9 Reinforcing the ring-fence
Introduction
126. In previous chapters we have indicated how the
approach taken by the Government to give effect to a ring-fence
leaves that ring-fence especially vulnerable to erosion over time.
The Commission has also identified the propensity of regulated
firms to seek to press at the limits of permitted activities for
short-term economic gain, and the risks that such efforts might
be supported by pressure on politicians to agree to convenient
changes which reduce the long-term effectiveness of the ring-fence.
The Commission has also concluded that the ring-fence requires
reinforcement if it is withstand pressures in the long-term. This
chapter makes specific recommendations for reinforcement.
Objectives in primary legislation
127. The legislation begins by setting a continuity
objective for the regulator described as "protecting the
continuity of the provision in the United Kingdom of core services".[198]
Barclays pointed out that the continuity of core services objective
is "subjective and hard to measure".[199]
Chapter 3 illustrated the wide range of options for structural
separation in addition to the ICB's proposals, intended in part
to provide for continuity of core services. Therefore it could
leave the regulator able to use these powers to pursue a wide
range of approaches. This could be all the more concerning, given
the vulnerability of the regulators and the banking community
to fashionable mantras. The legislation's lack of clear objectives
leaves its future operation vulnerable to changing attitudes over
time.
128. Andrew Bailey identified how specifying objectives
more clearly could also help provide greater legitimacy:
in the context of the legislation that you are scrutinising,
we need to have the objectives and the powers set out very clearly.
I think it needs to go a step further than it has gone in the
draft that we have today, which is a bit too enabling without
specifying how the objectives work. Fitted together, that would
be a big step forward because it creates a much greater sense
of legitimacy.[200]
Andrew Bailey has also requested "better narrative
regarding how the PRA's safety and soundness and continuity objectives
interact." The FSA believe that, as currently drafted, the
draft Bill "implies that if there is a clash, the [PRA's]
continuity objective would prevail over the safety and soundness
objective".[201]
129. The Chancellor of the Exchequer, when challenged
on the lack of objectives in the draft Bill, argued that the continuity
objective was all that is needed:
there is a very clear objective in the Bill, which
is that the regulators and the Government of the day can continue
the provision of core services in the banking industry in the
situation in which a bank is failing. [...] If we crack that,
I would say that we will have cracked one of the significant problemsnot
the only problemthat arose during the banking crisis.[202]
He also expressed concern that adding other objectives
would reduce rather than enhance clarity:
I do not think that adding a load of further objectives
would clarify the situation; I think that it would add to the
complexity of what we are asking to be done. [...] I think it
is important to have a very clear focus on the objective, rather
than a load of objectives, and the objective is to allow core
services to continue even when we allow a bank to fail. You would
muddy the waters if we created more objectives in this legislation.[203]
In a written response to Andrew Bailey's request
for clarity, the Chancellor of the Exchequer confirmed that:
The draft Bill currently sets out how the PRA's objective
for ring-fencing and its general objective interact. When the
PRA is acting in relation to matters related to ring-fencing,
and only then, the PRA is required to act at all times compatibly
with its continuity objective. [204]
130. The
ICB final report sets out three, not one, objectives for the ring-fence.
These are:
- make it easier
to sort out both ring-fenced banks and non-ring-fenced banks which
get into trouble, without the provision of taxpayer-funded solvency
support;
- insulate vital banking services
on which households and SMEs depend from problems elsewhere in
the financial system; and
- curtail government guarantees,
reducing the risk to the public finances and making it less likely
that banks will run excessive risks in the first place.
The continuity objective does not
adequately reflect these. In order to anchor implementation of
the ring-fence more securely to the ICB's proposals, the Commission
recommends that the Bill as introduced imposes additional requirements
under the new section 2BA(4) of FSMA to ensure that in advancing
the continuity objective, the PRA must also seek to meet the following
requirements as set out in paragraph 1.3 of the policy paper accompanying
the draft Bill, namely:
- Making banks
better able to absorb losses;
- Making it easier and less costly
to sort out banks that still get into trouble; and
- Curbing incentives for excessive
risk-taking.
The continuity objective must be
properly understood as being about protecting the continuity of
the provision of core services, not about the continuity of institutions.
The regulator seeks clarity about how the continuity objective
relates to the other objectives of the regulator when exercising
powers in relation to the ring-fence. The Commission will take
further evidence and report on this matter in the New Year.
131. In
the light of recent revelations the Commission has taken evidence
regarding the ability of the ring-fence to protect and enhance
standards and culture in the banks and will consider in our final
Report whether an additional objective should be considered to
address these concerns.
Regulatory judgement
132. In written evidence, Andy Haldane identified
the main steps the regulator could take if it felt a firm were
breaching regulatory rules:
- Impose higher capital requirements,
or tighter liquidity requirements;
- Take action under the approved persons regime,
potentially including removal of approvals;
- Impose a financial penalty;
- Remove links to owners and group companies;
- Vary a bank's authorisations to limit or prevent
activities.[205]
In seeking to exercise these powers and otherwise
enforce the ring-fence, the regulator is likely to encounter the
difficulties which Sir Mervyn King highlighted:
I have been struck in the last five years, learning
more about how the regulatory process worked, by how much of it
has turned out to be a negotiation between the regulators on the
one hand and banks on the other [...] The big principle is that,
to be effective, the regulator has to be able to use judgment.
That is what we want to get to. But if judgment ends up simply
as a negotiation between the regulator and the regulated bank,
there is only one winner in that, and that will be a very bad
outcome. Clarity is crucial to enable the regulator to exercise
judgment within a very well-defined framework, and the regulator
needs to be able to tell banks, "This is the capital requirement
you will have", as opposed to merely entering into a negotiation.[206]
133. It
is essential that the new framework for the ring-fence and the
secondary legislation and rules that flow from it are not seen
by the banks merely as a basis for negotiation. The legitimate
role of the judgement of the regulator in implementing the framework
must be beyond doubt. The regulator's decision-making, in line
with its judgement in pursuit of its objective in relation to
the ring-fence, should not require it to identify a specific breach
of rules in order to take action to maintain the integrity of
the ring-fence. The Commission considers that it is of paramount
importance that the new legislation is drafted in such a way as
to make this clear.
Conditions on the exercise of
certain delegated powers
134. The extreme examples included in paragraph 58
illustrate that the design of the conditions which govern the
delegated powers are of vital importance. Those examples demonstrate
that the subsequent secondary legislation will not be merely technical,
but central to the way the ring-fence operates. Previous chapters
have demonstrated that the Government's reliance on secondary
legislation poses significant risks to the durability of the ring-fence.
Two examples of areas where this may of particular concern are
the powers under proposed sections 142A(2)b and 142D(2). The first
power allows the Treasury to exempt a class of institution from
the requirements of the ring-fence. This is intended in particular
to allow the introduction of a de minimis test to exempt small
deposit-takers, which is considered in chapter 10, but the power
is not limited to this purpose. The second power allows the Treasury
to change the definition of an excluded activityone which
ring-fenced banks cannot conductfor example, a particular
type of derivative trade. The test that must be met for use of
either power is very similarthat the Treasury believe it
would "not be likely to have a significant adverse effect
on the continuity of the provision in the United Kingdom of core
services".[207]
135. In addition
to the enhanced scrutiny arrangements recommended later in this
chapter, the Commission recommends that the Treasury's delegated
powers under proposed sections 142A(2)(b) and 142D(2) be tightened.
It is insufficient to require only that exemptions from the ring-fence
restrictions do not have a "significant adverse effect on
the continuity in the United Kingdom of the provision of core
services". The fact that this condition is framed as a negative
test could too easily allow a series of exemptions cumulatively
to weaken and complicate the ring-fence, even if individually
these fall short of risking a "significant adverse effect".
The provisions should be tightened by requiring that exemptions
should be made only if they:
a) do
not pose a risk to the continuity objective; and
b) provide
a significant economic or financial stability benefit.
Determining the height of the
ring-fence
136. The draft Bill requires the regulator to use
its existing rule-making powers to make additional ring-fencing
rules, the stated purpose of which is "ensuring
a) that the carrying on of core activities by
a ring-fenced body is not adversely affected by the acts or omissions
of other persons, and
b) that any ring-fenced body which is a member
of a group is able to act independently of other members of the
group in carrying on the business of the ring-fenced body."[208]
137. Constructing the ring-fence will entail major
corporate restructuring of all the large UK banks. A great deal
of judgement will be involved in this process. The regulator largely
tasked with making these rules has said that its mandate in the
draft Bill is not strong enough to protect it from challenge:
should the PRA choose to make ring-fencing rules
that are not mandated in the draft Bill, it could potentially
be seen to be acting beyond its remit.
In our view the draft Bill should provide 'parameters'
within which the PRA is given a statutory mandate to make rules
to enforce the appropriate degree of separation between the RFB
and the NRFB in the event that it needs to exercise its rule-making
powers in ways not specified in the draft Bill.[209]
Andrew Bailey expanded on this in his oral evidence:
What we have to get right is the balance between
giving us the job of implementing a rule book essentiallythe
short version of itand Parliament having sufficient hands
on in terms of the objectives so that the legitimacy and authority
of Parliament is very clearly behind it. That is a balance. At
the moment, this is a very short piece of legislation in a sense.
It says, "We'll define some objectives and then send you
off to police them." I think we have to get the balance right
in terms of being a very clear statement of Parliament's intent
here.[210]
Paul Tucker concurred, adding that:
We are clear, and I think that if Adair and Andrew
were here they would say the same, that it is important that the
meat of the regime is set out in secondary legislation; that the
PRA board does not become a quasi-legislative body. I completely
agree with Andy that the things that he has set out, and that
type of thing, should be in the secondary legislation.[211]
Paul Tucker also summarised the concerns that arose
from this approach:
I think what the FSA is concerned about, and certainly
what we are concerned about, is that as drafted, the primary legislation
allows the meat of the regime to be set out in secondary legislation,
or in PRA rules, or in a combination of the two. Technically,
therefore, it would be possible for the secondary legislation
to be almost silent, leaving the whole of the regime to be set
out in the PRA rules. We are clear [..] that it is important that
the meat of the regime is set out in secondary legislation; that
the PRA board does not become a quasi-legislative body.[212]
138. The Chancellor of the Exchequer told us that
"the rules will ensure the economic and operational independence
of ring-fenced banks from the rest of the group in which they
sit. The regulator is best placed to deal with these matters but
the outcome and objective will be clearly expressed in legislation."[213]
139. The Commission
is extremely concerned, as are the regulators themselves, that
the key issues determining the height of the ring-fence are proposed
to be a matter for determination by the regulator alone. A regulator
enforcing rules of its own creation will have less authority in
doing so than a regulator giving effect to a clear mandate in
legislation with parliamentary authorisation. There is a compelling
case for strengthening the regulator's hand when it makes ring-fencing
rules through such a mandate. The Commission recommends accordingly
that proposed section 142H of FSMA be amended either to define
the parameters of the rules to be set by the regulator more fully
or to require that secondary legislation made by the Treasury
and subject to the affirmative resolution procedure defines the
parameters. The objective of this legislation should be to empower
the regulator to police and enforce the ring-fence. The Commission
considers in chapter 10 what the legislative parameters should
be.
Scrutiny
140. The Commission received a very helpful memorandum
from the House of Lords Delegated Powers and Regulatory Reform
Committee in response to our request that they consider the appropriateness
of, and scrutiny arrangements for, the delegated powers in the
draft Bill. In its submission, that Committee identified two consistent
themes: "a lack of appropriate Parliamentary control; and
a lack of explanation for some significant powers contained in
the draft Bill".[214]
141. The draft Bill proposes only the weakest form
of Parliamentary scrutinythe negative resolution procedurefor
all but one of the delegated powers which it gives the Government.
Under this procedure, secondary legislation can be made and comes
into effect immediately, and only ceases to have effect in the
exceptionally rare cases where one House of Parliament passes
a resolution requiring it to be annulled. In the House of Commons,
even a debate on the secondary legislation in question can only
be secured with the agreement of the Government. This procedure
is often held to be appropriate in circumstances where delegated
powers provide technical detail which implements policy, but does
not have the ability to change its direction.
142. The only power relating to the design of the
ring-fence where secondary legislation will be subject to the
affirmative resolution procedure is the one under proposed section
142A(2)(b) (the power to exempt classes of institution from the
ring-fence). Under the affirmative procedure, secondary legislation
can only come into force (or, in certain urgent cases, remain
in force) if both Houses of Parliament agree to this after a debate,
usually in a Delegated Legislation Committee in the House of Commons
and in Grand Committee in the House of Lords.
143. The other five powers listed in paragraph 57,
which together give the Treasury the ability to add or exempt
activities which must or cannot be done in a ring-fenced bank,
are only subject to negative resolution. The Treasury's delegated
powers memorandum attempts to justify the choice of procedure
for several of the powers by reference to the fact that the power
is likely to be technical or that there are restrictions on the
use of the power.[215]
As discussed in chapter 4, while these powers may well be technical
in content, their scope is not confined just to matters of detail
but can have important policy implications, and allow for a wider
departure from the ring-fence as currently planned.
144. The assessment of the Delegated Powers and Regulatory
Reform Committee was that all six powers listed in paragraph 57,
which together define the ring-fence, should be subject to affirmative
procedure, not just that under proposed section 142A(2)(b). That
Committee questioned in particular one of the justifications given
in the delegated powers memorandum for the choice of procedure
for the power under proposed section 142B(2), which is the power
to define when accepting deposits is not to be regarded as a "core
activity". The justification referred to "the fact that
the effect of the power will be to narrow the range of cases where
a person who accepts deposits must be a ring-fenced bank or an
exempt bank".[216]
As the Committee noted, this is "based on the assumption
that removing control needs a lower level of Parliamentary scrutiny
than imposing it and we do not consider that the assumption may
be so easily made here where important issues of public policy
may be at stake".[217]
145. Another justification for negative resolution
which the Committee challenged was that given for the power to
create new core activities (under proposed section 142B(5)), where
the Treasury referred to the fact that it is possible that it
might in some cases be desirable to take urgent action to protect
the activity in question.[218]
The Committee noted that "the possible need for urgency [...]
cannot be accepted as a justification, since FSMA itself deals
with urgency in other affirmative cases by means of the 28-day
'made affirmative' procedure (i.e. in force immediately but lapses
if not approved within 28 days)."[219]
146. The scrutiny
arrangements for secondary legislation as specified in the draft
Bill are unacceptably weak. Many of the delegated powers may involve
significant policy choices, not merely implementation decisions
of a technical nature. The Commission recommends that use of each
of the delegated powers under proposed new sections 142B(5), 142D(2),
142D(4) and 142E should be subject to the affirmative resolution
procedure.
147. The Delegated Powers and Regulatory Reform Committee
also noted the significance of the powers under proposed section
142F. According to the Delegated Powers Memorandum, these are
supplementary powers which enable the Treasury to "give the
regulator power to make technical provisions related to core activities
and excluded activities, in areas which are generally treated
as the preserve of the regulator".[220]
In other words they permit the Treasury to delegate responsibility
for some of the technical detail to the regulator rather than
this all needing to be set out in secondary legislation. However,
the Committee explained to us that section 142F also "enables
an order:
- to confer powers on the Treasury
or on a regulator;
- to require the regulator to make rules;
- to authorise the making (by anybody) of other
instruments for purposes connected with any provision of the order;
and
- if the Treasury authorises the regulator to make
rules, to enable the Treasury to control the content of the rules."
The Committee concluded that as a result of this
for example, an order could authorise the Treasury
to make regulations or give directions for the purposes of the
order, without a need for Parliamentary procedure, thus relegating
parts of the material covered by the order to an instrument free
of any Parliamentary control. We were not convinced that this
is appropriate.[221]
148. In response to the concerns expressed, the
Treasury stressed that the power under section 142F was a subsidiary
one, and that it would not enable the Treasury to give itself
the power to create new excluded activities or core activities,
or to provide for exceptions to the core and excluded activities
provided for on the face of the Bill without following the parliamentary
procedure laid down under the earlier sections.[222]
149. The Commission
has concluded that the range of powers available to the Treasury
under proposed section 142F is unacceptably wide. As a first step,
the Commission recommends that the power of the Treasury to give
itself further order-making powers be more fully circumscribed.
In particular, there should be a requirement that the power further
to delegate under secondary legislation a power to make what might
be termed tertiary legislation should be subject to the same parliamentary
procedure as the instrument by which the power to make it is delegated.
The Commission also recommends that, in the delegated powers memorandum
accompanying the Bill itself, the Government set out in more detail
the proposed use of each of the additional delegated powers it
is seeking in section 142F.
150. The concerns expressed about certain delegated
powers are magnified in many ways by the underlying concern that
has run through our consideration of the ring-fence proposals,
namely that, even if the ring-fence is faithfully implemented
at first in accordance with the firm commitment of the current
Chancellor of the Exchequer, it risks being eroded over time.
We have therefore considered what additional parliamentary bulwark
could be established to prevent, or at least highlight, such erosion.
151. The Commission
has concluded that a necessary form of parliamentary bulwark against
erosion is the creation of a specific statutory provision for
enhanced parliamentary scrutiny of the proposed use of delegated
powers which have the potential to change the location of the
ring-fence in a significant way. This would apply to all uses
of the powers referred to in paragraph 146, subject to exceptions
for secondary legislation of an urgent nature, which should be
subject to the 'made affirmative' procedure. This scrutiny would
be undertaken by a small ad hoc joint committee of both Houses
of Parliament, to be established on each occasion subsequent to
the first use of each delegated power when the Treasury proposes
to exercise one of those delegated powers. Although the membership
of the joint committee would be determined by decisions of the
two Houses, there should be a statutory requirement for the Chairman
of the House of Commons Treasury Committee to be an ex officio
member of it.
152. The Government
would be required to publish its case for the proposed new use
of the power, alongside a provisional version of the secondary
legislation itself. This provisional version would be subject
to public consultation. The ad hoc joint committee would be established
at the outset of this consultation phase. It would examine and
report on the proposal within a specified period. After that report,
the Government could proceed with secondary legislation in the
usual way, albeit subject to the affirmative resolution procedure
in accordance with the Commission's recommendation in paragraph
146, but would do so in a way that secures far greater transparency
about the purpose and likely effect of any changes.
Electrifying the ring-fence
EVIDENCE RECEIVED
153. The final element which the Commission has considered
to create the best prospects for the long-term effectiveness of
the ring-fence is its electrification, by which we mean creating
a very significant disincentive for banks to depart from the spirit
of the ring-fence by creating full structural separation as a
viable alternative.
154. Advocates of a ring-fence did not rule out the
possibility of full structural separation in the future. Sir John
Vickers told us that, while he was optimistic about the prospects
of the ring-fence succeeding, full separation might become necessary:
If the industry turned out to be unreformable, and
I am not so pessimistic as to think that, of course it is possible
that total separation would turn out in due course to be the better
step to take[223]
Martin Taylor identified circumstances in which his
preference for a ring-fence might change over time:
The main reason why I would support a full split
was if I thought a ring-fence was unworkable. I do not think thatI
think a ring-fence is a superior solutionbut if a ring-fence
were put in place and proved to be unworkable because of attrition,
as you call it, there would be a case for going further, but I
do not start from that.[224]
155. Referring explicitly to the exchanges between
the Chairman of this Commission and Martin Taylor in which the
possibility of a contingent power to impose full separation was
raised, Andy Haldane developed the proposition further:
I was struck by the point made by you, Chairman,
in the testimony provided by Martin Taylor, where you floated
the idea of having as a back-stop, perhaps as a legislative back-stop,
the possibility of separation if the ring-fence proves permeable
or impossible to police. That is an idea that is worth thinking
about. I can see some attractions to that from an incentives perspective.
What it makes clear is that if for whatever reason the ring-fence
does not work as planned, the next step is not to remove it entirely
but to go the next step.[225]
Andrew Bailey also voiced his support for such a
measure to deter banks from attempting to circumvent the ring-fence,
but noted the importance of making this a credible tool:
Get it right, and it is a very sensible deterrent
that would make people think twice about tunnelling. My point
is that we need to get it right in the sense that we need to construct
a deterrent power that the institutions know we could use.[226]
156. Witnesses noted that the way in which a full-separation
backstop was designed would be central to its effectiveness, and
that there would be important questions about accountability for
use of such a tool. Sir John Vickers said:
there are obvious questions about who would exercise
that power, if it were there as a reserve power, and under what
conditions that power would be exercised. It is not unprecedented
for companies in this country to be required to separate, but
I believe it is very rare.[227]
Paul Tucker pointed out that the appropriate accountability
for the use of a backstop would depend on whether it was intended
to trigger full separation across the whole industry or to target
an individual firm that was causing problems:
It is important to make a distinction between whether
this question is about changing the ring-fencing policy to full
separation across the board as a general policy, which should
lie with Parliamentwe do not want to be legislatorsor
about specific institutions. [...] In terms of dealing with individual
banks burrowing under the ring-fence and rendering themselves
unresolvable or not super-resolvable in consequence, the regulator
should have the power to say something.[228]
157. Andrew Bailey explored further the idea of a
regulatory tool that could be used against individual institutions:
if you found that the institution was misbehaving
in the sense that it was tunnelling under the ring-fence, that
it was masquerading things one side of the ring-fence that should
be the other side of the ring-fence, that would risk invalidating
your resolution plans. [...] at which point you would say, "I
am sorry but you have effectively voided the right to operate
this system because we cannot be sure that we could actually resolve
you in that situation because you seem to be so tricky to deal
with that we could not be sure that the plans were actually operable."[229]
Sir John Vickers noted that the requirement for full
separation in the case of individual banks would not pose the
same risk to diversification as requiring this for the sector
as a whole:
One reason why I, and we, were wary of mandating
a full split for the sector as a whole was that it could create
a sector of stand-alone, rather similar, undiversified, highly
correlated institutions, whereas if a power were deployed in relation
to one or two banks, but not the others, that loss of diversity
point would not have such traction.[230]
158. Andy Haldane pointed out that it would take
"further legal work to see whether that ultimate sanction
was practical",[231]
but pre-empted one argument that he expected might be deployed
against it:
I would be resistant to the notion that merely having
this sanction power would cause banks to look inwardto
hoard capital and not lend. We have heard that argument far too
much over the last few years, and we must not be held hostage,
in doing the right thing, by the notion that the banks will stop
lending.
He also recommended that the way to "avoid any
adverse behavioural consequences" arising from the existence
of such a backstop sanction would be to "seek absolute clarity
about where the boundaries of the ring-fence were drawn":
If there is ambiguity, blurriness or greyness in
where the boundary lies, that could legitimately cause banks to
hold back and to worry about getting on the wrong side of the
line and then facing the ultimate sanction. The greater the clarity
about where that line is drawn, the less the chances of adverse
behavioural consequences from the ring-fence.[232]
RELEVANT EXISTING AND PROSPECTIVE
POWERS
159. In examining the likely form and effectiveness
of a back-stop power of the kind that was canvassed in evidence,
it is necessary to consider the relevant existing powers of the
regulator. We noted earlier the range of powers listed by Andy
Haldane.[233] One of
these powers was to the power to vary or cancel a firm's permission
to carry on regulated business under section 45 of FSMA. This
power might notionally be used to prevent a ring-fenced bank from
carrying on certain specified regulated activities, which might
amount to all activities that fall outside the ring-fence. However,
it stops short of being a power to require a restructuring or
reorganisation of the business of a bank breaching the ring-fence.
160. There a number of safeguards for the exercise
of the power under section 45 of FSMA. First, the regulator may
only exercise this power in pursuance of its regulatory objectives,
which for these purposes will include the continuity objective
that we have discussed in the previous section when the relevant
legislation comes into force.[234]
Second, any restriction imposed upon a firm must be proportionate
to the objectives the FSA is seeking to achieve.[235]
Third, a regulator must give the regulated firm written notice
of any proposal to exercise the power, provide that firm with
a chance to make representations (whether or not the firm has
referred the matter to the Tax and Chancery Chamber of the Upper
Tribunal (Upper Tribunal)) and inform the firm of the right to
refer the matter to the Upper Tribunal. Fourth, if having considered
the representations the regulator decides to proceed, it must
provide the firm with written notice which confirms the decision
and informs the firm of the right to refer the matter to the Upper
Tribunal. Where a firm does refer a matter to the Upper Tribunal,
the case will be heard by at least one High Court judge sitting
with one or two non-legal experts. Fifth, an appeal may be made,
with leave, from the Upper Tribunal to the Court of Appeal on
a point of law.[236]
161. Paul Tucker also drew attention to the fact
that the draft Recovery and Resolution Directive (RRD), if passed
in its current draft form, would give the regulator
the power to say to a bank, including a ring-fenced
bank, that it is not resolvable, "You need to do one of a
number of things, including shifting around your organisational
structure to ensure that you are resolvable."[237]
Andy Haldane expanded on this possibility in written
evidence:
The range of sanctions envisaged in the RRD is extensive,
including divestment, limiting or ceasing certain activities and,
ultimately, requiring changes to the legal or operational structures
of the firm [...] The rationale for a reserve power would be slightly
different than in a resolution context (continuity of core service
rather than resolvability) but the underlying rationale would
be the same (protecting financial stability).[238]
CONCLUSIONS
162. There
is a strong case for the proposition that full structural separation
would be the wisest course to take. As we noted earlier, Sir Mervyn
King told us that he had "always felt that total separation
was the right way ultimately to go" and that he was "glad
that many more people are now coming on board with the idea that
a move to some kind of serious separation is the right thing to
do". At the very least, it is essential that it remains a
possibility.
163. The ring-fence
envisaged by the Government may, in the long run, not provide
an adequate degree of separation. Nor may it be adequate to buttress
banking standards. The role that separation might play in strengthening
standards across the banking sector is a matter to which we will
return in the New Year. The inadequacies of the framework may
become apparent over time, as banks seek to test the strength
of the ring-fence. The evidence received by the Commission from
the current regulators, and to which we referred in chapter 5,
highlighted the pressure which is likely to be exerted on the
regulator by banks and by politicians to take steps consistent
with short-term profitability and sectoral development, but inconsistent
with the long-term objectives of the ring-fence. Additional powers
are essential to provide adequate incentives for the banks to
comply not just with the rules of the ring-fence, but also with
their spirit. In the absence of the Commission's legislative proposals
to electrify the ring-fence, the risk that the ring-fence will
eventually fail will be much higher.
RESERVE POWERS IN RESPECT OF INDIVIDUAL
BANKING GROUPS
164. The
regulator already has powers under section 45 of FSMA to require
banks to cease certain activities in specified circumstances.
The Commission believes that it is necessary to go further. The
Commission recommends that the forthcoming legislation add reserve
powers to implement full separation.
165. The first
reserve power would be a power exercisable in respect of individual
companies. A second reserve power would relate to the sector as
a whole and would be exercisable in consequences of the review
to which we refer in paragraph 171. With regard to the first reserve
power, the Bill should include powers for the regulator to take
steps that could lead to a specific banking group affected by
the ring-fence being required to divest itself fully of either
its ring-fenced or its non-ring-fenced bank. The powers would
be exercisable only if the regulator had concluded that the conduct
of that banking group was such as to create a significant risk
that the objectives of the ring-fence would not be met in respect
of that bank. In these circumstances the regulator should consider
the group's adherence to the principles and spirit of the ring-fence
as well as its compliance with the letter of the law. The Commission
recommends that the objectives for this purpose should be aligned
with those for the relevant work of the regulator set out on the
face of the Bill, as amended from the draft Bill in accordance
with our recommendation in paragraph 130.
166. The Commission
recommendation is of sufficient significance to require a number
of limitations and safeguards. First, in order to allow time for
the ring-fence to demonstrate its effectiveness, the Commission
recommends that the Bill provides that the powers should not be
exercisable by the regulator until after the completion of the
first independent review of the effectiveness of the ring-fence
that we propose in paragraph 171 and that we envisage should be
completed less than four years after the ring-fence comes into
force. The opportunity of this delay in commencement should also
be taken by the Government to secure amendments to European legislation
to ensure that the provisions relating to full structural separation
are compatible with European law.
167. The Commission
is convinced that there is a need for clarity and certainty about
these powers. They should be separately provided for in the legislation
which the Government plans to introduce early next year. The Commission
considers that the new provisions should set out a series of steps
that would have to be taken by the regulator. First, the regulator
might be required to inform the banking group concerned of the
regulator's intention to take steps which might lead to a requirement
for full structural separation of the group. This would provide
the group with an opportunity to make representations for remedy.
If the regulator wished to proceed, the regulator might be required
to propose the appointment of an external reviewer to consider
the standards and conduct of the bank and its relationship with
the regulator. The involvement of an external reviewer at this
stage would be a crucial safeguard against discriminatory conduct
by the regulator. The Commission envisages that there would be
a statutory requirement modelled on the provisions of paragraph
1(1)(a) of Schedule 1 to the Budget Responsibility and National
Audit Act 2011 (on the appointment of the chair of the Office
for Budget Responsibility) requiring the consent of the Treasury
Committee for the regulator's proposed appointee as external reviewer.
168. In the light
of the report of the external reviewer and any representations
of the banking group, if the regulator still wished to proceed,
it would have the power to recommend that divestment of activities
either inside or outside the ring-fence take place. This power
would be subject to the same rights of appeal as the power currently
exercisable by the regulator under section 45 of FSMA. The Commission
has concluded that it would be inappropriate for the regulator,
acting alone, to move directly to enforcement of full separation
in respect of a banking group. The regulator
should therefore make its recommendation known, in the first instance,
to the Treasury, which would have the power, in the last resort,
to override its implementation. In order to ensure transparency
and parliamentary accountability, the recommendation would need
to be made public at an appropriate stage. Should the Treasury
decide to exercise its override power, that too, together with
the Treasury's reasoning, would need to be made public at the
same time. If, for reasons of
confidentiality and market confidence (amongst other reasons),
there is a delay in the publication of the recommendation, the
Chairman of the Treasury Committee should be informed in confidence
of the final recommendation.
REVIEW MECHANISM
169. The draft Bill currently contains only a narrow
review mechanism, which requires the regulator to report on the
effectiveness of its own ring-fencing rules after five years and
every five years thereafter. That review would not necessarily
comment on the wider design of the ring-fence as defined in secondary
legislation. For example, it is not obvious that the review could
comment on the de-minimis threshold or the exemption for large
depositors. The current provisions for the review laid down in
proposed section 142I of FSMA also do not prescribe the terms
of the review or any follow up mechanism, beyond requirements
for the report to be given to the Treasury, laid before Parliament
and published.
170. Reliance on the regulator to conduct the review
has the advantage that it is likely to have the best understanding
of the operation of the ring-fence in practice, through its regular
engagement with firms. However, this also carries the risk that
that the regulator could be too close to the issues, and could
find it hard to provide objective criticism of a set of rules
which it had principal responsibility for preparing and implementing.
Virgin Money noted that alternative bodies could conduct such
a review:
there is a case for the reviews to be carried out
by a body other than a body that was involved in setting the rules.
If not by the PRA, the reviews could be carried out either by
the Treasury Committee and/or by an independent body with appropriate
credentials.[239]
Sir Mervyn King favoured the legislation including:
a provision to reconstitute this body, or a successor
body, three, four, five years down the road to review how far
the ring-fencing of Vickers had worked and whether any amendments
were needed. In other words, a definite compulsory review should
be built which could not just be avoided and put off; it has to
take place in order that there would be an open study of whether
or not there had been too much borrowing.[240]
171. The
review mechanism currently included in the draft Bill is narrow
and unacceptably weak. The Commission recommends an annual report
from the PRA on the operation of the ring-fence. This is important
to provide transparency on any issues arising between the regulator
and banks and will give the regulator a vehicle for exposing attempts
to game the system, get round or burrow under the ring-fence.
The Commission recommends that the Bill be greatly strengthened.
It should require a regular review of the effectiveness of the
ring-fence across all banks to which the rules apply. The review
body's terms of reference should require it to express a view
on whether ring-fencing is achieving the objectives set out in
legislation, and to assess the case for a move to full separation
across the banking sector as a whole. The terms of reference for
the review should be set out in statute, based on the objectives
for the ring-fence as laid down in legislation. The review body
should have a duty to make recommendations to the regulator and
the Treasury about the design and application of secondary legislation
and ring-fencing rules. Prior to that review, the Bill should
require that the PRA publish a statement which summarises how
the ring-fencing rules have been implemented by the industry with
specific consideration being given to how the position of the
ring-fence has evolved, primarily focusing on what activities
and services, in addition to the core activities and core services,
sit within the ring-fenced bank and to the type of derivative
products are being offered by the ring-fenced banks. The review
body should be able to draw upon the work conducted by the regulator
as part of its statement on the position as it has evolved by
then. If the first review does not lead to full separation, second
and subsequent reviews should also draw upon the regulator's accounts
of experience in relation to the first reserve power the creation
of which the Commission has recommended. Significant use of this
reserve power would indicate that full separation across the banking
sector would be very likely to be the appropriate step. The independent
review should take place within four years of the rules implementing
the ring-fence taking effect, and regularly at an interval specified
in statute of no more than five years.
172. The review
body should be independently-led in order to provide appropriate
challenge to the Treasury and PRA, who may otherwise find it difficult
to criticise their own involvement in designing the framework.
We would expect the body to have a range of backgrounds and views
comparable to that of the ICB, although we believe that it should
also include a former very senior central banker or regulator.
198 Draft Financial Services (Banking Reform) Bill,
Clause 1 Back
199
Ev w29 Back
200
Q 1015 Back
201
Ev w188 Back
202
Q 1044 Back
203
Q 1058 Back
204
Ev w191 Back
205
Ev w198 Back
206
Qq 1144-5 Back
207
Draft Financial Services (Banking Reform) Bill, Clause 4, proposed
new section 142A(3). A similar but not identical wording appears
in proposed section 142D(3). Back
208
Draft Financial Services (Banking Reform) Bill, Clause 4, proposed
new section 142H Back
209
Ev w61 Back
210
Q 977 Back
211
Q 1187 [Paul Tucker] Back
212
Q 1187 Back
213
Ev w191 Back
214
Ev w3 Back
215
Ev w1, paras 5, 31, 35, 44, 51 Back
216
Ev w3 Back
217
Ev w54 Back
218
Ev w3 Back
219
Ev w54 Back
220
Ev w6 Back
221
Ev w54 Back
222
Ev w193 Back
223
Q 762 Back
224
Q 361 Back
225
Q 596 Back
226
Q 952 Back
227
Q 748 Back
228
Q 1155 Back
229
Q 964 Back
230
Q 752 Back
231
Q 1151 Back
232
Q 1151 Back
233
See paragraph 132. Back
234
Section 45(1)(c) FSMA Back
235
FSA Enforcement Information Guide, www.fsa.gov.uk, Chapter 8 Back
236
Section 53 FSMA Back
237
Q 1152 Back
238
Ev w198 Back
239
Ev w156 Back
240
Q 1152 Back
|