Draft Bribery Bill - Joint Committee on the Draft Bribery Bill Contents


Memorandum submitted by Professor Jeremy Horder (BB01)

  This is a note from Professor Jeremy Horder, Law Commissioner for England and Wales. I was responsible for the Law Commission Report, "Reforming Bribery" (Law Commission No 313) which led to the draft legislation currently being considered.

  It may assist the Committee, and save time, if I make some comments on a few differences between the Government's draft Bill, and the Law Commission Bill ("the Lawcom Bill"). I apologise if these comments seem to appear in a somewhat random order.

GENERAL COMMENT

  1.  The Commission is delighted that its recommendations, that followed wide consultation, have been influential in shaping the current Bill to the extent that they have.

CLAUSE 4 (BRIBING A FOREIGN PUBLIC OFFICIAL)

  1.  This clause, which otherwise closely follows the Lawcom Bill, omits the excusatory defence (Lawcom Bill, clause 5) to this offence that the Commission recommended.

  This defence would have applied when the accused (the burden of proof being on him or her) mistakenly but reasonably believed that making the payment was lawful, where his or her reasonable belief followed the taking of steps to ascertain the legal position.

  "Ignorance of law is no excuse" is a well-known maxim, but the maxim refers, of course, to the law of one's own country, not to the domestic law of another jurisdiction ("Ignorance of the law might be an excuse" would be a better maxim in the latter case). The Law Commission concluded that, in fairness to businesses and individuals, perhaps seeking to do a particular kind of business in a country for the first time, they ought to be excused conviction for so serious an offence as bribery when, for example, they had been given legal advice from UK lawyers that making a particular payment was lawful in that country.

  However, I perfectly understand the reasons that the Government has omitted this clause (clause 5) of the Lawcom Bill. During our consultation, it proved unpopular with both the OECD and anti-corruption groups. Some members of the judiciary, whilst sympathetic to the aim, were uneasy about departure from the "ignorance of the law is no excuse" maxim.

  For our part, (a) we could not see how the excuse would be abused, given the stringent test for satisfying it, (b) we thought it would be likely to arise only rarely, and (c) we thought that it did something to strike a balance between the need to combat bribery with firm action, and the need to ensure that both companies and individuals were not unfairly labelled as, in effect, "corrupt", when they had only done what they reasonably believed to be perfectly lawful in the country in question.

  There are no easy answers. I merely wish to highlight our contrary view on this difficult issue.

CLAUSE 5 (FAILURE OF A COMMERCIAL ORGANISATION TO PREVENT BRIBERY).

  1.  Whose negligence counts? To commit the offence under clause 5, a commercial organisation must "negligently" fail to prevent bribery by one of its employees or agents anywhere in the world. Whose negligence matters?

  The Lawcom Bill [clause 7(1)(c)] spoke of the negligence of, "any person…connected with or employed by [the business], whose functions…included preventing [relevant persons] from committing [bribery] offences". The Government's Bill replaces this [clause 5(1)(c)] with a reference to negligence on the part of "a responsible person, or a number of such persons taken together".

  I believe that the Commission's original clause 7, referring to "any" person, could have been read so as to produce the same result as in clause 5(1)(c). The Government's Bill is obviously clearer on the point. The point is that a number of individuals within a firm (perhaps one or more here, and one or more in a foreign country where the bribe is offered) may, through their conduct, collectively contribute to what amounts to a culpable failure to prevent that bribery.

  In practical terms, there may be advantages (as well as disadvantages) to the prosecution in alleging that the conduct of more than one person in the company contributed to the commission of bribery. It means that the company in question cannot perhaps quite so easily seek to retain shareholder and market credibility simply by hanging one individual out to dry, possibly dismissing them for negligence in advance of the case, having heaped all the blame for what happened on that luckless individual. In some countries, there have been concerns that prosecutors are prone to accept such action, in lieu of prosecution, which may not serve the public interest. Taking such a "multi-party" course, in prosecuting, also makes more likely the fulfilment of the prosecutor's "dream ticket", where those giving evidence about fault all seek to blame each other.

  2.  Collective fault. Clause 5(1)(c) will inevitably invite comparison with the analogous part (section 1) of the Corporate Manslaughter and Corporate Homicide Act 2007. That Act requires the relevant negligence to be substantially attributable in part to failures on the part of "senior management" [section 1(3)]. Neither the Lawcom Bill, nor the Government Bill, contains any such restriction. That may not be a bad thing, in that—as is sometimes the case with price fixing, for example—both the wrong (bribery) and the failure of supervision may well occur at lower, perhaps local, levels of management.

  However, it should be noted that the presumption at common law is that with a fault based offence the fault must be attributable to the directors (or equivalent persons) who can in effect be identified with the company itself: the so-called "identification" doctrine. There is currently nothing express in the Bill to stop the courts reading that doctrine in to clause 5, and hence requiring that "a responsible person" etc means someone at that high level. However, the wording of clause 5(5), which deals with a situation where a director (or equivalent) is the one who has been negligent—see 3. below—suggests that for the courts to take such a course would be wrong. Clause 5(5) implies that the offence can be committed through the negligence of someone other than a "senior officer".

  There is perhaps a case for being clearer on the point in the Bill than either the Law Commission, or (following the Commission's lead) the Government, have been; but it may be ok because nowadays the courts take a more context-specific approach to interpreting the nature and scope of corporate criminal liability.

  The Law Commission is currently considering the legal status of the identification doctrine, as a part of a general project on corporate criminal liability.

  3.  The "adequate systems defence". Clause 5(4) is absolutely crucial to the legitimacy of the offence created by clause 5. It introduces an "ongoing compliance" element to the essentially retributive and deterrent function of the offence. In other words, the message is not simply, "don't let carelessness lead your employees or agents to commit bribery"; the message is, "put systems in place capable of sustaining an anti-bribery corporate culture in your firm".

  The OECD were understandably anxious that there should be greater clarity over what would count as an "adequate system", something important not just from their point of view, but from the perspective of firms seeking guidance. It was simply not possible for the Law Commission to address this issue in the time available.

  There is a case for saying that, even if it reaches the statute book, this clause should not be brought into force until some work has been done with the CBI, other business representatives, anti-corruption experts, and others, to hammer out some basic standards and procedures.

  There are some serious issues to be addressed.

  For example, there is the "red tape" problem. If an "adequate system" is one in which every payment/gift, no matter how small, must be logged, this will create major administrative problems for global companies whose employees or agents move frequently across borders or in and out of (air)ports, where small "grease" payments may have to paid routinely (but which would never be the subject of prosecutions). Some may scoff at such an objection, but the question is whether the generation of paper mountains in respect of conduct that will never be subject to prosecution is worth the effort.

  Secondly, there is "external supervision" problem. The Woolf Committee recommended that current and prospective contractors should all be interviewed to check compliance issues (recommendation 11). Nice idea; but how realistic is meeting that ideal for a company with hundreds or even thousands of contractors, perhaps changing daily or weekly, across the globe? How realistic is meeting that ideal, in cost terms, for a small company which (reasonably) may be asked for compensation for travel/accommodation costs from the contractor who is to be interviewed, if that small company cannot itself visit its prospective contractor?

  In practice, it is likely to be specialist lawyers or other professionals in the area who do any such interviewing, or who engage in corruption policing on behalf of their client more generally. They will not offer their services free of charge.

  Moreover, there is the problem of whether interviewing will in fact reveal defects in suppliers' own procedures, or whether some other kind of evidence is needed if the whole process is to be meaningful. In general, site visits are considered to be more effective, but again, these are costly and time-consuming. Moreover, only a party in a dominant bargaining position may be able to insist on them.

  Accordingly, there is a risk that big firms will come to dominate certain markets in certain countries, amongst other reasons, because smaller firms do not have the "clout" or the resources to meet the cost of compliance and to make compliance meaningful. Their choices will be: quit the market, or cut corners through bribery. The consumer may not benefit in that situation.

  I should stress that these are not insuperable problems; but the solutions must be thought through, on the basis of wide consultation, and a careful look at what is done in, eg, the USA. We cannot afford to lead businesses into the classic regulatory "dead end", where businesses incur costs and waste time formally complying with procedures imposed from on high that, because they are regarded by almost everyone as mere formalities, amount to "box ticking" that does nothing to achieve the desired goal.

  4.  Directors' negligence and the adequate systems defence. Clause 5(5) was something suggested to the Law Commission by the OECD during consultation. It is meant to be a purely common sense measure. What is says is, in effect, that if the directors responsible for drawing up systems to prevent bribery themselves negligently fail to prevent it, it cannot be right that the directors should subsequently be able to employ the adequate systems defence.

  I believe that this clause has proved to be unpopular in some quarters, because it is regarded as discriminating against small firms who have no "middle management" to whom the responsibility for preventing bribery can be devolved.

  It may be that the criminal law does sometimes discriminate against small firms, but I believe that this is not an instance of it.

  Inevitably, a small firm with no middle management must take responsibility for compliance at directorial level, whether that be health and safety, environmental, or bribery-related compliance. That is just a matter of logic, really.

  The "adequate systems" defence is a defence aimed at larger firms with middle managers and agents (with devolved responsibilities) operating partly independently of direct control at board level. It may well be far more cost-effective for a small firm to take responsibility for compliance at board level, rather than employing a middle manager to take it on; but with responsibility comes the prospect of liability.

  In any event, with very small firms, any bribery committed on their behalf may well raise a suspicion of knowledge or intention at board level. In such cases, the company—and/or the individual directors can be prosecuted directly under clauses 1 or 4.

May 2009








 
previous page contents next page

House of Lords home page Parliament home page House of Commons home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009
Prepared 28 July 2009