the principle of fiscal devolution
to local authorities is accepted, the justification for detailed
financial constraints on local authorities falls down. One example
is the constraint on the level of fees and charges local authorities
can levy. We recognise that there are risksfor example,
where a local authority is the sole supplier of a service for
which it can charge. Local authorities are currently limited to
charging only what they need to recover in costs. Central Government
is, however, going to have to learn to trust local government
and their local electors, and as a first step it could use a devolution
framework and fiscal agreements to set limits to allow local authorities
to charge, for example, more than the cost of providing a service
and to allow authorities greater freedom to apply these resources.
137. We recommend that as part of
a devolution framework and in fiscal agreements the Government
provide for the relaxation of the current controls on the levels
of fees and charges local authorities can charge for services
and the purposes to which the income generated can be disbursed.
Borrowing
138. Those authorities to which fiscal
responsibilities are devolved should be able to demonstrate fiscal
competence and management, and a key objective of the process
would be economic growth. The process would allow them a greater
range of revenue streams. On enhanced borrowing powers, the LFC
said:
· the
Government should distinguish between borrowing that will be used
to promote growth or reduce public expenditure and thus be repaid,
and other kinds of debt;
· in
light of the robust and effective prudential borrowing regime,
GLA Group borrowing ceilings should be removed;
· the
Mayor and London's local authorities should determine which Tax
Increment Financing (TIF) projects to proceed with in London,
within the prudential borrowing code.[262]
Under current prudential borrowing arrangements
local authorities can borrow for capital expenditure without obtaining
prior Government approval. Local government officers assess the
sustainability of borrowing and set limits in line with the prudential
code, which requires councils to have the financial capacity to
repay debt, as borrowing is unsecured by assets.[263]
Newcastle University noted the precedent being set once again
in Wales:
The UK Government accepts that the
Welsh Assembly Government should have new capital borrowing arrangements
subject to a proposed referendum on income tax powers. The Welsh
Government will also be offered early access to limited capital
borrowing in order to fund immediate improvements to the M4 Motorway.[264]
TAX INCREMENT FINANCING
139. Earn Back and Gain Share are tax
increment financing (TIF) schemes now in place in Manchester and
Cambridge respectively. The GMCA said its model:
allows us to capture a proportion
of the growth generated as a result of our local investment in
transport infrastructure for reinvestment. This is based on a
formula linked to changes in rateable values over time at the
Greater Manchester level, which provides a revenue stream over
30 years, provided that additional GVA is created relative to
the agreed baseline. This therefore provides an additional incentive
for Greater Manchester to prioritise local government spending
to maximise economic growth.[265]
The Department for Communities and Local
Government said that the business rates retention scheme now gave
all councils unfettered access to tax increment financing by enabling
them to retain and borrow against future business rates.[266]
Core Cities told us its members needed access to a wider range
of devolved taxes in order to fund further TIF schemes and allocate
finance over longer periods.[267]
It added:
Government should not [
] be
concerned about large increases in borrowing. The use of the Prudential
Code is a robust process, and the numbers of viable schemes on
which cities would feel able to use mechanisms like TIF is relatively
small in the context of national borrowing and spending.
It also said local areas should determine
which TIF projects to proceed with, again within the prudential
borrowing code.[268]
The GMCA also referred to "the strong financial stewardship
of local government" and said that the Treasury could be
reassured about the affordability of borrowing within the PBF.[269]
As we have noted in previous chapters, the Department made plain
that further decentralisation should support deficit reduction.[270]
Professor Andy Pike from Newcastle University took issue with
the deficit reduction test, however, noting that
of course one of the easiest ways
to reduce the deficit is not to borrow at all, but where does
that leave the counties and the cities in terms of investing and
putting in place the future conditions for growth?[271]
140. One key aspect of fiscal devolution
is its focus on stimulating economic growth. Local authorities
in England wanting to grow their economies may therefore need
to borrow to invest. Given the Government's focus on deficit reduction,
however, we recognise that a general relaxation of the rules on
borrowing is not appropriate at this stage. But those local authorities
that negotiate a fiscal agreement with the Government will have
had to demonstrate strategic financial management and competence.
Such authorities should therefore have access to greater and
more flexible borrowing powersfor the purposes of capital
investment in projects clearly and quantifiably designed to stimulate
growth. Enhanced powers should remain within the stringent prudential
borrowing code, however, ensuring authorities have the means and
capacity to meet their annual borrowing costs. This would allow
them to pursue the innovative approach to borrowing that the Government
has, commendably, negotiated with Greater Manchester, allowing
it to benefit from increased tax take. Greater local revenue streams
would enable local authorities to borrow to invest and so increase
their tax yield and reinvest in further schemes. Devolved
areas should have the power to determine what TIF projects to
introduce without the need for Treasury approval but within the
prudential borrowing code. Given the limited number of projects
to which this would apply, this should be achievable in practice.
HOUSING REVENUE ACCOUNT
141. Core Cities, among others, also
wanted the Government to raise the Housing Revenue Account borrowing
cap, which it described as "an unnecessary threshold which
restricts growth and construction, and sets limits on local self-determination".[272]
The LGA told us that reforming the classification of council borrowing
for housing would bring the UK into line with Europe in the way
it classifies this kind of borrowing and end the current preoccupation
with where the borrowing sits for accounting purposes, rather
than the value attained for investment. Sir Merrick Cockell from
the LGA added that:
Some research has been done by Capital
Economics into the impact of lifting the cap, and the belief is
that if we lifted the cap, we are talking about (councils having
an additional) £7 billion (to invest) over five years. They
believe that that is not going to have any impact on the market.[273]
In our report, Financing of New Housing
Supply, we recommended that:
that the Government lift the cap
on local authorities' borrowing for housing, and allow councils
to borrow in accordance with the Prudential Code [
] The
cap is already unnecessary, and further borrowing restrictions
would have a detrimental impact upon the contribution councils
can make to new housing supply.[274]
The Government responded saying:
Our reforms must not jeopardise
the Government's first economic priority, which is to reduce the
national deficit. Borrowing made possible by any income stream,
including housing rents, must be affordable not just locally but
within the national fiscal framework.[275]
142. We reiterate our recommendation
in a previous report that the Government lift the cap on local
authorities' borrowing for housing. We believe this should be
universally applied.
National fiscal implications
and management
143. Throughout our inquiry witnesses
emphasised that any increased tax yields or borrowing would be
spent oninvested ininfrastructure projects or, indeed,
public services. This has implications for the UK's gross national
spending limits, particularly, Total Managed Expenditure (TME).
TME covers all current and capital spending carried out by the
central Government, local authorities and public enterprises.
It comprises Departmental-Expenditure Limits, spending that Government
departments control, and Annually Managed Expenditure (AME). AME
includes locally financed public expenditure, funded by council
tax and other local sources.[276]
144. When we put the impact of fiscal
devolution on national spending to Professor Travers, Chair of
the LFC, he said:
so long as we have a public spending
control system of the kind we do [
] and we now have one
set all the way out to 2018/19 [
] if a part of the country
were given some fiscal independence or autonomy and were able
to grow its economy faster and then spend more, that extra spending
will always count against the preordained total. There is no way
out.[277]
He explained:
That is why in the Finance Commission
we effectively put in a thinly disguised argument for some derogationsome
exemption from these rulesat least for investment. If this
money were generated by city regions as a result of these reforms
going through, and they were then able to invest in their infrastructurein
tramways or, frankly, any physical capitalthe money markets
and the eight ratings agencies would tell the difference between
that and borrowing to fund day-to-day spending.[278]
Professor Travers added that "the
way the Office for National Statistics measures public expenditure
is entirely ordained by classifications issues, which I am sure
they would say were fitting with international accounting standards".[279]
Both Professor Travers and Rob Whiteman from CIPFA told us other
countries had a more restricted definition of public debt in their
control totals. Professor Travers cited Germany and the United
States as examples. While acknowledging these were federal counties,
he noted that in the US total public spending funded by taxation
was "definitely not something that the President starts with
and says, 'This will be a total we will work down from'".[280]
145. We put these points to the Minister,
Greg Clark, and he too linked them to those accounting rules,
which he said assumed a certain growth trajectory whereby, if
Manchester or Liverpool grew faster than the average, it was at
the expense of somewhere else. He urged us to reflect on how those
conventions did not allow for the association of growth and revenue
with particular places.[281]
With the further Scottish devolution in mind, we asked him whether
TME could be raised to take account of what Scotland decided to
spend (rather than trigger an offsetting reduction in England).
He said:
That will be a decision that the
Government has to take: whether to expand it or whether to accommodate
it (increased spending).[282]
146. Growth in one area of England
does not mean reduced growth elsewhere. Fiscal devolution focused
on local growth may involve increased local spending financed
from local or national taxes, borrowing or voluntary contributions
through business levies. Under the current rules limiting gross
expenditure, this would have to be offset by a reduction in expenditure.
Applying that requirement to infrastructure projects would be
unjustified. While we accept that all governments have to manage
the resources taken by the public sector, we think it would be
regrettable if the control system were used to hobble fiscal devolution
in England. It has not obstructed fiscal devolution to Scotland
and Wales. We recommend that the Government clarify how
the controls on UK public expenditure will apply to fiscal devolution
to Scotland and Wales and whether similar arrangements could be
put in place for local authorities in England.
147. There are perhaps three ways
in which the problem could be addressed. First, local authority
expenditure on capital projects designed to stimulate economic
growth could be taken out of the control total. It would be distinguishable
by the ratings agencies, and would be used to invest in growth
projects, a potentially virtuous circle. Second, the Government
could agree to raise Total Managed Expenditure to accommodate
expenditure devolved to local authorities in England. A third
way would be to decrease central Government spending.
- No Government having accepted
fiscal devolution to Scotland and Wales should allow the Treasury's
fiscal control system focused on gross expenditure to require
every additional pound of additional public expenditure in Scotland
and Wales to be offset pound-for-pound by a reduction in spending
in England. Nor should such a perverse arrangement apply to additional
public expenditure determined under fiscal devolution in England.
Where such expenditure is fully funded by increased local taxes
and charges a gross control of public expenditure cannot be justified.
Fully funded expenditure does not increase the deficit.
211 Raising the Capital: the report of the London Finance Commission
(May 2013); the Mayor of London established the London Finance
Commission in July 2012; it was chaired by Professor Tony Travers
of the London School of Economics, who in a personal capacity
gave evidence to this inquiry twice. Back
212
'London and England's largest cities join to call for greater devolution to drive economic growth'
Greater London Authority press release, 30 September 2013; and
Core Cities (FDC0008) para 3.10; the Core Cities are Birmingham,
Manchester, Nottingham, Bristol, Sheffield, Newcastle, Leeds and
Liverpool. Back
213
Raising the Capital: the report of the London Finance Commission,
p 9 Back
214
Raising the Capital: the report of the London Finance Commission,
pp 9, 71 Back
215
Raising the Capital: the report of the London Finance Commission,
pp 11, 64, 65 Back
216
Valuation Office Agency, "How are my rates calculated?",
accessed 19 May 2014 Back
217
Leeds City Council (FDC0025) p 4 Back
218
Q193 Back
219
Q153 Back
220
Q352 Back
221
Qq 351, 354; see also Q192 [Cllr Watson]. Back
222
Q195 Back
223
LCCI (FDC0019) para 25 Back
224
Greater Birmingham Chambers of Commerce (FDC0016) pp 2, 3 Back
225
Qq126, 150 Back
226
Q354 Back
227
Q352 Back
228
Q393; see also Q317 [Darren Johnson AM]; Q354 [Cllr Nick Forbes]. Back
229
Growth and Infrastructure Act 2013, section 29 Back
230
For example, "Small shops 'to pay as supermarkets save £1bn on rates'",
The Independent, 29 October 2013 Back
231
Q399 Back
232
LCCI (FDC0019)
para 25 Back
233
Q155 Back
234
Q222 Back
235
Q157 Back
236
Raising the Capital: the report of the London Finance Commission,
p 11 Back
237
Q504 Back
238
Q505 Back
239
Q373 Back
240
GMCA (FDC0006) para 4.2 Back
241
Q507 Back
242
Department for Communities and Local Government, "No Council Tax revaluation tax rises pledge ministers",
accessed 20 May 2014 Back
243
"Council tax revaluation 'would hit poorest the hardest'",
The Guardian, accessed 16 June 2014 Back
244
Q216. See also Leeds City Council (FDC0025) p 4 Back
245
Wolverhampton City Council (FDC0024)
para 8 Back
246
Raising the Capital: the report of the London Finance Commission,
p 67 Back
247
IPPR North (FDC0020) p 5 Back
248
Leeds City Council (FDC0025) p 4 Back
249
Q278 Back
250
Q307 Back
251
See paragraph 48. Back
252
Q420 Back
253
GMCA (FDC0006) para 4.3 Back
254
HM Revenue and Customs, "Devolved taxation in Scotland",
accessed 2 May 2014 Back
255
At para 19 Back
256
Raising the Capital: the report of the London Finance Commission,
p 71 Back
257
LGA (FDC0005) para 37.2 Back
258
Q120 Back
259
See HM Revenue and Customs, "Scottish rate of income tax",
accessed 14 May 2014. Back
260
IPPR North (FDC0020) para 4 Back
261
Q334; see also Qq279-281 [Boris Johnson]. Back
262
Raising the Capital: the report of the London Finance Commission,
p 10; further information on the prudential code, p 50. Back
263
See Newcastle University (FDC0009) para 9.6. Back
264
Newcastle University (FDC0009) para 9.4 Back
265
GMCA (FDC0006) para 3.2 Back
266
DCLG (FDC0014) para 20 Back
267
Core Cities (FDC0008) para 3.8 Back
268
Core Cities (FDC0008) paras 3.8, 3.10 Back
269
GMCA (FDC0006) para 8.2; see also Q316 [Darren Johnson AM]. Back
270
DCLG (FDC0014) para 4 Back
271
Q83 Back
272
Core Cities (FDC0008) para 3.7; see also Wolverhampton City Council
(FDC0024) para 9, London Chamber of Commerce and Industry (FDC0019)
para 2, and LGA (FDC0005) para 29.3. Back
273
Q407 Back
274
Communities and Local Government Committee, Eleventh Report of
Session 2010-12, Financing of New Housing Supply, HC 1652, para
93 Back
275
Department for Communities and Local Government, Government
Response to the Communities and Local Government Committee's Report
on Financing of New Housing Supply, Cm 8401, July 2012, para
16 Back
276
House of Commons Scrutiny Unit, Finance Glossary, pp 1, 5, 13;
see also Politics.co.uk "Public spending", accessed
20 May 2014. Back
277
Q426 Back
278
Q430 Back
279
Q432 Back
280
Q442 Back
281
Q510 Back
282
Q514 Back
|