Select Committee on European Communities Tenth Report


PART 2 MAIN ISSUES (Continued)

Implementation

  65.    The Directive presupposes that Member States' laws will have two sale of goods regimes, broadly speaking one for commercial transactions and one for consumer contracts. CA did not think this would create any problems in the United Kingdom, there already being two regimes consequent upon the Unfair Contract Terms Act 1977 and the Unfair Contract Terms Directive (p 45). However, it would not, as Professor Reynolds said, be possible to repeal the existing Sale of Goods legislation in respect of consumer sales and use the Directive as a modern "Consumer Sales Act". The Directive was not sufficiently comprehensive. Professor Reynolds did not underestimate the difficulties of incorporating the Directive, especially the provisions on remedies, into our domestic law. He was not worried about different regimes existing for commercial and consumer sales: "I would be more concerned about two, or one and a half, consumer regimes" (p 198).

  66.    There was, in the view of the consumer bodies, a risk that whilst bringing some benefits the implementation of the Directive into UK law might result in a weakening of domestic consumer protection law. Article 7(2) provides that Member States may adopt or maintain in force "more stringent provisions". The draft Directive proposes only minimum harmonisation. The Commission's Explanatory Memorandum said: "the national margin of discretion will be very wide" (Appendix 3). CA said "there is the real danger that the Directive may present an opportunity for industry to apply pressure which may lead to the weakening of UK law about the sale of consumer goods" (p 51). The NCC also feared a weakening of consumers' rights: "Business lobbies regularly state that they cannot support legislation beyond the minimum because it would make their goods and services uncompetitive" (p 53). However, for the DTI, Mr Salvidge said: "If the Directive is agreed, there will be no question of diluting the protection of our law which we think is flexible, pragmatic and has stood the test of time". Moreover, before consumers' rights could be withdrawn or reduced primary legislation would be necessary (QQ 359-61).

The extent of any harmonisation

  67.    As mentioned in the previous paragraph Article 7(2) makes clear that the proposal is a "minimum" one. The proposal, the Commission accepted, would only bring about a partial harmonisation of sales laws and even if it meant that in some respects there would be differences in the laws of Member States the minimum protection given by the Directive would be better than not having that protection. The consumer would not be expected to know where, for example, some Member States went beyond the Directive. The Commission only expected consumers to know their "minimum rights" (QQ 307, 309). A number of witnesses recognised that the Directive would, nevertheless, cause changes, and bring benefits to consumers, in a number of other Member States. The Director General of Fair Trading (the Director General) said: "from many countries' perspectives the Directive will be a major step forward" (Q 83). Article 3(1) would, for example, make a substantial difference to the consumer in Germany where a restrictive six-month rule presently applies (p 137). CDC said that the Directive would improve the consumer's rights under Italian law (p 151).

  68.    LACOTS, however, said that while, in theory, the introduction of common rules should be a significant advance "the lack of detail in the Directive and the level of discretion given to Member States will ensure that significant differences remain" (p 177). Article 7(1) expressly indicates that the rights given by the Directive can be exercised without prejudice to national rules governing contractual and non-contractual liability. The proposal only seeks to harmonise certain aspects of consumer sales law and leaves intact other national rights and remedies. It does not, for example, regulate the formation of the contract or liability for possible direct or indirect damage caused by any lack of conformity. AMDEA concluded: "One certain effect of this proposal will be to change every Member State's laws whilst ensuring that every Member State's law remains different from everyone else's" (p 73).

  69.    A number of witnesses expressed regret that the Directive did not contain proposals developed from those which had been included in the Green Paper and which would have improved access to justice by a consumer who had bought defective goods in another Member State. Professor Beale said: "the real problem in our minds about cross-border shopping is not the rights you have against the retailer, it is what you do when you get back home and you find the goods will not work" (Q 72). The Directive says nothing about who shall bear the costs of returning the goods. CA said that the Directive should make this clear and that the seller should be responsible for them (p 49). Nor did the Directive do anything to assist the enforcement of legal rights cross-border. As Professor Goode noted, a consumer from the United Kingdom who makes a cash purchase abroad will usually fall outside the scope of Article 13 of the Brussels Convention on Jurisdiction and Enforcement of Judgments,[26] and so will not be able to sue in this country. In most cases the consumer will have to pursue his or her legal remedies in the seller's country, "an even more daunting prospect than suing here" (p 172). The Green Paper had raised the possibility of the producer being made responsible for defects and, as Professor Beale told the Committee, an early draft of the Directive proposed that there should be "network liability" whereby the consumer could, if need be, enforce his or her rights against the producer's authorised dealer in the area where he or she lived. Witnesses representing consumers regretted this omission from the final version of the Commission's proposal (Q 180). BEUC considered that the limitation of the proposal to the seller-consumer relationship in cross-border transactions was a major weakness of the Directive and strongly urged the amendment of Article 3 to provide for joint liability of the manufacturer (and other members of the chain of distribution) and the seller (p 145).

Costs

  70.    The Commission's Impact Statement argued that the compliance costs associated with the Directive would be negligible. It recognised that there might be a small increase in costs associated with handling defective products but stated that these could be assessed perfectly in advance on the basis of the products' reliability record (Appendix 3). The CBI rejected the Commission's view that the proposal would not result in appreciable costs: "it would involve additional costs for business e.g. increasing obligatory product exchanges when a repair could have been effected, implementing additional compliance programmes and training staff" (p 79). FSB said that the Directive would certainly increase retail costs and cause the closure of many small retailers (pp 166-7). Both the BRC and the BSSA drew attention to cost implications of the system of remedies proposed, the likelihood being that consumers would opt for a refund or replacement rather than a repair (p 74, p 142). Mr Vestey, of Sony, said: "We believe that the majority of consumers will select either refund or replacement, and these are the two things that will drive up the cost" (Q 202). Mr Brotherton, representing the John Lewis Partnership, did not accept that the Directive only reflected current best practice: "I do not think that retailers generally, even the better retailers, give an automatic right of choice to the consumer of a replacement if they have a problem with an item. What we will generally do will be to respond in the most appropriate way in accordance with the circumstances" (Q 204). Mr Round, for RETRA, described how the Directive might bear more heavily on smaller retailers (QQ 208-211). This point was also raised by the British Hardware Federation (p 141). British Furniture Manufacturers (BFM) said that the cost of this "double supply" would be high (p 140). MOTA said that manufacturing costs would increase "as disproportionately larger efforts are applied to quality inspection and durability" (p 188).

  71.    The British Radio & Electronic Equipment Manufacturers' Association (BREMA) estimated that "suppliers could be faced with an increase in their guarantee costs of up to three times their current levels. These costs will eventually work through to the consumer in price increases of as much as 4 per cent; and/or reduced choice" (p 76). In relation to personal computers, the PCA said the increase in costs could be much higher, 50-75 per cent (p 194). Mr Budd, representing BRC, said: "we have to recognise that perhaps at the other end of the spectrum, for non-technical products, the cost of providing additional consumer protection of the level proposed would be modest, but we have discussed this and we regard an average overall increase in costs of two per cent as not being an exaggeration" (Q 194). Mr Carver, representing AMDEA, saw a considerable increase in manufacturers' costs: "We are still working on our compliance cost sums, but between two and six per cent of sell-in value is round about where we think we will end up" (Q 200). On the other hand, LACOTS considered that the business burden might have been overstated and the cost implications needed further consideration (p 177). BEUC believed that there was little hard evidence that costs-and corresponding prices-would increase if the Directive became law. Manufacturers and retailers supplying goods of a reasonable quality had little to fear from an increase in consumer protection in this area (p 149).

  72.    As regards the burden of any increased costs as between manufacturers and retailers, witnesses indicated that this might depend on factors such as the nature of the product and the strength of the negotiating position as between a buyer and seller (QQ 195, 196, 200, 203). There was, however, general agreement among those representing manufacturers and retailers that in the end the additional costs would likely be borne by consumers (p 72, p 76, p 79, p 142, p 162). Panasonic said that because of the extreme competitiveness of the UK market there was insufficient margin for the cost to be borne by suppliers and that the additional costs would have to be funded either by increased charges to retailers/consumers or reduced product range and/or R & D (p 190). Mr Vestey, of Sony, said: "There is not sufficient profit in our business to be able just to absorb these sums with equanimity". Consumers might see a slow down in the rate of price reduction in real terms year on year (Q 201). Mr Carver (AMDEA) said that it was a matter of current debate as to whether the consumer would bear the increased costs in higher prices of domestic appliances or in higher charging for their servicing (Q 200). In relation to motor cars Mr Pallister, of Ford, said: "Any increase in nearly-new product which is coming back will significantly affect the residual value of new product in general, therefore it is quite possible that the customer not only will have to pay increased prices because of the increased costs of actually standing behind this level of guarantee, but will also suffer because the product he buys will depreciate faster" (Q 203).

  73.    The DTI's initial reaction was to dispute the Commission's analysis: it was possible that there could be significant compliance costs associated with the Directive (pp 116-117). However, the DTI, Miss Gane said, was re-examining the issue in the light of developments and changes in its own understanding of the Directive, especially of the likely effects of Article 3(1) and (4): "we believe that the compliance cost would be significantly lower than our provisional estimate" (QQ 370-1). Particular attention would be given to the impact of the proposal on small businesses (QQ 375, 387).

  74.    The Commission has, following a preliminary discussion of the proposal with the Member States last autumn, invited tenders for a study of the economic impact of the proposed Directive.[27] The Commission explained that the study was intended to deepen understanding of the economic impact of the proposal (Q 275). Mr Budd, for the CBI and BRC, said: "We think it is a matter for regret that this was not done before the proposals were published" (Q 193).

Competition and Competitiveness

  75.    The Commission's Impact Statement suggested that the proposal would encourage competitiveness by stimulating cross-border shopping and removing barriers to trade and the artificial compartmentalisation of markets forcing firms to be more competitive and to establish appropriate quality control systems and better working relations (Appendix 3). The CBI did not accept the Commission's argument that the proposal would enhance competition. Harmonisation of the legal rights in question would, in the CBI's view, adversely affect competition: the range of goods available to consumers might be reduced (p 78). The FSB also drew attention to the possibility that there would be less choice in the high street: "Small retailers in their anxiety to ensure that the goods they promote are brand goods with a long track record will be reluctant to experiment with new and innovative products. This will, of course, be disadvantageous to innovation and to new entrants in the market place" (p 167). The GCCNI's Report, however, contended that cross-border shopping brought potential benefits: wider consumer choice, greater market efficiency and better living standards. It encouraged competition: "It can stimulate retailers in the home market to match the highest standards offered elsewhere in order to retain their customers, and it can encourage companies to consider ways of distributing their products beyond their traditional markets".[28] BEUC also argued that giving consumers a minimum corpus of rights throughout the Community could encourage efficiency (p 150).

  76.    As regards the international competitiveness of EC firms, this, the CBI said, would be reduced because of the additional costs which the Directive would impose (p 78). This view was supported by UNICE (p 216). Mr Carver, for AMDEA, said: "This Directive is going to do nothing to improve the quality of the manufacturers' performance ... that was not the job that the author of the Directive was given" (Q 213). The PCA pointed out that in an industry such as personal computers where most of the components originated outside the EC and were made for a global market, UK and other EC based trade distributors of those components would have to bear a disproportionate part of the costs of faulty products: "Global distribution based outside the EC would enjoy the economies of scale and increased market share, to the detriment of the EC distributors" (p 194).

Environmental implications

  77.    The Commission believed that the proposal would have beneficial effects on the environment by reducing over exploitation of natural resources and waste (Appendix 3). Both the BRC and the CBI contradicted the Commission's view that the Directive would have positive environmental effects. Giving the consumer the choice of remedies, especially the option to demand a replacement or refund even where repair was viable and appropriate, would create unnecessary waste (pp 75-6, p 79). There would, as AMDEA said, be an environmental cost to pay: "`Returned product' is often scrapped" (p 72). If repaired goods cannot be placed on some form of second hand market, Mr Vestey said, "you will have a great number of otherwise serviceable products entering the waste stream prematurely and conflicting with current concerns about end-of-life product recycling which is currently being discussed in Europe and elsewhere" (Q 240). DMA had similar concerns about the build up of unwanted goods (p 158). MOTA said that more products would have to be manufactured (p 187). The amount of freight transportation would also increase (p 79). The consumer bodies did not accept this. NCC said: "In reality if retailers offer a very speedy repair, in appropriate circumstances, we do not expect consumers to demand replacement" (p 53). The DTI said that, as regards the use of resources, there was no evidence that the Directive would affect the durability of goods in such a way as to reduce significantly the rate of production of goods or demands for raw materials. As regards waste, the Directive might, because replacements could increase, lead to a rise in the number of goods needing to be disposed of. If so, firms' reactions would be likely to vary considerably according to the nature and value of the goods and the nature of the defect. The DTI did not believe that the Directive would have a significant impact on the environment (p 123, Q 372).

Employment

  78.    The Commission's Impact Study suggested that the Directive was capable of having a positive impact on employment by increasing the demand for maintenance and quality control services which by definition were labour-intensive (Appendix 3). A number of witnesses said that the Directive could have adverse effects for employment. Again the cause was the proposal that the consumer should have the option to have a refund or replacement rather than the retailer having the opportunity first to repair the goods. The CBI rejected the Commission's assertion that the proposal would have positive effects on employment: "There is no evidence for this assertion, and it may even have the reverse effect by, for example, reducing demand for repair services" (p 79). The BRC and the DMA also pointed to a likely negative impact on service engineers' employment and the repair industry (p 74, p 158). Mr Vestey, of Sony, explained that the vast majority of repairs of faulty brown goods were carried out by local repair operators operating on very tight margins. These might have to be closed down and be replaced by manufacturers' central repair facilities working more efficiently and employing fewer people (QQ 240, 243). The CBI and BRC estimated that in the brown and white goods sector there were some 50,000 people employed as repairers. A reduction of up to 20 per cent was, they said, considered to be realistic (p 96). The DTI, however, having looked in particular at employment in repair services, did not believe that the Directive would have a significant impact (Q 372).

Legal base

  79.    The Commission has put forward its proposal on the basis of Article 100a of the EC Treaty. This, according to the Commission's Explanatory Memorandum, would be consistent with Article 129a of the Treaty, which deals with the Community's Consumer Protection policy. Under that Article, the object of the Community's policy is defined as being to contribute to the attainment of a high level of consumer protection through measures taken under Article 100a in the context of the completion of the Single Market or specific action which supports and supplements Member States' consumer protection policies.

  80.    Consumer bodies, in particular BEUC, CA and CDC, said that reference should also be made to Article 129a in order to give the consumer policy objective its proper basis (p 45, p 144, p 152). BEUC said: "the text of the Directive presents the minimum harmonisation of guarantees merely as a useful measure for the implementation of the Internal Market, under Article 100a. By making no reference to Article 129a the Commission emphasises the functioning of the internal market objective of the proposal, and seems to make the consumer policy objective a secondary one" (p 144). The Law Society also thought that the Directive should contain a reference to Article 129a (p 182). The Commission, however, was clear that the proposal belonged in the context of the internal market and that Article 100a was the correct and a sufficient legal base. Article 129a had not been forgotten: that Article referred to Article 100a. A reference to Article 129a was, therefore, implicit in the present proposal (QQ 275, 290). The DTI agreed that Article 100a was the appropriate legal base and that a reference to Article 129a was not necessary (Q 390).

Subsidiarity

  81.    The Commission's Explanatory Memorandum seeks to justify the proposal in the light of the principle of subsidiarity on the grounds that the measure concerns an area where the Community has sole jurisdiction, namely the creation and operation of the Single Market; that the objective can only be achieved by laying down minimum (legal) rules; and that the Directive is strictly limited to the essential aspects concerning legal and commercial guarantees (Appendix 3). The Commission, Mr Pappas explained, had considered and rejected the idea that the objective could be achieved by "soft law" (e.g. code of conduct). Nor did the Commission consider it sufficient to try to persuade individual Member States (where consumer protection might be weaker than, for example, in the United Kingdom) to improve their laws. Mr Pappas said: "the rôle of the Commission is to deal with problems justified at European level. This is, in a way, also the meaning of subsidiarity. The concern here was to create an internal market ... giving the confidence to consumers [to shop abroad] ... harmonisation here was indispensable for the Commission" (QQ 285, 289). The DTI, however, had doubts about whether the Directive passed the subsidiarity test under the Edinburgh guidelines but recognised that other Member States might have a different view on the question (QQ 388, 391).


26   Given effect in the United Kingdom by the Civil Jurisdiction and Judgments Act 1982. Back

27   1996 OJ C359/20. The invitation to tender provides: "This contract has 3 aims:

- first of all it will be advisable to assess the financial impact the directive proposal is likely to have on professional environments and consumers,

- then it will need to determine what advantages the directive proposal will have on these same economic environments and compare them with the possible costs of the previous point. When assessing the advantages, the following could be taken into account: customer satisfaction and loyalty, product durability, competitiveness, as well as repercussions that the use of the directive proposal could have,

- finally, as regards determining by product sector what effects the directive proposal is likely to have on the economic relation between the distributor and producer, especially in the application of Article 3(5) of the proposal". Back

28   Cross Border Shopping in the Island of Ireland, Extending Consumer Choice, page 10. Back


 
previous page contents next page
House of Lords home page></A>
<A href=Parliament home page House of Commons home page search page enquiries

© Parliamentary copyright 1997
Prepared 20 March 1997