6 Structural separation in the
first instance
The starting point
79. The Chancellor of the Exchequer contended that
not only is there a consensus on the need for structural separation,
a matter considered in chapter 3, but that there is also a UK
consensus that this Commission should not seek to re-open on what
form such separation should take:
I do agree we have a consensus that some form of
separation is required. That consensus has been created through
the Vickers process, but Vickers specifically looked at what form
of separation and specifically addressed the question of complete
separation. Indeed, it was part of his remit to look at that issue.
He looked at it and rejected it. When asked by this Commission,
he rejected it again and, indeed, other people who have come before
your Commission have rejected it. So I would say to you that there
is a consensus about structural reform and that you need to pull
apart investment and retail banking in some way, but we also have
in this country a consensus of how that is done.[123]
80. There
is widespread, but not universal, support for structural separation
in some form. However, views in evidence to the Commission about
how separation should operate, where a ring-fence should be placed
and indeed whether ring-fencing can achieve the desired policy
aims, fell well short of consensus.
Contagion, diversification and
cost
81. One argument for full separation, i.e. moving
some activities completely outside the banking group containing
the core activities, is that anything short of this will not be
able adequately to insulate the retail bank from the risk of contagion,
in the sense that a loss of trust in an investment bank, should
it fail, could lead to a run on the retail bank. Paul Volcker
highlighted the importance of a shared brand to a bank's reputation:
If the name is on the institution, or parts of the
institution, it will be protected; to the extent possible, each
part will be protected. If your name is on the door, you are going
to protect it. As I understand it, under the philosophy of Vickers
and Liikanen that would not happen. I think Britain is going a
little bit uphill.[124]
The ICB, in its final report, argued that reputational
links between different parts of the banking group could be a
feature of ring-fencing that enhances rather than threatens financial
stability.[125] An
investment bank, in order to secure its own reputation, may be
encouraged to provide assistance to a retail bank that bears its
name. Martin Taylor explained that:
One sees banks going to enormous lengths to protect
subsidiaries or commitments they have made with their brand on.
If you look at this with the object that the investment bank is
the only dangerous thing, you can make a bad mistake. I don't
terribly like the idea. If we enforced a split in the UK, you
would have a rather strange ecosystem with very large, very highly
correlated retail banks with no earnings diversification from
elsewhere, and I don't think that is a particularly good idea.[126]
A number of banks also emphasised the benefits of
having a number of diverse functions or operating in a number
of territories, broadly suggesting that this would help to insure
them against one narrow area of the business falling into difficulties.[127]
Sir John Vickers told us:
I do not believe that we are in a simple world of
utility and casino, where the utility is totally safe. There are
risks in any form of credit extension and they can be correlated
risks, when an economy hits trouble. One, in my view, cannot dismiss
the possibility that a stand-alone, undiversified sector would
get into trouble. If it got into trouble when the rest of the
world or the rest of banking was doing okay, one would have lost
a great deal by a full split, because there would not be the group
resources to mitigate the losses in UK retail.[128]
82. The Chancellor of the Exchequer argued that the
additional costs from full structural separation as opposed to
a ring-fence would need to be justified by additional benefits:
there is a very considerable cost to the industry
in what we are doing. [...] I have taken a judgment [...] that
this is a price worth paying and that it is outweighed by the
broader economic benefits that greater stability will bring. However,
there is a cost to the industry, and exactly the same Members
of Parliament who get up and say, "You must screw the banks
down" are the same people getting up and saying, "We've
got to get the banks to lend and when are we going to do it?"
[...] I think that full separation would be an even greater cost
and I'd have to justify it. I would be prepared to do so if I
thought it was bringing benefits that outweighed that cost.[129]
Sir John Vickers explained that the ICB's rejection
of full separation was founded on the belief that ring-fencing
could deliver similar benefits at a lower cost.[130]
The contention that the costs of ring-fencing would be lower was
set out in the ICB's final report:
there are a number of factors which would lead full
separation to be more expensive than ring-fencing. This is principally
because ring-fencing preserves those diversification benefits
which arise from the ability to move excess capital [...] average
analyst estimates suggest [diversification benefits] could be
as much as £4bn annually but the empirical evidence is mixed.
In addition, there are other synergies which ring-fencing
would preserve but which full separation would not. There may
be a valuable benefit to some customers of being able to purchase
from a single banking group a range of services which would straddle
the divide between retail banking and wholesale/investment banking.
Within banking groups, there need not be restrictions on the sharing
of information and it may be possible to preserve a greater degree
of operational synergies than under full separation.[131]
Martin Taylor referred to how the ICB made a deliberate
attempt to preserve these operational synergies where they did
not pose a threat:
Where we had a choice, we tended to take the line
that would not put extra cost or inconvenience on the banks. For
example, we allowed the ring-fenced bank and the non-ring-fenced
bank to share treasury functions and IT functions. This saves
these banks a lot of money.[132]
Culture and standards
83. Paul Volcker considered that the cultural advantages
of structural separation would best be secured through full separation.[133]
The ICB did not consider standards and culture as part of their
remit, and it should not be expected that their solution would
necessarily be that which best addresses the wider problems in
banking standards. Nevertheless, Sir John Vickers argued that
they did examine cultural issues:
We certainly gave thought to questions about culture.
"Culture" was the word we used more than "standards",
and it was before some of the events of this year. Our view was
that, given the questions that we had been set, it was not for
us directly to seek to regulate cultural standards, which is a
difficult thing in any case, but that the issues that we were
looking at, both on structure and on loss absorbency and on the
competition and consumer side, all had a very clear bearing on
questions of culture and, as we might now say, of standards.
I do not believe that the recommendations that we
made on the questions that were put to us would have been materially
different if standards had been explicitly among, let us say,
the issues that we were to have regard to.[134]
Permeability
84. One of the arguments for full structural separation
compared with a ring-fence is that full separation would entail
fewer rules and therefore less monitoring and enforcement, because
the two entities would be separately owned and would have no more
incentive to create interdependencies than any other two banks.
Paul Volcker's main doubt about the effectiveness of a ring-fence
was that they "tend to be permeable over time".[135]
He added:
If you really want to separate some operations very
clearly and decisively, you put them in different organisations.
In my experience, you do not put two functions in the same organisation
and say that they cannot talk to each other or interact.[136]
85. Sir John Vickers and Martin Taylor both argued
that full separation would not be much simpler than a ring-fence,
concentrating on the fact that determining the location of the
split would be just as complex for full separation as for a ring-fence.[137]
In the words of the latter:
[An] error that people are prone to make is that
somehow splitting is simple, and a ring-fence is complicated.
In fact, if you are going to split, you have to go through all
the complexity that we have gone through with ring-fencing and
decide exactly where the split should come. You would have just
as much regulatory complexity, and of course you would also risk
putting it in the wrong place.[138]
86. Lord Turner pointed out that Glass Steagall,
which is thought of as a full-separation approach, nevertheless
eroded away over time.[139]
However, Paul Volcker argued that the failure of Glass-Steagall
was not because full separation was ineffective, but because the
separation became less full, saying "the restrictions between
the 'commercial bank' and the 'investment bank' in Glass-Steagall
broke down over time. I have a little fear that that might happen
in Vickers too."[140]
Market-driven separation
87. It is possible that even if not mandated, some
banks may decide to pursue full separation of their retail and
wholesale activities voluntarily. A robust ring-fence would retain
some synergies between the two banks, but would remove many of
the benefits that banks obtain from conducting retail and wholesale
activity side-by-side. In such circumstances, shareholders might
consider themselves better served by spinning off one of the banks
and allowing it to compete without the costs and constraints of
the ring-fence. António Horta-Osório said:
if the synergies that customers perceive in having
an integrated approach are more than offset by the internal costs
that you impose on the organisation, I think that shareholders
in the future will say that the synergies do not compensate for
the costs, and that banks should spin off their investment banks
or their retail banks. They will separate, but it will be a market
force separation.[141]
Professor Kay went further, arguing that if a ring-fence
really did result in effective separation, then banks should want
to split themselves up:
I have thought, and in some ways I continue to think,
that the effectiveness of ring-fencing would be demonstrated by
whether Barclays wanted to split itself up. If the ring-fence
were really effective, they would have little reason to want to
maintain that structure. In that world, the interest that certainly
the previous management of Barclays would have in the retail side
of the activities would probably be rather small.[142]
European law
88. One difficulty that the imposition of full structural
separation might pose is that it may conflict with European law.
The final ICB report noted that:
full separation would give rise to legal obstacles
which are not applicable to ring-fencing because European law
places particular constraints on the degree to which ownership
of companies can be controlled. Member states can object to the
change of ownership of a bank only on certain grounds, and it
is far from clear that these would enable the authorities to prevent
the acquisition of a UK-incorporated retail bank by a European
universal or wholesale/investment bank. [...] while it might be
possible to secure changes to the relevant EU law, there seems
little reason to pursue this difficult and uncertain course given
that the merits of the economic arguments do not clearly favour
full separation."[143]
89. Martin Taylor referred to "the deep difficulties
under European law of mandating full separation" as a factor
in the ICB's deliberations when he gave oral evidence.[144]
The limitations on change of ownership are set out in Article
19(1) of the Banking Consolidation Directive (2006/48/EC), which
was incorporated into that Directive by the Acquisitions Directive
(2007/44/EC), and which was transposed into national law by sections
185 and 186 Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 (FSMA). The
provisions were intended to ensure that acquisitions were blocked
only on strictly prudential grounds, rather than discriminatory
grounds. A ban on the acquisition of a retail bank by an investment
bank, because it is an investment bank, could be held to
breach the obligation on the FSA under section 185 of FSMA to
object to an acquisition only on the limited set of prudential
criteria set out in section 186 FSMA, which do not include the
criterion that an acquirer of a retail bank is not an investment
bank.[145] In considering
the impact of these current restrictions, it needs to be borne
in mind that, if the European Commission puts forward a legislative
proposal based on the work of the Liikanen Group, as expected,
then this might provide an appropriate vehicle within which to
negotiate the necessary changes to EU law if full separation were
to be pursued.
International context
90. The ICB remit included a requirement to have
regard to the impact of their recommendations on "the competitiveness
of the UK financial and professional services sectors".[146]
Bill Winters told the Treasury Select Committee in May 2011 that
"we spent some time thinking about whether either large universal
banks or parts of universal banks were likely to re-domicile".[147]
He noted that the ICB made recommendations based on "what
we thought the right structure was for the banking industry in
the UK, considering financial stability, competition costs, and
service to society, not focused primarily on whether banks would
re-domicile".[148]
In evidence to us, Martin Taylor voiced scepticism over the suggestion
that banks would be driven to relocate by the current set of proposals:
I do not believe that we will have wholesale moving
of banks' head offices, which is what we were worried about two
or three years ago, simply because pretty much the entire world
is going in the same direction. I work in Switzerland and spend
half my time there. I remember in 2009-10, all the people in the
City were saying they wanted to move to Switzerland, and all the
Swiss banks wanted to move to London. Each of them was ignorant
about the changes taking place on the other side.[149]
Michael Cohrs noted that the UK has a number of distinct
advantages as a location for banks which would remain regardless
of the UK's approach to financial regulation:
generally speaking, it is really hardjust
as it is really hard to separate a bankfor a bank to move
its jurisdiction. That is before you get into the cultural issues,
which, for a bank, should be very important. So I am dismissive
of bankers when they tell meI used to be one of them"If
you don't give us a good regime, we will go elsewhere." It
is rubbish... You know the most important reason? Greenwich Mean
Time.... Two, language is critically important. The world has
adopted our language; that is very important. Three, our legal
system is very clear. It works. People want to litigate in this
country. That is a big asset that we have. We should make this
into an industry, as a country. We are probably not charging enough
for people to come here and use our courts [...] Finally, London
is a pretty neat place to live. These people make a lot of money.
They want to spend their money in a pleasant place, and London
is a very pleasant place.[150]
Conclusions
91. Sir Mervyn King drew the Commission's attention
to the fact that he had long supported structural separation:
I have made no secret of the fact, and I have spoken
about it for five years, that I have always felt that total separation
was the right way ultimately to go. I have been joined in arguing
this by some distinguished company, but it has been a lonely and
difficult furrow to plough. I am glad that many more people are
now coming on board the idea that a move to some kind of serious
separation is the right thing to do. Even the Financial Times
has now advocated a move in this direction.[151]
However, he went on to say why he strongly supported
introducing a ring-fence "now":
I really do not want the last five years of effort
to go to waste through the whole issue being kicked into the long
grass by not implementing Vickers. We appointed the Vickers Commission
in the UK, and I think this is the best-qualified group of people
to serve on such a Commission in my lifetime in the UK. These
are very impressive individuals, and they have thought about it.[152]
This viewed was echoed more recently by a fellow
member of the Financial Policy Committee, Michael Cohrs:
I am not completely pessimistic. I think that Vickers
is a step in the right direction. To me, however, it is only a
step in the journey because I think a modern Glass-Steagall will
ultimately see total separation. [...] I think that we are on
a journey, and Vickers is a good path for us to follow.
92. The Chancellor of the Exchequer emphasised in
his evidence how a change of approach at this stage would cause
significant delay and be hard to justify:
[W]e have reached this point, we have got agreement,
we are fundamentally going to change the structure of British
banking. We have got that consensus. Let's get on and implement
it and legislate for it, instead of getting to the top of the
snakes and ladders board and then going all the way down the big
snake that takes you to the bottom again.[153]
93. Whatever
their views on arguments for and against full separation, which
are finely balanced, the majority of witnesses told the Commission
that the partial structural separation of the ring-fence would
probably bring significant benefits for public policy and for
banking. The Commission therefore welcomes the Government's action
to bring forward legislation to implement a ring-fence.
94. The ICB's
proposals should be the starting point for proposals for legislation
for implementation of structural separation. However, that does
not mean that they should be the final destination. The current
proposals may not be sufficient. In addition to concerns about
proprietary trading, the case that a ring-fence will in practice
be able to achieve the necessary level of separation remains unproven.
The ring-fence may also be tested and eroded over time. The Commission
considers it essential that steps are taken to reinforce the ring-fence,
and makes specific recommendations to this effect in chapter 9.
95. There is
evidence to suggest that proprietary trading, which under the
current proposals could still take place within the non-ring-fenced
part of banking groups, is an activity which is incompatible with
maintaining the required integrity of customer-facing banking
and which could have harmful cultural effects if permitted to
continue. This was the primary concern of Paul Volcker in suggesting
the prohibition of such activity in US banks.
96. The Commission
has not considered fully the ramifications and practical issues
of supplementing the proposed UK ring-fence with something akin
to the Volcker rule. The Commission intends to take further evidence
on this in the New Year. The Bill which the Government will shortly
introduce provides the appropriate vehicle for establishing the
future structural form of the UK banking industry.
97. The Commission
will consider further the implications of introducing a prohibition
on groups containing a ring-fenced bank from engaging in proprietary
trading and, in particular, the contribution such a prohibition
could make to the changes needed to banking culture and standards.
The Commission expects to report in good time in order that legislative
effect to any recommendations can be given as the Bill progresses.
98. Measures
to tighten the regulation of UK banks beyond international norms
should be assessed for their potential to cause an unwelcome shift
of activity abroad. However, concerns about relocation of banks
may be over-stated. They should not be allowed to dominate the
decision on the measures necessary to remove the implicit guarantee
and ensure the banking system serves the UK economy. We will address
this in our final Report.
123 Q 1066 Back
124
Q 53 Back
125
Independent Commission on Banking, Final Report, September 2011,
p 63 Back
126
Q 369 Back
127
Q 860 [Peter Sands]; Ev w30 [Barclays] Back
128
Q 760 Back
129
Q 1066 Back
130
Q 762 Back
131
Independent Commission on Banking, Final Report, September 2011,
p 64 Back
132
Q 395 Back
133
Qq 55 and 62 Back
134
Q 746 Back
135
Q 53 Back
136
Q 53 Back
137
Qq 369 and 761 Back
138
Q 369 Back
139
Q 761 Back
140
Q 92 Back
141
Q 899 Back
142
Q 312 Back
143
Independent Commission on Banking, Final Report, September 2011,
p 65 Back
144
Q 369 Back
145
There is also a public policy exception, but this has generally
been interpreted narrowly. Back
146
Independent Commission on Banking, Terms of Reference. www. hm-treasury.gov.uk Back
147
Oral evidence taken before the Treasury Committee on 24 May 2011,
HC (2010-12) 1069- i, Q35 Back
148
Oral evidence taken before the Treasury Committee on 24 May 2011,
HC (2010-12) 1069- i, Q35 Back
149
Q 393 Back
150
Uncorrected transcript of oral evidence before Parliamentary
Commission on Banking Standards Panel on Regulatory Approach on
11 December 2012, HC 821-i, Q 34 Back
151
Q 1160 Back
152
Q 1160 Back
153
Q 1027 Back
|