Draft House of Lords Reform Bill - Joint Committee on the Draft House of Lords Reform Bill Contents


Examination of Witnesses

Professor John Curtice and Professor David Denver (QQ 308-332)

Professor John Curtice, University of Strathclyde, and Professor David Denver, Lancaster University

Q308   The Chairman: Thank you very much for coming. You know the scope of this inquiry and what we are at. Would you like to say something to start off with, or would you like to launch straight into questions?

Professor John Curtice: I think we have agreed that Professor Denver will go first. I have not submitted written evidence. I was asked by the Committee to appear, so I wanted to make a small statement to give you some idea of what I am willing to talk to, but we have agreed that Professor Denver is going to make a rather more wide-ranging statement, so with your permission, Lord Chairman, I think he would like to talk first.

Professor David Denver: I was asked to look at some questions, most of which have been done to death already, as far as I can hear, but I will quickly skip through them anyway and give you my perspective on them. The first question is what is the best form of electoral system. The answer, of course, is that there is no such thing as a best system; it all depends on hat you want to achieve. If you want a broad representation of opinion, you might go for one thing; if you want the ability to produce majority Governments, you would go for another; if you want close links between representatives and the represented, you would go for another. Except, of course, that the electoral systems do not always produce what even people such as John and I expect, hence we have in Scotland a majority Government elected on the Additional Member system, which surprised lots of people, especially me. And, of course, we have a coalition in Westminster on the basis of first past the post. So life is always interesting for the electoral analysts and you never know what is going to happen.

None the less, in the draft Bill there is a commitment to PR, and that seems to imply that what the Government—or the people concerned with this—are seeking is some kind of broad representation of opinion. It does mention list systems as a possible option. Personally, I would be deeply opposed to such a system. It is simply a party stitch-up, because the parties control who gets elected and non-party candidates are virtually excluded—well, they are excluded. Party list systems are awful, in my view.

STV is proposed, as we have heard at great length. People know the good points. It provides a broad range of opinions being represented and it confers power on voters rather than parties, at least in the electoral process itself. It does not take it away from parties entirely, as we heard, when it comes to nominating candidates, but it gives a bit more power to voters, I think, at that point. On the other hand, people have to accept that there are problems with STV. The biggest one does not apply in this case, which is that it does not confer decisive governmental power, and at that point it transfers power from the people to the politicians. That seems to me to be a dreadful thing, but as I said that does not apply here. It is also associated with weaker links between representatives and the represented. I do not think that matters much here either, because of the very large districts proposed. Some people talk about elected Lords doing constituency work. That just seems to me to be bonkers. One disadvantage also seems to be that STV might seem complicated, but in fact it worked very well in Scotland when it was introduced in 2007 for the Scottish local elections.

1.8 per cent of ballots were rejected, which is a bit more than you would get on first past the post, but it compares with the Irish experience. They have been doing it since the 1920s. So you get a wee bit more rejected ballots, but nothing very dramatic—certainly not as dramatic as the Scottish election produced for the Scottish Parliament in 2007.

Q309   Lord Trefgarne: Unless you are part of the 1.8 per cent.

Professor David Denver: Unless you are part of the 1.8 per cent. But when it gets to 4 or 5, as it did in the Scottish Parliament election, then you really have got problems. One of the reasons for rejected ballots, and another problem, is that it requires lengthy ballot papers—very lengthy if you are going to have seven people, as I will come back to. There is clear evidence that when people are voting using STV, there is alphabetical voting. People placed at the top of the list clearly do better. Many fine Labour councillors in Scotland were defeated because they happened to be called Young or Wright, or things like that. That is very clear, and nobody has really come up with an answer.

Lord Trimble: There is an answer. We had a rash of this in Northern Ireland. You change your name by Deed Poll.

Professor David Denver: You can change your name, that is right. It is interesting to note also that, no matter where the level being employed, most voters using STV give three choices and no more. They go one, two, three and then they stop. Only real nerds like me go a lot further. The evidence is absolutely clear. Some people go on—there are nutters like me who will go on and on—but Ireland is the case in point, as is Scotland at the last election. After three, there is a very big drop-off. That is just for interest, really. I do not know what relevance it has for your deliberations. Of course, STV requires large electoral districts—very large in this case, as you know, with only 80 to be elected across the country.

On the point about timing, the draft Bill proposes elections at the same time as general elections. I can see the reasons for this. The point about turnout was made earlier, but that seems to imply that people would not bother voting for the House of Lords if it was not on the same day as the general election, which is a sad assumption. A more realistic reason for it is cost. It costs a lot of money to run an election, and running a separate one would be expensive. I accept that, but none the less the Committee might like to consider the argument that coterminous elections lead to confusion in the electorate. There are confusing messages coming across and campaign material, for example. It leads inevitably to the downgrading of the less important election. We have lots of experience of general elections and local elections held at the same time. When that happens, you hear nothing about the local elections. They are lost, and that seriously downgrades the whole function of elections, which is to hold people to account, including on local councils. And, of course, please note that in Scotland local elections have recently been decoupled from the Scottish Parliament elections, precisely for these reasons of confusion and so on.

My penultimate point is about electoral districts. We have already heard that multi-Member districts are required and a minimum of three are required for STV to work, really. In general, if you want more representative people elected, the more the better. The Bill proposes five to seven. The problem with the upper limit is quite a simple practical one, which is the size of the ballot paper. If you have seven, with three parties, that is 21 for a start, before you go any further. It is always possible—it is difficult to know how to put this—that the more representative it is, the greater the chances that people with, shall we say, eccentric opinions would get elected. You might say that that is fine, or that it is not fine.

I had a think about making the electoral districts based on groups of counties. On the whole, I think that is probably the sensible thing, because parliamentary constituencies are usually within counties anyway, so it will not complicate the boundaries too much.

Finally, on by-elections, obviously people will die, given the 15-year term, but by-elections would be really silly, because it would be really expensive for not very much, it seems to me. The Bill proposes to replace whoever dies, or whatever, with the next person of the same party. This bespeaks a fixation with party that is contrary to the spirit of STV, and I fail to see why the replacement should not simply be the next person in line, as it were, irrespective of party. There, I will stop.

Professor John Curtice: I was asked to talk specifically about the actual system, and particularly about the Scottish experience of the single transferable vote in 2007. A lot of this is probably very familiar to you, but just so you understand, let me start with a little bit about the presumptions on which I am operating. The first presumption on which I am operating—I have heard some debate about this—is that it is now probably the case that if a body is going to be regarded as legitimate, by which I mean that it is a body that most of the public accept has the right to be involved in the law-making process for the rest of society, that body probably has to be elected these days. If you want to get some idea of this, for example when British Social Attitudes last asked people about their attitudes towards the House of Lords, I have to tell you that between about a fifth and a quarter wanted to get rid of it entirely, but among the remainder only 10 per cent felt that the House of Lords should be entirely appointed. Many were willing to accept the idea of a mixed House, but there is very clear evidence from polling data that in today's society, people are doubtful about a Chamber that does not have an element of election to it. This is the presumption from which the Government is starting.

However, I also accept that the House of Lords has at least developed, perhaps partly by accident, a role that is now valued as, in some senses, the principal revising Chamber of the two Houses, and certainly a revising Chamber that occasionally is willing to tackle the detail of a Bill without necessarily debating it entirely on party lines, and to consider whether the technical merits of the Bill are adequate. That rests, in part at least, on the fact that it is a body that is widely acknowledged to contain much in the way of renowned professional expertise, much of which is represented in this Room. There is clearly no guarantee that once we move towards a system of election, we will necessarily get the same body of professional expertise among elected politicians. Therefore, one potential risk of moving towards election is that maybe we lose, to some degree, the body of professional expertise. Certainly an obvious danger is that, whatever electoral system we have, the expectation in most elections is that most elected representatives are going to be representatives of parties, so the elections tend to be about party. There is therefore a clear risk a system of election will increase the partisanship of the upper Chamber.

In a sense, therefore, I am starting from the basis of accepting that we probably have to have a House that is pretty much elected, but if we are to preserve its ability to do the job for which it has become renowned, we need to try to minimise the extent to which partisanship becomes a feature and, in so far as possible, at least not to make it any more difficult than necessary for those with acknowledged professional expertise to become Members.

If you come from that standpoint, you can certainly see why people would want to choose the single transferable vote. Point No. 1 is that all votes are for candidates, formally they are not for parties, and if I give a first preference to, for example, a Labour candidate, that does absolutely nothing to enhance the prospects of any other Labour candidate being elected. In this respect that extent it is pretty much unique among systems that are regarded as proportional. It is very much a personal system. At the same time, however, as long as you have reasonably sized districts, it produces a reasonable degree of proportionality. Almost unlike any other proportional system, the other ingredient is that it is a system of transferable votes. To some degree, therefore, it provides an incentive to parties and to candidates to appeal for lower preferences from those who are not supporters of their party. To that extent, therefore, both because it is a more proportional system—therefore it is unlikely to create a majority in the House—and given the nature of the electoral system, you can see how, to some degree at least, STV would help to reduce the partisanship of elections, because you will be looking at people who to some degree have had an incentive to appeal across party lines, and because you have a House where it is probably not true that any party is going to have a majority, so to that extent the search for consensus is being highlighted.

You can see why you might choose STV. The question is whether it works in practice. Although STV is not used in many places, it so happens that the one thing we know about the system is that it produces very different consequences in different contexts. In Malta, it is associated with one of the strongest two-party systems in Western Europe, with very little in the way of willingness from voters to transfer ballots across party lines. In contrast, in Ireland it is associated with one of the weaker party systems in Western Europe and a system in which voters are very keen and willing to vote on the basis of the personal attributes of candidates, not least whether or not they have done a favour for them recently. Therefore, we have to be very careful about making any inference about the way in which the system might operate if it were introduced in Great Britain. I have to say here, with due respect to colleagues in Northern Ireland, that given the very different party system there, we cannot even infer very much from Northern Ireland about what would happen on this side of the water in an STV election.

One place where you can gain some guidance is from Scotland, which introduced the single transferable vote for local elections in 2007. The other think about it that is interesting, given the Government's proposals, as David has already referred to, is that these elections were held at the same time as another election that most people regarded as more important, and certainly grabbed the media attention. Therefore, the Government's proposed context was replicated in 2007 and interestingly is not going to be replicated in 2012, which I suspect might be important. We will come on to that further.

There are some differences. I have heard some people say that you cannot have STV in three-Member constituencies. Oh yes you can; Scotland has them in spades. The deal between Labour and the Liberal Democrats meant that we had very small wards. They are all three or four-Member wards. They are smaller than those proposed in the Bill. This makes a difference, because, for example, with such small wards lots of parties put up just one candidate. That affects the nature of the system and the choice that is given to voters.

The other thing to say is that Scotland has four significant parties rather than three. The more fractured the party system, the more likely it is that voters will cast preferences for candidates from more than one party. So you need to bear that in mind.

Given those caveats, this is about as good as it gets. Given that there was this novel experience, I was lucky in being able to persuade a funding council to get respondents to the Scottish Social Attitudes survey in 2007 to complete a mock ballot paper. We asked them to replicate on a mock ballot paper, which had the names of all their local candidates, how they voted in the election. Although you can tell some things from elections—David has already referred to the fact that, because we had an electronic count we know that the median voter only cast three preferences—there are lots of things we cannot tell from it. But by asking people exactly how they voted and linking it to other evidence about those people, we can learn a lot more about how people used that ballot paper and which kinds of people did so. In doing that exercise, we replicated very closely a study done of the Irish election to the Dáil in 2002, so we can begin to get some handle on how similar Scotland is to Ireland, and by extension how similar England and Wales might be, too 1-1, or is it to some degree different?

Okay. Let me just give you one or two headlines and then I am sure you will want to talk more later on. The first thing that clearly needs to be true if this system is going to work is that people need to be willing to vote for more than one party. If that transfer incentive is going to be there, we need to know that voters are going to use it. 59 per cent of people who responded to our mock ballot paper indicated that they voted for more than one party. Even among those who had more than one candidate standing for the party of their first preference, around 43 per cent of them were not necessarily ranking all the candidates of that party above the candidates of any other party. So of those voters who were faced with the possibility of just voting SNP one, two, three and going home, many did so, but a significant minority voted SNP one, Labour two, Tory three, or whatever.

The incidence of that kind of behaviour is lower than it is in Ireland, as you might expect. We are more partisan, but arguably there is enough there to suggest that there was an incentive for somebody standing to say, "I am not just a Labour candidate, but by the way I am a really good Labour candidate and I have these other personal qualities, and therefore you should vote for me."

That said, there is undoubtedly a very clear problem, which again David has already referred to. If we just take all the people who responded to our survey, we can ask how many of them said that they gave their first preference vote to a candidate who was placed higher up on the ballot paper than the candidate they gave their second preference to. If voters were doing this intelligently, you would expect that figure to be roughly 50 per cent. The answer is that among all voters it is 60 per cent. If you look at those voters who voted Labour one, two and three, or whatever, they were in a ward where Labour—it was mostly Labour—was putting up more than one candidate. They were partisan voters who just wanted to go Labour one, two and three. It is among that group of voters that alphabetic voting is very clearly happening. About 70 per cent of those voters voted alphabetically.

This is where I come back to the issue of coupling. One of the things that is very clear about comparing the Scottish data with the Irish data is that voters in Scotland were much less likely to say that they really liked the candidate that they put their No. 1 against. It was only about a fifth of voters. We asked them to give the candidate whom they gave their first preference vote to a mark out of 10 for how much they liked them. In Scotland, only 19 per cent of voters gave their first preference candidate a score of 9 or 10. In Ireland, 39 per cent did so in 2002. Undoubtedly, if you have an election in which you have partisan voters and the candidates evidently have not made that much impression on the electorate as individuals, you are certainly creating an environment in which alphabetic voting is likely to occur. I cannot prove it until we have factual evidence, but this is where I think Scotland in 2012 is going to be important. One of the potential risks of having the Lords election on the same day as a Commons election, in which all the media attention is going to be on what happens in the House of Commons, is that it will make the environment in which voters vote more partisan. I have suggested earlier that you want to minimise the partisanship of the election, whatever system you use. Secondly, you will arguably make it more difficult for individual candidates to get the profile that they need to be able to get votes on an individual basis and you are probably creating an environment in which you will maximise the incidence of alphabetical voting. I realise that there are downsides with not coupling, but I suggest that if you are really concerned to create an electoral system and an electoral environment in which voters are voting for candidates, the issue of running it alongside Commons elections at least needs thinking about. I am hoping to persuade somebody to replicate this exercise in 2012, which would give us some idea of whether, when we have a local election that is not coupled, the incidence of alphabetical voting declines. If so, I suggest that that would be very strong evidence indeed against the idea of a coupled election.

There are other ways around this, such as Robson rotation. But if you are going to have a voting system that gives voters the chance to say what they like about candidates rather than about parties, pretty much any preferential system is at least potentially at risk of suffering from alphabetical voting. The alternative is of course that parties also have to try to do something about it. The answer, perhaps particularly in Northern Ireland and in the South is to say to voters, "This is how we want you to vote: one, two, three". But arguably, that is not really voting on the basis of personality either.

Q310    The Chairman: Thank you very much. Can I start off by assuring you two gentlemen that, for many of us in this room, "party politician" is not necessarily a term of abuse?

Professor John Curtice: I entirely accept that. I am not using it as a term of abuse. I am pointing out that it is widely accepted that one of the strengths of the upper House at the moment is that it is somewhat less partisan. The truth is that partisanship has declined as a force in House of Commons voting and we now have a very rebellious lower Chamber, but historically, the upper Chamber has tended to be rather less partisan, with Peers being rather more willing historically to vote against the party line. It has been felt that that is one of the reasons why the upper House is often rather more effective than the Commons at saying, "Hang on. You may want to achieve this objective in Government, but this is not a terribly good way of going about it".

Q311    The Chairman: I do not want to follow this for too long, because I want to talk about the details of the electoral system, but I assume that you would agree that you have got to have parties, even in the upper House. You have to have a party structure and parties have to be operative, otherwise you will not get a thing through.

Professor John Curtice: Yes, exactly. In a sense, the argument that I am suggesting is that basically you need an ideal mix. Yes, of course you are going to have to have parties to organise elections and you want parties to provide a degree of organisation to the House, but you do not want parties to be so powerful that a single party can say, "This is what we want. Our chaps are going to vote for it come what may. End of argument". You want a chamber in which argument and deliberation potentially have some impact on the outcome.

Q312    The Chairman: Can I come on to the details? I have two or three questions, one of which is a slight idiot boy question, which I am sure I should know the answer to. Why do you have to have five to seven in an STV constituency?

Professor John Curtice: A basic rule of electoral systems is that the smaller the district size—the smaller the number of people elected per district—the less proportional it is. That is a basic rule, irrespective of whether it is STV, d'Hondt, Sainte-Laguë, open list, closed list or whatever. The major text on this, which did a very substantial comparison of electoral systems across the world, came to the conclusion that the most important determinant of the proportionality of the system is district size. If you have a four-Member district, you basically have to get 20 per cent of the vote to be sure of getting elected. If you go down to a seven-Member district, you only need 12.5 per cent to be sure of getting elected. It is just straight arithmetic. It is a trade-off. It is a question of how much proportionality you want. Of course, one of the things to be aware of is that even with a seven-Member district, the de facto threshold of STV—what kind of share of the vote you require before you are going to get elected—is pretty high. It is certainly higher than the de jure threshold that most list systems enforce, such as the system in Germany.

Q313    The Chairman: My impression, having heard evidence from both of you, is that on the whole you think STV would be a good electoral system for the upper House, provided that you can overcome all the difficulties about the dates on which you do it, the size of the districts and the number of seats. Is that fair?

Professor David Denver: If you want to achieve a broader range of opinions, STV is the one that does that. But then there are other problems.

Professor John Curtice: My argument to you is that, given the premises I laid out—you want a House that is not dominated by one party at any one time, but which also maximises the incentive for candidates to get election on the basis of personal popularity, because that may also be advantageous to the House—STV is certainly not an inappropriate system. You may regard some other open list preferential systems as an alternative. If you can get STV to work and you can overcome the issue of alphabetic voting, it would be difficult to find a better system. I think that the argument would be whether you found the problem with alphabetic voting so serious that you therefore wanted to reduce the degree to which voters had to choose between candidates in order to reduce that problem. That is probably where the argument is.

Q314    The Chairman: Perhaps I can abuse my position and ask one more question. Suppose that we were to go to the European size constituency and you were to have elections to the upper House on the same day as the European elections, which would not synchronise with the Commons elections. Do you think that would create more or less difficulty? Would it be desirable to have the Houses elected on different dates by different systems?

Professor David Denver: Electors are often brighter than we think. They can cope reasonably well. In the Scottish case, there was STV and then there was what is technically called MMP—mixed Member proportional. Most voters coped with it perfectly well. You get worried if there are 2, 3 or 4 per cent of spoiled ballots, but that means that 96 per cent are coping quite well. I want more elections all the time—as many as possible—so my preference is still to keep them separate, because it gives dignity to the body being elected. It gives some kind of focus on the body being elected, rather than people just having to turn up and vote for two things. Just think what would happen if we had a general election, an election for the Lords and local elections as well. We have had local elections in England on the same day as general elections the last three times, I think. I disapprove of it.

Professor John Curtice: Given the current election cycle for England and given the Fixed-Term Parliaments Bill, if this draft Bill were to be enacted in time for 2015, you would have three elections on the same day in many parts of England.

Coming back to the question, I would make two observations. We can have an interesting speculation about whether elections to the House of Lords would attract more voters than elections to the European Parliament. Holding them on the same day as elections to the European Parliament would certainly not do anything to increase the turnout to this body. It might have some benefit on the turnout for the European elections. Holding the local elections on the same day as the European Parliament elections has certainly done something for European Parliament turnout. The second thing that I would say, however, is that I suspect it would be true that if you were to hold House of Lords elections with an open list system or with STV on the same day as the European Parliament elections with a closed list system, the debate about the closed list system for the European Parliament elections would be reopened and I guarantee that you would have plenty of phone-in programmes in the run-up to the election saying, "Why can't I choose my local MEP?". As many Members here will be aware, it was a somewhat controversial decision, when it was originally made back before 1999. I suspect it would cause that issue to be reopened.

Q315    Baroness Scott of Needham Market: I have two questions. First, for Professor Denver, could you say a word or two about experience in the Scottish Parliament of having some Members elected on a constituency basis and some on a list? This question of hybridity exercises us. The second question is for both of you. You have both talked about having elections on the same day. Initially, my concerns were very much along the lines of Professor Denver's about how you get oxygen for the subordinate election. But as time has gone on, I think that this is a more important issue than we are giving it credit for. I would appreciate your thoughts on this, because it seems to me that in all our talks about primacy of the Commons we have discussed it in constitutional convention terms, whereas it seems to me that its primacy comes because the voters vote for it. They vote, on the whole, twice as much in general elections because they are voting for the Government. In a sense, its primacy comes from the people because they jolly well turn out and vote. Is there, in fact, a question not of weakening the vote for the second Chamber by having it on the same day, but almost giving it an importance that the voters would not otherwise give it?

Professor David Denver: You heard me talking about MMP, which is the mixed Member proportional system, which is what politically correct political scientists want to use instead of the additional Member system, because using additional Members implies that somehow the additional Members are kind of extra or not of the same value. That is precisely what happened in the Scottish Parliament, when it began anyway. The regional Members, as we might call them—the additional Members—were kind of looked down on by the properly elected constituency Members. The constituency Members thought they should get paid more. I think that actually passed.

Professor John Curtice: They got more expenses.

Professor David Denver: The constituency Members got more expenses, because they had more constituency work. I do not know, but I suspect that as time has passed, that kind of controversy has gone now and people just accept the fact that people are Members of the Parliament and they do not have that kind of rivalry any more.

Professor John Curtice: The truth is, David, that since the disaster suffered by the Labour Party in 2011, it will have rediscovered the advantage of allowing candidates to stand both in the constituencies and on the list—let alone anything else—because the Labour Party made its situation even worse when it suffered a disaster in May, because it meant that large numbers of people were elected on the list who had not been in the Chamber before, whereas large numbers of its Shadow Cabinet were out of the door. The days of arguments—most of which came from the Labour Party—about list MSPs being second-class MSPs north of the border are over. The Government of Wales Act was changed to make it impossible for people to stand in both ballots. I always find that slightly odd, because of course the reaction of the Conservative Party, which is also rather sniffy about list Members, was that therefore you had to stand in both. You pay your money and take your choice, but the truth is that this argument will now disappear in the light of what happened in May in Scotland.

Professor David Denver: The second point was about having elections on the same day. Were you expressing doubt about whether—

Q316    Baroness Scott of Needham Market: What I was saying was that my initial concerns were about the failure of the second and subordinate election to get oxygen. However, my bigger concern is almost the reverse—that of having a sort of second-hand turnout, whereby people are turning out to vote for the Government, and while they are at it they are casting a vote for something else. There is an issue of legitimacy that may roll on to the primacy question.

Professor David Denver: There is a very subtle point about legitimacy that is very much opposed to the point made earlier—the fact of getting a higher turnout would give more legitimacy to the Lords. Your point would be that, actually, people are not turning out to vote for the Lords at all and, as happens in local elections, they turn out to vote in the general election, because that is the most important one, and while they are there they fill in the local ballot without perhaps knowing or caring very much. It is different perspective on legitimacy—albeit a subtle one—from the point made earlier by our friend here. It is just a different way of looking at it. In the end, you have to decide. Do you want elections on the same day or not?

Professor John Curtice: The truth is that you pay your money and take your choice. Do you want to ensure that as many people as possible can vote? It is always worth remembering that Commons elections do not attract quite as much interest from the voters as they did. The House of Commons manages only 60 per cent these days, so perhaps we should not necessarily rely on that too much as a crutch. You either say, let us get as many people as possible through the polling station or you say, let us create an environment in which people actually get the chance to consider the candidates and the issues. You pay your money and take your choice. Let us be straightforward; the other obvious downside of a decoupled election is what happens if the House of Lords comes to be regarded as not being that important—and there is no guarantee that it will. We know what happens in local elections, which people do not regard as important. They say, "That rotten David Cameron, Gordon Brown or whoever is in Downing Street. I want to send a message that I am not going to vote for a Tory or Labour candidate". The whole thing therefore becomes caught up in a protest vote against the Government. There is no perfect answer to these things. It is a question of a trade-off. What I would say, however, is that it comes back to what you want to achieve. If you want to minimise the partisanship of an election and maximise the degree to which individual candidates standing in that election have a chance to impress themselves on the electorate, you probably would not go for a coupled election; but you may feel that the other considerations that we are talking about are more important.

Q317   Oliver Heald: The debate about electoral systems over the years has tended to be in the context of electing a Government or a body that has a majority, and it is therefore clear who should be in the executive positions. That is true of the Scottish elections, the general election in the UK, councils and so on. However, a slightly different exercise is required in terms of electing a second Chamber. If you have an electoral system that is designed to elect a Government and you apply it to a second Chamber, is not the effect of that to confer additional legitimacy on the second Chamber?

Professor John Curtice: I am not sure that that follows. My view is very simple. I understand the arguments in favour of majoritarian electoral systems where a Government is at stake. However, parenthetically, I would say that I regard first past the post as a rather poor way of achieving that—but that is another argument. I do not see any argument for having a majoritarian system where you are not choosing a Government and where you are indeed choosing a body to represent the views of the electorate. That would seem to be, in the case of Lords election, what it is about and that therefore there is no argument for a non-proportional system. I fully accept the argument for majoritarian systems where you want to emphasise the ability of voters to make and unmake Governments, but where that is not at stake, it is very difficult to think of an argument against a proportional system. That is the argument.

Q318   Oliver Heald: That is on a slightly different point from the question I was asking you. I may have misled you. The point is that the two main contenders in the normal argument about electoral systems are proportional representation—often STV—on the one hand, and on the other you would look at first past the post. There are competing arguments about that. But is not the question in the context of a second Chamber rather a different one. It is how to give democratic legitimacy without affecting primacy.

Professor David Denver: That is nothing to do with the electoral system. I speak as a supporter of first past the post. I do not think that people are going round saying to themselves, "Gosh, I wonder if the House of Lords is more legitimate than the House of Commons". I just do not think that that will occur to people.

Oliver Heald: Let me give an example of what I mean. If you look at the system in Australia, they have chosen a voting system, STV, but they allow a group voting ticket, which 90 per cent of electors use, and the size of constituencies varies tremendously, because it relates to states. That is a system that does not confer as much legitimacy as first past the post does here in a general election.

Professor David Denver: Indeed.

Professor John Curtice: But the point is that the Australian Senate is partly there to do a different job. It is much more analogous to the United States Senate; it is designed to give equal representation to the various component parts of the Australian federal state. If truth be told, you could regard that as an objective here, in which case you would be talking about having equal representation for Northern Ireland, Scotland, Wales and perhaps the component regions of England. That would be a different vision for an upper Chamber—perhaps a vision that we might have to revisit if devolution goes further in the United Kingdom, and particularly if it were to go further in England—but at the moment that does not seem to be on the table. You are talking about an upper Chamber that is in part designed to deliver a different function. Australia has not only compulsory voting, but also requires people to go all the way down the ballot paper. If truth be told, most people think that that is daft, and that is part of the reason why you have ended up with a block vote—in order to save voters the trouble of going 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, and wasting an awful lot of ink and increasing the risk of casting an invalid vote.

Q319   Oliver Heald: Let me put my overall proposition to you and then hear what you both think about it. If your aim was to have a House that was basically doing the same sorts of things as the House of Lords does now and you wanted to have in it eminent people with national standing as well as people with a regional flavour, you could have a closed list and you could say that it would have to have certain requirements in terms of balance, and regional requirements. However, by doing that, you would elect people but they would not have an individual mandate for an area. They would be national figures and they would have that standing. That is a very different proposition to what you would want to do for the Commons.

Professor David Denver: The mind boggles, frankly. A national list—it is kind of like "Big Brother" or "Strictly".

Professor John Curtice: Of course you could do that. That argument against it is, first, you would probably find that the public would not be too keen on it. There were grumblings in Scotland because there was a closed list system. Leaving that to one side, the argument against is that it is felt that if you have that kind of system, how will people get up the list? If truth be told, even if you have some requirements with gender zipping or whatever, it is because you are popular among your party membership, and most parties these days have some form of election for deciding the order of their lists and, therefore, the people at the top of the list will tend to be the people whom the party members like and they will tend to be partisan. I would suggest that that is not the element of the upper Chamber that you wish to exaggerate any more than you have to.

Oliver Heald: But they are the people who would get selected under any system.

Professor John Curtice: They might do, but if the view of the party's electorate differs from that of the public in terms of the order of which candidates would be elected, the same people would not necessarily get elected. I grant you that there are arguments both ways, but I have come at it very clearly. I suspect that you probably do not wish to emphasise the role of the party in order for the House to do its job effectively.

Q320   Gavin Barwell: I have two quick questions, the first of which is to Professor Denver. I want to pick him up on the issue he touched on, and on which some members of the committee had some concerns, regarding Members of and elected second House potentially taking up casework. I think that you rather colourfully described it as nonsense, or something like that. In the Scottish context, what evidence is there of list Members competing with individual constituency Members on that basis?

Professor David Denver: This caused no end of trouble because when you have a regional Member and a constituency Member from different parties, the constituency Member tends to think that the regional Member is trying to pinch his seat and is spending his or her expenses doing constituency work in order to prepare for the next election. This causes a lot of problems, because people are frightened about votes in the next election. But do not forget that in Scotland there are eight regions, which are quite small areas. If you are talking about regions of the UK for this issue, you are talking about vast regions. I can see that Members elected could try to do some pro-regional work, if you like—perhaps on behalf of the tourist board or something. But I cannot see them dealing with constituents' problems with the Department of Health or social security.

Professor John Curtice: That is probably also my view, but I am afraid that I am going to say something that will probably also be very unpopular in this Room. Given the extent to which the rest of society is being told by politicians that competition is good for us, I have no sympathy for MPs or MSPs who are worried about competition for their seats. I think that it is good for you too.

Q321   Gavin Barwell: I personally agree with that. The other question that I wanted to pick up was about the dates of the elections. You have been very honest in discussing the pros and cons. I want to put two points to you. First, I would be very interested in your view of the likely turnout if you went for the more expensive option of a stand-alone election. Obviously it will be just an educated guess. Secondly, Professor Curtice made the point about the Scottish context and how a separate election made it much easier for individuals to raise their profile. I think that you were saying that in relation to the Scottish council elections and the Scottish Parliament elections. I think that you were referring to both categories. Would you not agree that in the context of what is proposed by the Government here, the potential electoral areas are so big that it would be very difficult for anyone other than a celebrity, such as the candidates for the Mayor of London are, to develop any kind of individual profile in that way? Therefore, to me, those arguments are less persuasive the larger the geographical area is that you are talking about.

Professor David Denver: On the stand-alone election, I would guess that the turnout would be in the 40s, percentage-wise. It would be difficult, but there are regional personalities. I do not know what happens in London, but in the north-west or north-east, and so on, there are people who have a regional profile. I do not see any reason why they could not get that across in an election. It would be difficult because, naturally, the parties would be competing. However, I think that there is a chance of well known regional figures, such as the people who were involved in the north-east referendum on devolution, for example. It attracted big personalities in that area.

Professor John Curtice: I have a couple of points. I agree that a turnout of about 40 per cent would be my guess. There are two somewhat separate issues here. There was a lot of discussion with your previous witness about Independents. There is no doubt that it will not be easy for Independents to stand. The truth is that we know from other elections that there are two kinds of people who can make it as Independents. One is general practitioners and the other is ex-party politicians. They can often do it. Margo MacDonald as an ex-party politician managed to do it on the list in Scotland. I suspect that there might be a regional TV presenter standing on some big campaign. But that may be rare. However, a separate issue, among the candidates for parties, is about how much personality will matter. It is the argument about whether voters are going to vote alphabetically or whether they will exercise discretion. Certainly, in so far as candidates discover that voters do not vote just alphabetically or follow the advice of their parties—it really depends on what the voters do—those candidates will have a strong incentive to say, "By the way, I am so and so. This is what I do for this region". They will have an incentive to develop their personal profile. However, it depends on the electorate. If the electorate do not vote alphabetically and voters start to exercise their own discretion, then the system will work. That is why I come back to this: if that is what you want to achieve, think about not making it too difficult and creating an environment in which that is more likely to happen.

Q322   Mr Clarke: There are those who think that the Commons has not dealt with the West Lothian question. Having looked at the draft Bill, do you think that we have got that right?

Professor John Curtice: You are talking about the distribution of seats across the various parts of the United Kingdom?

Mr Clarke: That is part of it. My supplementary would be that, assuming that we have 80 per cent elected in the Lords and they start saying, "We have been elected from English regions" or whatever, "but we are not allowed to vote on these issues in Scotland". In other words, the West Lothian question, which might not yet have been addressed, could become an issue in a House of Lords which has an element of election.

Professor John Curtice: Okay. There are various complicated issues here. One of them is that it is intriguing that nobody raises the question of Members of the upper House who might originally have come from the Scottish Peerage—I do not think that there are any of those still left in the House—or those who are simply resident in Scotland still being allowed to vote on English Bills. Actually, the issue is arguably already before us in this House. Why should someone who is a Peer from north of the border be allowed to vote on so-called English legislation? At the moment, the Bill assumes, as is now the case in the Commons, that all parts of the UK should be represented on the basis of population. That certainly does not deal with the West Lothian question. The only thing I will say, and I will now make myself very unpopular with one person in this room, is that it could be argued as somewhat curious, if you are going for a House where the distribution of seats of the elected element is in proportion with the population of the UK, that one of the elements of the nominated element will be representative of the church of only one portion of the UK. That is another issue that you might want to think about, given the wider spirit of the Bill. But otherwise, Tom, the answer is that this Bill does not deal with the West Lothian question. The West Lothian question will be there, but it is arguably already there at the moment.

Q323   Lord Trimble: Sorry, but I am going to start with a bit of a grouse, particularly addressed to Professor Curtice and the way in which, in his introduction, he regarded Scotland and the Republic of Ireland as things that we could learn from, but skated over Northern Ireland by saying that we could not learn from it because, allegedly, the party system was different. The party system in Northern Ireland is closer to the system here than that in the Republic of Ireland. We have got over 30 years' experience of PR there, and it is worth studying instead of making excuses for not learning about, if you will forgive me for saying that.

The other thing that I want to focus on is when you were looking at people transferring votes beyond a particular party. The dynamic that tends to work here, and I am quite sure that most of the electorate can work this out for themselves as soon as they think about voting, is that, with STV, you do a simple triage. You decide the people who you want to vote for, who you give your first preferences to. Then there are the people who you do not want to see elected, who you do not give any preferences to. Then there are the ones in between, who you give lower preferences to in order to vote against the other party. It is a simple triage. The electorate understand this very quickly, and very quickly follow it. When you say that you got 59 per cent who voted for more than one party—hooray—a lot of that 59 per cent might just be voting for the other party to keep out a third group of people. That is what normally happens in this situation.

Professor John Curtice: Sure. Absolutely.

Lord Trimble: The other thing that normally happens is that parties give advice to the electorate. The electorate generally pay attention to that advice. That becomes quite a significant factor in this, too. You can probably only get rid of the alphabetical factor if you randomise the ballot paper. People talk about that, but I do not think that it ever has been.

Professor David Denver: It certainly has not been done in Scotland.

Lord Trimble: I have a third observation to make. This cannot happen when you have got boundary commissions, but in the glorious days when you did not have them, the way in which you gerrymandered STV was in the choice between three and four seats. You would go for one or the other depending on the level of electoral support that you had in the area. It is quite sophisticated but can be done. I will run classes in that later, if you like.

Professor John Curtice: There are a few points to respond to. The point that I was making about the Republic of Ireland is that, actually, we cannot necessarily rely on it. I was trying to tell you that the evidence from Scotland is not the same as that of the Republic of Ireland. It is simply that I would also suggest to you, for reasons that I will come on to, that there are equally particularities about Northern Ireland. As you will well know, one of the reasons for introducing STV in Northern Ireland was in the hope of promoting cross-nationalist/unionist transfers.

The Chairman: I fear that there is a Division in the House of Commons.

The Committee was suspended for a Division in the House of Commons.

On resuming—

The Chairman: We have a quorum.

Professor John Curtice: Do you want me to repeat for the record the conversation that Lord Trimble and I were having as we broke up?

Lord Trefgarne: No.

Professor John Curtice: I gave you a chance.

Q324   John Stevenson: I have two points to clarify on what you were saying, and one general question. Under the draft Bill, there is a cooling-off period for Members of the House of Lords to stand for the House of Commons. I get the impression that you would like to see that taken out, and I would like clarification on that point.

Secondly, you seem to be supporters of STV, but am I correct in saying that, if that were to be introduced for the purposes of the House of Lords, we should also introduce a rotation system for the ballot paper? Would you want to see that actually happen?

Thirdly, on the elections being on the same day, if they are on the same day as a general election, you would get higher turnout. Clearly, it would be favourable to the main parties. There would less of a protest vote, and there would be not be a better mandate to the House of Lords over the House of Commons. If it were to be held on a separate date, such as that of the European Parliament, you could start to see quite a dramatic change in British politics. For example, in the previous European elections, UKIP got about 16 per cent of the vote. If you saw that happen, effectively as a protest vote against the Government, you could have a very different second House from the first House. I would be interested in your observations on the possibilities of that and its consequences.

Professor David Denver: These are very interesting questions. On the first one, I have no views whatever on the cooling-off period. It is not something that I have even thought about; it is just not within my competence. I am not a supporter of STV in general for electing the House of Commons; I certainly would not favour that. It seems as if what we are looking for with the House of Lords is a kind of proportional system. STV seems to be the best. We were just saying beforehand that it would get rid of a lot of problems if you introduced a kind of randomisation of the ballot, if you just randomised the candidates and did not put them in alphabetical order. That would cure it. There seems no reason to avoid it at all. I cannot see why you would not do it.

Often I have been able to say to students and others that it is really nice that the European Parliament elections come along when they do, because they are nice and conveniently in the middle of the term and we get something exciting and different. You get UKIP, and a few years ago you got the Greens getting a huge vote. It is all good fun, since who cares about the European Parliament? You may as well have some fun with it. If you had the Lords tied to that and it was in the mid-term, you would assuredly get a different kind of vote. You would get more protest voting, with the mid-term blues. It would become what we call a second-order election. In second-order elections, people are much more willing to desert the major parties. They are less likely to turn out, but they are much more willing to experiment with other parties. On the whole I do not think that that would be too bad. It would add to the gaiety of life.

Q325   John Stevenson: Do you not think it would potentially have long-term consequences for our system of legislation?

Professor David Denver: But in the long term we are all dead.

Professor John Curtice: This, frankly, is outside my remit, but you have asked me the question. My own view is that I do not agree with term limits. I would allow people to stand again. It seems to me that it is up to voters to decide whether or not people are worthy of being re-elected to the House. One reason for saying that, in the context of my previous remarks, is that one of the things that would help to ensure that voters did not simply vote alphabetically is the presence on the ballot paper of either popular or unpopular incumbents. To that extent at least, I would not be in favour of term limits. Why should voters not decide whether or not it is a good or bad idea for people to stay in the Chamber?

On the rotation system, I think that, yes, it is probably a good idea in principle, although you will doubtless get complaints from political parties because it will make their lives more difficult in persuading their voters to vote in a particular way.

The third thing I would say is that, we now know that European elections are an occasion on which UKIP does extremely well, and there is some evidence that that also spills over into local elections that are held on the same day. Therefore, to that extent at least, if I were not holding it on the same day as a UK general election, I would also probably not hold it on the same day as the European Parliament elections. The thresholds are, as we discussed, very much higher and it would not be that easy for UKIP, the BNP or the Greens to gain representatives—boy, oh, boy, if I was giving evidence on behalf of those parties, I would say that it was a wonderful idea to have them on the same day as the European elections because I would think that that would be more likely to happen. That said, as I said earlier, there is no doubt that, even if you had it on a day other than the general election and European Parliament elections, you will probably get a certain amount of anti-Government voting. I am not sure that there would necessarily be any long-term consequence. Under the current proposals, if we get a Labour Party landslide in one election, a Conservative landslide in the next and maybe a close contest in the third, the upper Chamber will not look anything like the Commons on any of these occasions anyway. It is almost built into these proposals that the House of Lords will always be a pale reflection of the current political mood.

Q326   Ann Coffey: If you wanted the House of Lords to be a bit different and were trying to achieve that by making it much more diverse, representative and reflective of the British population, and given that neither proposal for these voting systems will achieve that except at the margins—because the parties will still be choosing the candidates—how do you think that you could achieve it while at the same time having some legitimacy as a House with some connection with the people out there?

Professor David Denver: I think that you are absolutely right. You were earlier, when people were going on about diversity and gender, absolutely right that the parties can do that. I do not think that it should be done any other way, myself. Indeed, I feel myself to be swimming against the tide a good deal. I am a real radical in that I think that the electors should decide who gets elected, not anybody else. There should be no rules about women or anything else. The electors decide. That is my view. I do not approve of special mechanisms to get different groups. Once you start, where are you going to end? What about Scottish working-class kids? Apply that and get more of them in the House of Commons?

Ann Coffey: We can have a very robust discussion on that, but the question that I am asking is, if you want it—if the aim was to achieve a House of Lords that was more diverse—

Professor David Denver: Appoint them all.

Professor John Curtice: The technical answer, if you wished to enforce that, is to go for a closed party list system in which, by law, the parties were required first to zip by gender, alternating the top from one region to another. You would also require their proportion of ethnic minority candidates to somehow reflect the local population. The first is relatively easy to enforce. The second will be much more difficult because you then get into the question of whether it is just any ethnic minority or whether it should be a certain proportion of those of Indian or Pakistani origin etc. Of course, as our population gets more diverse, not least as an increased number of people are of mixed origins, this becomes more difficult to achieve. In practice, what we have discovered is that the greatest pressure for ethnic diversity is the geographic concentration of those populations. As a result, parties can find it political because they have a membership which has said, "Hey guys, we want somebody from an ethnic minority representing us around here".

Q327   Dr Poulter: Professor Curtice, you made a couple of points earlier about a study you had done of voting patterns in Ireland. Is that correct?

Professor John Curtice: We mounted a study in Scotland that replicated research that had been done in Ireland, so that we could compare Scotland with Ireland and see how different or similar they were. My basic argument was that voters in Scotland in the 2007 Scottish local elections were not as candidate-centred as voters were in the Republic of Ireland. On the other hand, they were reasonably candidate-centred.

Dr Poulter: My only concern with these studies is that we know that there is a false recall as well, is there not? If you speak to and survey voters, there can be false recall. Is it Professor Antony King of the University of Essex who does this? He did some good work into this after the previous general election and found that 28 or 29 per cent of people were still saying that they voted Liberal Democrat, when we know that only 23 per cent of people actually did. There is that confounder, is there not?

Professor John Curtice: There is a rather different confounder in this case. We were asking people to remember how they had filled in a ballot paper that they filled in some time ago. While most people in this room would regard it has holy writ that they would easily remember, lots of people probably did not necessarily remember. Because the votes were counted electronically, however, we can to some degree verify the data. For example, the median voter in our study cast two votes. Casting three votes was not quite at the 50 per cent point; I think that we had about 45 per cent, 46 per cent or 47 per cent casting three or more votes. We were slightly short, but only slightly short. Certainly, on the number of voters in our study who cast only one preference, which we had as 22 per cent, in the electronic data it is 20 per cent. There is a bit of an issue about whether people remembered all the votes on that ballot paper. There is probably a bit of a problem there, but it does not look to be too serious.

As for whether the survey matched the outcome, yes, we were pretty close on all three ballots in 2007. But bear in mind that I was saying nothing about the partisanship of the voters. It was about how they were using the ballot paper.

Dr Poulter: There was another confounder. Correct me if I am wrong, but you were also saying that, in Scotland, not every party put up a full list. That also rather confounds and undermines, in my view, the transferability of that into real practice.

Professor John Curtice: Absolutely, and I was upfront about that. There is no doubt that a smaller number of wards means caveat emptor. If I was a Conservative supporter and my party put up only one candidate, I was more likely to cast a second preference for a candidate of another party than if my party put up two candidates. To that extent, at least, the degree to which the voters are willing to transfer votes across may be less than was the case in Scotland. However, I remind you that Alan Renwick, in his evidence to the Committee, has pointed out that the recall proposal that the Government are suggesting will create an incentive for parties to put forward candidates. Therefore voters will have more choice within parties. It will then come to how far they want to go down that path.

Q328   Dr Poulter: I have one more question on this point. Lord Trimble made the point very well that it is actually very difficult to analyse what may or may not happen. There can be the propensity for agreements to be made, and so you have more national elections, as in Australia. For example, we saw in the Australian elections that the Green second-preference vote was significant. Informal agreements can be made between parties. It is very difficult to extrapolate that until voters are informed by their first-preference parties about where other loyalties may or may not lie.

Professor John Curtice: Absolutely. If you are an advocate of STV, you regard that as an advantage of the system. If you are a critic, you regard it as a disadvantage. The interesting thing in Scotland is that I do not think that I came across a single piece of evidence of any of the political parties encouraging or giving any sign that they wanted their voters to transfer to somebody else. The parties managed to avoid saying any of those things in 2007. Whether they will continue to do that, who knows? There is an incentive to do so. If you can maximise the transfers between parties, as Fine Gael and Labour have demonstrated in the past, that is to your advantage. You pays your money, you takes your choice. I do not necessarily regard it as being a problem. You can argue that it is a way of enabling voters to indicate whether or not they back an understanding between the parties or not.

Q329    Lord Norton of Louth: I have two quick questions. Since we have you here, it would be interesting to know your views on which method you would prefer for the allocation of surplus votes. Should the method actually be on the face of the Bill, given its significance? Secondly, I want to pursue the point that has been raised about the "no re-election" rule. Obviously, that sets this system apart from those that you are mentioning; it puts us on a par with Mexico in terms of having a "no re-election" rule. Professor Curtice, you have argued against that, and that the electors should have the capacity to re-elect. Would it also flow from that that you would recommend a shorter term than the 15 years that is stipulated in the draft Bill?

Professor John Curtice: The answer to your first question is that, as you will be aware, the Scottish Parliament insisted on the weighted inclusive Gregory method. It did so after the Local Government Committee of the Scottish Parliament looked at the practice in both the north and south of Ireland and said, "We do not like this. It looks a bit too haphazard". It was advised that if you used electronic counting it was possible to use the weighted inclusive Gregory method. The reason why we had electronic counting in 2007, and weighted inclusive Gregory, is because of a cross-party consensus that was generated in Parliament. It was not something that originally came from the Government. Given that electronic counting is possible, there is no reason why you should not use weighted inclusive Gregory.

On the second question, you are right; I think that 15 years is an inordinately long time to give somebody for a term. There are some knock-on consequences to that. If you elect the whole House every five years, and if we accept that seven Members is probably the maximum for an STV constituency, you would have to have smaller constituencies. Some things I have heard in this room suggest you might regard as being an advantage. The Government were obviously concerned about turnover. If you go for something like STV, the turnover will be dampened down quite a lot. If you allow incumbents to be re-elected, you will keep the turnover down. The funny thing is that, although the Government's proposals try to dampen down party turnover, on membership turnover you have got a third of new boys and girls every five years.

Lord Norton of Louth: Did Professor Denver want to comment on the allocation?

Professor David Denver: No, I do not. That is way too technical for me. I go for big, broad brush strokes.

Q330    Lord Norton of Louth: To pursue the previous point, Professor Curtice, was your argument against the "no re-election" rule that it limits the choice of electors? So, if they want to re-elect someone it should be up to them. Would not the same principle apply in respect of this limit of four years before you can stand for the Commons? Is that not also a limitation on the choice of electors?

Professor John Curtice: Yes, absolutely. Maybe again this is an issue in Northern Ireland. People complain about people being able to "double job". I say that it is up to voters. If voters are happy for people to "double job", that is up to them.

Lord Norton of Louth: Professor Denver is nodding; I wanted to add that for the record.

Professor David Denver: Yes.

Q331   Lord Trefgarne: I share Professor Denver's preference for the first past the post system. Therefore, I am wondering whether it would not be possible to devise some sort of system, perhaps akin to the French one, where you have two elections separated by two weeks, provided that they have got less than 50 per cent first time. One has to recognise that Members of our House of Commons are elected by first past the post and very rarely attract more than 50 per cent of the vote.

Professor David Denver: Indeed. The strength of first past the post is to elect Governments, even though John will say that this is going to happen less and less. None the less, that it what it is for. In the case of the House of Lords, we are not electing Governments. It is all right to have STV for a second Chamber. I think that you would open up a Pandora's Box if you start bringing in two rounds of elections.

Professor John Curtice: You now have a straight political problem. The double-Member system will to many people look horribly similar to the alternative vote system, which has been decisively rejected by the electorate. I think that it is probably a dead duck.

Q332   Lord Hennessy of Nympsfield: David and John, you are both great experts in watching political markets in operation all across the world and here. As you have gone on, I have put down a little sketch, based on what you have been saying, of what the political market that the Bill wants us to create might look like if it comes to pass. It will have a second-order election, particularly if it stands alone, with about a 40 per cent turnout, to produce what you called a "pale reflection" House containing a mix of celebrities, eccentrics, UKIPs and very big tranche of party politicians who are not even household names in their own household. I may have got you wrong, but that is what has come out of the picture that you have been painting. If I was in favour of a wholly or largely elected Chamber, I would be deeply depressed by that prospect. Have I reflected your views accurately with these little scraps I have together?

Professor David Denver: I think that they might be unrepresentative in that they are torn out of context; in fact, I have no doubt. I did not ask to start from here, either. If it were up to me, I would not even have started reforming the House of Lords. But there you are: we are stuck with it. What do you do?

Lord Hennessy of Nympsfield: I do not think that we are stuck with it. That is the whole purpose of being here every Monday.

Professor David Denver: Really?

Professor John Curtice: I think the riposte to you is, yes, the public can indeed be rather awkward at times.

Lord Hennessy of Nympsfield: That is very profound. Thank you very much.

The Chairman: Thank you very much indeed. That has been a fascinating, instructive, almost breezy session, and thoroughly enjoyable for that.


 
previous page contents next page


© Parliamentary copyright 2012
Prepared 23 April 2012