Select Committee on European Communities Eleventh Report


PART 3  WITNESSES' EVIDENCE AND OPINION OF THE COMMITTEE (Continued)


ENLARGEMENT

  98.    Enlargement, when it takes place, will bring into the EU countries with an average GDP per capita well below that of the poorest present Member State. To assess the impact of enlargement on the structural policies of the EU a number of questions need to be considered: when will the first wave of enlargement take place; which countries will be involved; what will be their economic and social needs in terms of reducing disparities in line with the EU's treaty commitments to cohesion policies; what funding will this require; at what rate can funding be absorbed by the new entrant countries; what will be the impact on the funds available for structural purposes in the existing EU15?

  99.    The evidence we received on these large topics seemed to be based on widely differing assumptions. One was that the cohesion needs of the new Member States could be met only by a substantial reduction of the monies devoted to the CAP. Another attitude-a sub-text rather than an assumption-was that there should be no reduction in funds flowing to the present recipients. Another discernible sub-text in some memoranda was that there should be a significant increase in the size of the EC Budget. We do not think it profitable to pursue many of these speculations. We propose to concentrate on what we take to be the best informed views that we have encountered: these come from the Commissioner with a particular responsibility for structural issues, Mrs Wulf-Mathies. We were surprised that a speech she made on 19 June 1996 to the EU Committee of the German Bundestag did not appear to have received greater attention and analysis in this country.

  100.    The key financial elements of Commissioner Wulf-Mathies' speech[23] were as follows. In 1999 0.46 per cent of the EU's GDP will be available for use by the Structural Funds and the Cohesion Fund. If this percentage were adopted for the next programming period, 2000-2006, around 37 billion ecu a year would be available compared to the present period 1994-99 when there has been about 28 billion ecu a year. Two consequences follow: first, the present own resources ceiling of 1.27 per cent of GDP for the EC Budget would be maintained; and second, there would be a 30 per cent increase in the funds available for structural policy, without an increased burden on the tax payer.

  101.    In her speech Commissioner Wulf-Mathies went on to suggest that this money could be used to give a substantial (sevenfold) increase in the EU support now given to the CEECs, presently through the Phare programme[24]. This could, she said, lead to a marked pick-up in their economic growth. There would still be scope for continuing the cohesion policy of the EU15: support to regions with per capita GDP of less than 75 per cent of the EC average could be maintained in full. Some of the present Objective 1 regions would no longer qualify under this criterion because of the improvement in their percentage average GDP: this might apply to parts of Spain, Portugal, Ireland and Italy but, she thought, the new German Länder would still be likely to qualify as Objective 1 regions.

Opinion: enlargement and EMU

  102.    We expect enlargement to take place not as a big bang but at various times determined by the readiness of the incoming countries. As a first approximation it might be estimated that the first wave, which might not take place before 2002, would comprise the four Visegrad countries (the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovakia) and Slovenia. Other accessions could follow later. According to Mrs Wulf-Mathies' calculations the newly admitted countries and those CEECs still pursuing their pre-accession strategies could receive substantially increased aid for cohesion purposes without reducing the total amount of the structural funds going to the 15 Member States which now form the Union. We recommend that the assumptions underlying these calculations be fully explained by the Commission so that their validity and the credibility of their message about the financial implications of enlargement for cohesion policy can be tested in open public discussion.

  103.    Our approach to the post-1999 period is to look first at the political realities. On the one hand there are forces against an increase in the structural funds. After 1999 the disciplines of sustainable convergence, whether or not EMU goes ahead on schedule, will still be required throughout the EU. There will be strong incentives for the Member States which are net contributors to resist any increase in the size of the EC Budget. The advent of EMU may, in the short term, lead some Member States to seek to increase their domestic income transfer payments to adversely affected regions. If this situation were to arise, it would not, in our view, be a justification for an increase in EU funds provided for investment in structural development, although we can foresee that the contrary might be argued on the grounds that EMU has made structural change more urgent[25]. On the other hand, enlargement will increase the disparities of development within the enlarged EU thereby creating pressures for more spending on cohesion policy in the new Member States. The level of funding that could successfully be absorbed by these countries without distorting their economies is a crucial consideration. Observation of the operation of the structural funds within the EU15 and the operation of the Phare[26] programme within the CEECs convinces us that recipient countries do not have an unlimited capacity either to handle and absorb net inflows of investment funds without damaging economic distortions or to produce the co-financing required. We are not in a position to form a firm view on what that absorption ceiling would be for any individual country, but we should be surprised if it were to exceed 4 per cent of GDP for even the best performing economies among the CEECs.

  104.    Our conclusion, based on our assessment of what is politically realistic, is that the best assumption for planning purposes is that the EC Budget ceiling of 1.27 per cent of EU GDP will not be increased after 1999. We also believe that the proportion of the EC Budget devoted to cohesion policies should be increased beyond the present one third only to the extent that the proportion going to support the CAP is reduced.

Opinion: distribution of funds within the EU after 1999

  105.    We assume, for the reasons set out in the immediately preceding paragraphs, that after 1999 about one third of the EC Budget will be available for structural policies. What this will amount to in absolute terms depends on the growth rates achieved by the EU but it seems that these are unlikely to be significantly different from those currently achieved. The prospect of a modest increase in the funds available each year in the period after 1999 is no justification for not putting in hand the radical reform of the funds which we recommend. We now consider in more detail the new arrangements as we think they might be after a reform based on the principles and processes set out in paragraphs 90-92 above.

  106.    We do not propose a blue-print for the reformed funds, but we make some suggestions for further consideration by national governments and the European Institutions. Geographical concentration is imperative. Commissioner Wulf-Mathies' figure for population coverage of 35 per cent (see paragraph 51 above) is, we assume, an aspiration rather than the result of aggregating the populations of the regions of greatest need assessed by objective economic indicators. The first questions which we think deserve further study are what indicators should be used and within what geographic boundaries should measurements be averaged in endeavouring to assess economic and social cohesion. Average GDP per capita, the criterion for Objective 1 status, and the unemployment rate, the criterion for Objective 2 status, are crude measures which do not fully reflect such relevant factors such as the age structure of the population, the existing capital infrastructure and the state of the labour market.

  107.    As to the spatial boundaries of areas for individual measurement we see the need to balance conflicting factors: on the one hand, the region defined should be large enough to have a degree of economic coherence but, on the other hand, it should be small enough to permit the identification of pockets of deprivation within generally more prosperous areas. In some of the wealthiest cities extremes of poverty can be found: London and Edinburgh are no exceptions.

  108.    We see a need for substantial concentration, or pruning, of themes or eligible objectives. We formed the impression, particularly on our visits that, at times, the potential recipients of EU funding were casting about for ways to spend money rather than fitting deserving projects into a properly considered strategy. Again, we do not attempt to prescribe detail, but we recommend that the over-riding considerations when determining eligibility criteria for projects within the more concentrated geographical areas, which we recommended in the preceding paragraph, should be: increasing competitiveness, increasing sustainable employment, and adjusting skills to meet changing labour market needs.

  109.    We have considered whether the Cohesion Fund should continue as a separate instrument after 1999. Its overtly proclaimed purpose is to assist convergence towards the criteria for entry to EMU. At first sight, therefore, any Member State which joins EMU no longer requires assistance from the Cohesion Fund. However, in accordance with the principle of continuity on which reform should be based (see paragraph 92 above), we recommend that, when one of the Cohesion countries joins EMU, Cohesion Fund assistance to that country should be tapered off. Others of the Four remaining outside EMU should continue to receive assistance from the Cohesion Fund if their GDP per capita remains below 90 per cent of the EU15 average: we say EU15, despite the possibility of enlargement, because it provides the basis for continuity.

  110.    As to the form in which assistance should be given for cohesion purposes to the CEECs, we think there are two rather different sets of circumstances. The first concerns CEECs in the pre-accession period. The Phare[27] programme is already helping them adapt to democratic market economies. We suggest that consideration should be given to adding to the Phare programme for each CEEC an element particularly addressed to achieving balanced regional development within that country. In the post-accession period we assume that new Member States will enjoy various derogations for transitional periods extending over several years. In this transitional period it seems to us to be prudent to apply the EU's cohesion policies and the financial instruments which support them with a ceiling so that the total in-flow of EU funds should be no more than 4 per cent of the recipient country's GDP. Our reasons for supporting such a "cap" on net in-flows were set out above, in paragraph 103. In the transitional period we assume that the fund for the new Member States would, by analogy with the Cohesion Fund, have no requirement for additionality.


23   The text considered was the summary of the speech published by the Commission in InfoRegio, August 1996. Back

24   The Phare programme was set up by the EC in 1989 following the collapse of the communist regimes in central and eastern Europe. The acronym "Phare" is derived from the French "Pologne/Hongrie: Assistance à la Restructuration Economique". The programme was soon extended to cover Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Romania and the Slovak Republic and later to include Albania, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Slovenia and Croatia. The programme is intended to help the recipient countries transform their economies and strengthen the democratic basis of their economies. For the countries applying to join the EU the programme is intended to help them create the conditions required for future membership of the EU. The programme covers a wide range of sectoral activities including infrastructure development (energy, transport and telecommunications), education, health, training, research, private sector development and enterprise support and environmental development and protection. For 1997 the Draft general Budget of the EC provides appropriations for the Phare programme of about 1 billion ecu. Back

25   See paragraph 134 of An EMU of `Ins' and `Outs', Session 1995-96, 11th Report, HL Paper 86. Back

26   See footnote 24. Back

27   See footnote 24. Back


 
previous page contents next page
House of Lords home page></A>
<A href=Parliament home page House of Commons home page search page enquiries

© Parliamentary copyright 1997
Prepared 25 March 1997