Memorandum by International Council for
Capital Formation (ICCF)
1. SUMMARY
1.1 Comprehensive economic modeling is essential
to the world's understanding of climate change and the development
of optimum, realistic solutions to address the issue. Only by
including analysis of the macroeconomic impacts of alternatives
policies such as the Kyoto Protocol, can the best policy solutionson
a national and international levelbe identified and developed.
1.2 The International Council for Capital
Formation[37]
(ICCF) has researched and developed robust evidence, which is
presented here for the House of Lords' Select Committee on Economic
Affairs. This evidence is based on detailed comparisons that have
been made between the various economic assessments used by the
UK government, the European Commission, the Intergovernmental
Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) and, by stark contrast, the United
States government.
1.3 This evidence and analysis shows that
attempts to constrain European greenhouse gas emissions (GHGs)
at the rate required by Kyoto will have large economic costs,
which have been severely underestimated by European and UK policymakers
to date. These economic impacts could drastically cripple these
developed economies over the next decade and further beyond. Further,
pursuing policy that undermines growth actually limits the ability
of both developed and developing countries to engage protective,
environmental measures.
1.4 The ICCF is an established think tank
focusing on developing sound research and workable solutions to
global problems affecting the environment, energy, tax policy,
intellectual property rights and private pension plans for retirement
security and trade.
1.5 The ICCF circulates its publications,
commentary, and ideas around the globe to reach public officials
on both sides of the Atlantic as well as in the Pacific Rim. The
ICCF Board of Directors includes business leaders and opinion
makers from around the globe. Founding board members include:
Mr Rudi Bogni, Sir Richard Greenbury, Mr Robert L. Hamburger,
Dr Friedrich Hoess, Dr Vincenz Lichtenstein, Sir Ralph Robbins,
Hon. George P Schulz, Mr Peter Spira, Hon. Robert S Strauss, Sir
Kenneth Warren and Hon. John C Whitehead.
2. What has been the approach within the
IPCC to the economic aspects of climate change, and how satisfactory
has it been?
2.1 Notably, the IPCC's approach to the
economic aspects of climate change has largely ignored the results
of a range of macroeconomic modeling showing the impacts of its
advocated climate change policies, including Kyoto. Further, in
many of its published papers,[38]
the IPCC has argued that project and sectoral level cost models
are more accurate than the use of macroeconomic models[39].
However this core assumption and many of the other assumptions
underpinning its "Special Report of Emission Scenarios";
(SRES) have been challenged by leading economists.
2.2 A range of macroeconomic models can
be used to reveal the potential costs of various climate change
policies. The IPCC itself admits, "The implied costs of different
climate change policies are quite sensitive to the underlying
model used."[40]
2.3 As a recent study by Dr Michael Canes[41]
illustrates, (figure 1)[42],
an accurate portrayal of the costs of complying with GHG emission
reduction targets depends largely on choosing an economic model
that captures the entire short and medium-term costs of adjusting
to higher energy prices or regulatory mandates on the economy
as a whole.
Figure 1.

2.4 Bottom-up energy models are constructed
from engineering data applied to specific technologies whereas
top-down energy models are based on statistical analysis of past
data. Both can be useful in understanding the effects of policy
on energy markets, but bottom-up models often neglect certain
costs that reduce returns on investment below what is predicted,
resulting in unrealistic estimates of what will occur if energy
markets are shocked. Top-down models are based on technology and
institutions existing at the time their data applies to and hence
may underestimate the ability of markets to adapt, but such models
often incorporate technology parameters, induced technological
change, or explicit changes in technology in order to avoid such
bias, thus incorporating bottom-up features within a top-down
approach. Because these models are based on actual behavioral
responses rather than simulation under somewhat idealized conditions,
they appear to be the most realistic way to accurately estimate
the consequences of climate change policy.
2.5 For example, a "bottom-up"
model, such as the PRIMES model used by EU environmental agencies
is designed only for measuring sectoral effects and not economy-wide
effects. PRIMES, a partial equilibrium model, is primarily designed
to show the effect of policy changes on energy markets. It can
calculate the direct cost implications of reduced energy use,
but not the economy-wide impact on gross domestic product (GDP),
employment and investment. Thus, the results of this model, which
show a reduction of only 0.12 per cent in GDP to the EU in 2012
from complying with Kyoto, are not an accurate measure of the
total costs.
2.6 Such reliance on results from PRIMES,
which is a useful tool for understanding the impact of changes
on energy markets but does not give the "big picture,"
has led Europeans to believe that the costs of achieving Kyoto
targets will be relatively small. This is inaccurate. General
equilibrium and macroeconomic models paint a very different picture
of the impact of Kyoto on GDP levels in the EU. General equilibrium
models measure the "big picture" impacts on an economy
after it has had time to adjust, perhaps over three or four decades,
to higher energy prices and regulatory mandates. General equilibrium
models, such as MERGE3, ABARE-GTEM or MS-MRT, show GDP losses
of about 1 per cent per year from 2010 onwards in the EU as a
result of Kyoto.
2.7 Macroeconomic models, such as Oxford
or DRI-WEFA (now Global Insight), are general equilibrium models
that explicitly account for market disequilibria caused by economic
shocks. In addition to identifying long-term costs, these models
provide the most complete near and intermediate-term analysis
of the costs of Kyoto-implementing policy. Results in Figure 1
indicate such models provide cost estimates, for European compliance
with Kyoto, that are 50-100 per cent higher than those from pure
general equilibrium models.
2.8 Results of ICCF analysis, conducted
within the 3 years, show that real GDP across European member
states would fall 1 to 1.5 per cent below predicted levels during
the 2008-12, without materially reducing global concentrations
of greenhouse gases. These results, supported by a range of independent
think tanks and research bodies[43],
show that the real cost to European economies, of implementing
Kyoto, could be between 10 to 15 times greater than current EU
predictions.
2.9 In November 2004, UNICE, the pan-industry,
pan-European employers group, which represents more than 20 million
small, medium and large businesses across Europe, also published
results of a study on the economic costs of Kyoto. The study,
conducted by Cowi Consultants using a general equilibrium model,
reveals that current EU policies to meet Kyoto targets would most
likely shave 0.48 per cent off the bloc's GDP by 2010, rather
than the 0.1 per cent reduction initially forecast by the European
Commission.[44]
2.91 These few examples are part of a growing
volume of robust evidence, (presented by a range of respected
organizations with varying interests), which indicates that the
real costs of IPCC-supported policiesincluding the Kyoto
Protocolhave been severely underestimated. Policymakers
have been deprived of key findings needed to accurately weigh
the costs and benefits of near-term targets and timetables to
reduce GHGs in the EU. As long as the IPCC continues to ignore
this evidence, its approach to the economic aspects of climate
change will remain unsatisfactory. Policymakers need to have access
to cost estimates based on appropriate climate policy models in
order to develop plans for the post 2012 period that will not
undermine job and industry growth across the wider European economy.
3. Could IPCC member governments, and the
UK in particular, do more in future to contribute to the robustness
of the economic analysis?
3.1 One of the advantages of using macroeconomic
models to perform robust and comprehensive economic analysis lies
in their ability to capture near and intermediate-term adjustment
costs, as well as the longer term costs associated with the market
shocks of implementing the Kyoto Protocol. Some of the advantages
of using macro-economic models are illustrated by making direct
comparison between the approaches taken by the EU and the US.
3.2 Macroeconomic models provide an assessment
of the overall costs of meeting emission targets where the short-term,
frictional costs of adjustment are included. These models were
used by US scholars and climate policy modelers in the early 1990s
to measure the impact of Kyoto on the US economy. They quantify
the impact on employment, investment, budget receipts and GDP
growth when an economy is "shocked" by having to make
quick changes in its capital stock, production processes and lifestyles.
3.3 In contrast to the EU "target and
timetables" approach to climate change, the US has chosen
a different path, one based on gradually reducing energy intensity.
The main reason that the Bush Administration rejected the Kyoto
Protocol approach was that they had analyzed the costs of sharp,
near-term emission reductions and found that the economic costs
were significant and the benefits (in terms of reduced global
concentrations of CO2) were negligible. A range of credible macroeconomic
models showed that Kyoto would have negative effects on the US
economy in the range of 2 per cent to almost 4 per cent of GDP
in 2010.
3.4 This approach has since been supported
by factual comparison between both the economic and the environmental
performances of the EU and US economies. According to data from
the US Department of Energy's Energy Information Administration,
the USusing a voluntary approachhas reduced its
energy intensity (or the amount of energy required to produce
a dollar of GDP) by a significantly larger percentage than has
the European Union (see figure 2.) The EU, which ratified the
Kyoto Protocol and thus faces mandatory emission reductions, has
reduced energy intensity by only 7.5 per cent compared to the
15.8 per cent reduction achieved by the US over the 1999-2001
period.
3.5 Similarly, the ratio of CO2 emissions
per dollar of output has decreased faster in the US than in the
EU over the past decade15.3 per cent for the US compared
to 13.8 per cent in Europe. By adopting its voluntary approach
to emission reductions, the Bush Administration balances multiple
policy objectives, including maintaining strong economic growth
and enhanced environmental quality. In contrast, EU economic growth
is weak and unemployment high (about 10 per cent in recent years).
3.6 These models offer decision makers,
who are concerned with maintaining healthy GDP, employment and
other economic indices over the next several years, the most complete
understanding of what to expect. For this reason, they are essential
in contributing to the development of sound environmental policy
that does not endanger the economies of the countries in or across
which it is implemented.
Figure 2.

4. What would
be the relative costs and benefits of using resources, otherwise
expected to be allocated to climate change control, instead to
expand international development assistance?
4.1 Academics and scholars at public policy
think tanks in the US have devoted considerable effort to measuring
the costs and benefits of near-term emission reduction targets.
According to scholars such as Brookings Institution economist,
Dr Robert Crandall, setting targets and timetables for US greenhouse
gas emissions is premature. He bases this conclusion on:
The uncertainty about whether or
not the extent to which global warming is occurring; new data
from climatologist and UN Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change
author Professor John Christy, University of Alabama, demonstrates
that while surface-based measures show warming, satellite data
shows little warming; and
The high cost of foregone investment
if the US sacrifices badly needed economic growth to reduce emissions.
4.2 In a 1999 report, Dr Crandall observes
that the economic estimates of the costs and benefits of reducing
emissions to 1990 levels that are in the literature are not particularly
supportive of going ahead immediately with any policy of abatement.
For example, as an analysis by Brookings Institution Fellows Drs
Warwick McKibben and Peter Wilcoxen points out, the estimates
of the costs of capping emissions at 1990 levels generally range
from 1 to 2 per cent of GDP per year, while the benefits, estimated
at most to be 1/3 per cent of GDP, will not arise for at least
30 to 50 years. Dr Crandall notes that "Every dollar dedicated
to greenhouse gas abatement today could be invested to grow into
$150 in the next 50 years at a 10 per cent social rate of return,
even at a puny 5 per cent annual return, each dollar would grow
into $12 in 50 years. Therefore, we need to be sure that the prospective
benefits, when realized, are at least 12 to 150 times the current
cost of securing them. Otherwise, we should simply not act, but
use our scarce resources in other ways." Moreover, the climate
models generally forecast that it would require far greater reductions
than a return to 1990 emissions to stabilize the climate. Dr Crandall
concludes, "We cannot justify a return to 1990 emissions
based on the average estimates in the literature, no matter how
efficiently it has done."
4.3 It is clear that the marginal costs
of abatement in low-income societies such as China and India are
substantially below those in developing countries, Dr Crandall
notes. Economists envision a marketable permits program as being
global in scope. The United States, France, Japan and Germany,
for example, would buy permits from China, India or Bangladesh.
The latter would, in turn, reduce their CO2 or other greenhouse
gas emissions by this amount over the levels that would have occurred
without the permits policy in all future years. The difficulties
involved in such a future program would be immense: measuring
emissions from millions of sources from motor scooters to bovine
animals; forecasting emission levels for the uncontrolled scenario;
and finally, enforcing the reductions from these myriad sources.
If enforcing nuclear nonproliferation treaties is difficult, enforcing
a global greenhouse gases trading program would be incomparably
more complicated.
4.4 Yale University Professor, William D
Nordhaus, has also analyzed the costs and benefits of CO2 emission
limits. Dr Nordhaus's research shows that the costs of even an
efficiently designed emission reduction program exceed the value
of environmental benefits by a ratio of 7 to 1 and that the U.S.
would bear almost two-thirds of the global cost. As EU scholars
examine the costs of near-term GHG emission limits to the EU versus
the benefits (in terms of reductions in global emissions), they
are likely to reach conclusions similar to those above. As the
May 2005 Copenhagen Consensus forum in Denmark concluded, the
world's most acute problems are HIV-AIDs and lack of sanitation
and clean drinking water in developing countries. More aid for
these critical problems, from which literally millions are dying
yearly, would yield greater benefits than efforts to try and force
down GHG emissions in the developed world. Climate change is an
important issue and it should continue to receive funding for
new energy technologies, carbon sequestration and the study of
climate science, but it should not take priority over funding
more urgent global problems.
4.5 Increased economic freedom is the best
way to promote cleaner energy use in developing countries. Economic
freedom positively impacts economic growth; faster economic growth
is linked with reduced energy intensity and lower emissions per
dollar of output. In other words, a focus on economic growth is
a surer path forward in addressing climate change. Policies like
the Kyoto Protocol are not a step forward; they're actually a
step backward because they impede economic growth with virtually
no positive environmental benefits. For example, if China and
India installed new industrial equipment, as efficient as that
currently employed by Japan and the United States, their emissions
intensity per dollar of output would drop much faster and global
concentrations of CO2 would fall much more rapidly (see Figure
3)[45].
Figure 3.

28 February 2005
37 The website for the International Council for Capital
Formation (ICCF) can be found at www.iccfglobal.org Back
38
Source: Page 27 "Macroeconomic costs", within "Guidance
papers on the cross-cutting issues of the third assessment report
of the IPCC", July 2000 http://www.ipcc.ch/pub/xcutting.pdf Back
39
Source: "Guidance papers on the cross-cutting issues of
the third assessment report of the IPCC", July 2000 http://www.ipcc.ch/pub/xcutting.pdf Back
40
Source: "Guidance papers on the cross-cutting issues of
the third assessment report of the IPCC", July 2000 http://www.ipcc.ch/pub/xcutting.pdf Back
41
"Economic modeling of climate change policy", Dr Michael
E Canes, October 2002-Dr Canes is a Senior Research Fellow at
the Logistics Management Institute in McLean, Virginia. His work
includes making annual estimates of the greenhouse gas emissions
of the Unites States Postal Service and helping that organsisation
identify options for emissions reduction. Dr. Canes has a PD in
Economics from UCLA and an MSc in Economics from the London School
of Economics. The updated version of this paper is in a new book
by the ICCF, called "Climate Change Policy and Economic
Growth: A Way Forward to Ensure Both", available at:
http://www.iccfglobal.org/research/climate/climate-change-book.html Back
42
Graph data source: Charles River Associates http://www.crai.com/ Back
43
Reference: climate change workshop co-sponsored by the International
Council for Capital Formation, Centre for the New Europe, Istituto
Bruno Leoni and Institut Economique Molinari, held on Wednesday,
24 November, 2004 in Brussels. Press release http://www.iccfglobal.org/research/climate/cop-10dec2004.html Back
44
Source: Union des Industries de la Communaute« europe«enne
(UNICE). From UNICE's contribution to the European Commission's
consultation concerning action on climate change, post 2012 (31.10.04)
www.unice.org Back
45
Graph data source: Charles River Associates http://www.crai.com/ Back
|