Memorandum by Professor Colin Robinson,
Emeritus Professor of Economics, University of Surrey
My interest in the economics of climate change
comes about because, for over 40 years, my main research efforts
have been in the field of energy economics and policy. The production,
distribution and consumption of energy products all have impacts
on the environment and so energy policy has, in recent years,
come to be dominated by environmental issues and, in particular,
by the view that governments and international institutions should
take action to combat the effects of human activities on world
climate. In the British government's February 2003 White Paper
on energy[1],
for example, the principal theme is that an expensive programme
of promoting "renewable" sources of energy, combined
heat and power and energy conservation is justified by the need
to ". . . put (the UK) on a path towards a reduction in carbon
dioxide emissions of some 60 per cent by about 2050"[2].
In various recent publications[3],
I have expressed scepticism about the predicted extent of global
warming and about the counter-measures proposed. In this brief
memorandum, I summarise the reasons why one should look critically
at the global warming consensus that now so influences policy
in many countries and I suggest some issues that the Committee
might wish to consider. The memorandum is intended to help set
the scene for the Committee's deliberations.
1. APOCALYPTIC
FORECASTS
To set in context present-day predictions of
climate change effects, one issue I suggest the Committee should
consider is whether the present prevailing wisdom about climate
change is another example of the apocalyptic forecasts that have
a long history in energy markets and that have so far proved greatly
exaggerated[4].
These forecasts of doom have usually concerned
the depletion of fossil fuel resources (coal, oil and natural
gas). In recent times the outstanding example has been the consensus
that formed in the 1970s and early 1980s that energy depletion,
especially of crude oil resources, was proceeding at an excessive
pace[5].
It was argued that the world faced potential disaster in the foreseeable
future which could be averted only by massive centralised action
by national governments and international institutions: coal,
nuclear power and synthetic fuels, in particular, should be promoted
by governments to make the switch away from oil that proponents
of this view argued was urgent, and economic growth rates should
be reduced to conserve resources. "The days of cheap energy
are gone for ever" is a well-known catchphrase of the times.
In the event, the excessive energy depletion hypothesis turned
out to be misguided and, probably fortunately, the associated
calls for massive central action met little response. Government
action was very limited, but by the early 1980s, 10 years after
the first "oil shock", decentralised energy market forces
had turned apparent scarcity into apparent surplus, the world
was awash with oil and the Organisation of Petroleum Exporting
Countries was meeting to try to prop up the price of crude oil.
Although the present consensus concerns pollution
rather than resource depletion, it may, ex post, appear as part
of a doomster tendency with a long history[6].
Prophets of doom have their benefits: they serve a useful function
if they help to stimulate the innovations that eventually solve
the problems they foresee. However, they can also be dangerous
if they force on to the community today costs that need never
have been incurred because these problems would have been solved
at less cost by normal decentralised market processes and associated
technological advance. The underlying issue is that, with some
reflection, any intelligent person can think of all manner of
problems that might afflict the world in the future but to which
solutions do not at present exist. But, as Dennis Gabor remarked,
"The problems of 50 years hence will not have to be solved
by our present-day technology but by that which we shall possess
in 20 or 30 years' time"[7].
I would also point out that past experience
suggests that once a consensus emerges and passes into the conventional
wisdomas the climate change consensus has doneit
is difficult to dislodge by the normal processes of scientific
challenge because an "industry" appears that is dedicated
to preserving the consensus. Governments make statements about
the need to deal with the problems the consensus identifies. The
scientific establishment comes to depend on research grants which
are most easily obtained if research projects appear to deal with
accepted problems. Consultants gear their efforts to advise on
these same issues. The media constantly run stories that appear
to reinforce the consensus. For all these reasons the consensus
is highly resistant to change.
Of course, I am not suggesting that the prevailing
wisdom about climate change should be dismissed because in earlier
times the consensus has been incorrect. My point is that past
experience should make us wary of accepting the scientific consensus
without very critical examination. As part of that examination
I would suggest the following.
2. HOW ROBUST
IS THE
SCIENCE?
First, I would urge the Committee to solicit
evidence from some of the scientists who dissent from the consensus.
In the past, minority views have often been nearer the truth than
the consensus (for instance, in the cases of the over-depletion
scares of the 1970s and the wildly over-optimistic consensus views
in the 1960s and 1970s about the future of nuclear power).
More generally, although economists are not
qualified to comment in detail on the methods used by scientists
to model global climate, they are used to modelling complex situations
in which human intervention plays a major part, where the nature
of the system being modelled is poorly understood and where there
are difficult multivariate problems to be solved (that is, there
are many determining variables at work, possibly interacting,
and the separate influences of these determinants are very hard
to disentangle by statistical methods). Climate modelling, like
economic modelling, relies on highly simplified representations
of a very complex and only partially understood system which apparently
responds to human action but where feedback mechanisms are often
unclear. In view of the complexities of the system and the huge
uncertainties that remain, I would suggest the Committeewithout
going into details of the scienceprobes scientific witnesses
about how robust they believe their models to be, and asks for
information about the sensitivity analyses they have carried out
to test what differences in the results emerge if changes are
made in the structures of the models and in the assumptions made
about critical variables.
Two issues in particular are worth examining:
(i) how confident are the scientists
that they have identified a warming trend?
There has clearly been a succession of relatively
warm years in recent times. But world climate appears to fluctuate
considerably so that what has been observed could be merely a
cycle that will be reversed. The matter is of some importance.
If the warming tendency is likely to be reversed naturally, action
by governments to reverse it might do more harm than good, perhaps
bringing about excessive cooling of the kind feared by many scientists
only 30 or so years ago.
(ii) how much confidence do they have
in the correlation between global warming and the release of greenhouse
gases, which appears to be a particularly awkward problem in multivariate
analysis?
In other words, given the variability of world
climate and incomplete understanding of its determinants, with
what degree of confidence is it possible to identify the effects
of manmade influences such as greenhouse gas emissions?
3. THE PROJECTIONS
OF THE
IPCC
The International Panel on Climate Change (IPCC),
which is a subsidiary of the World Meteorological Organisation
and the United Nations Environment Programme, is the main source
of projections of climate change and its possible effects. The
IPCC has produced three massive reports and is in the process
of producing number four. Its projections appear to have been
broadly accepted by many governments and they are widely quoted.
The bases for its scenarios, which of course include economic
factors, need to be examined carefully: this Committee is particularly
well qualified to make such an examination.
The starting point for the latest IPCC report
is the Special Report on Emissions Scenarios (SRES) that projects
emissions almost a century ahead, to 2100, linking them to projections
of world output, world energy use and the carbon-intensity of
energy sources. Projections that far ahead should, of course,
be viewed with extreme scepticism. Even short and medium term
projections in the energy field have, in my experience, usually
been so far from the out-turn that they have been of little value.
But these very long term projections may be a useful aid to thought
if the scenarios used are internally consistent, if the principal
determinants are carefully considered and if outside observers
can see exactly what has been done and can play a role through
constructive criticism. Unfortunately, in the case of the IPCC
scenarios it is rather uncertain whether these conditions have
been met.
Two economists who have looked in detail at
the IPCC scenarios[8],
David Henderson and Ian Castles, have been very critical of them[9].
Their main single criticism concerns the economic growth projections
for developing regions. The scenarios assume the initial (1990)
gap in income per head between these regions and OECD countries
is substantially closed. Castles and Henderson argue that the
extent of this 1990 gap is greatly over-stated through the use
of market exchange rates, rather than purchasing power parities,
in deriving comparative figures for GDP per head in that year.
By assuming the closure of an over-stated gap, the scenarios yield
projections of GDP for developing regions that are improbably
high. The corresponding projections of emissions are also therefore
too high, according to Castles and Henderson. I would add, on
the subject of these rapid growth rates, that it is not clear
to me that the IPCC authors have considered whether they are feasible
in terms of the resourcesnatural, human and man-madethat
would have to be used to sustain them.
The IPCC's reaction to this critique seems to
have been defensive and to have tried to discredit Henderson and
Castles, describing them as spreading "disinformation"
and referring to them as "so-called independent commentators"[10].
This is clearly a matter on which the Committee should probe the
IPCC which, if it is confident of its methods, has nothing to
fear from the normal process of scientific debate[11].
I understand Professor Henderson is appearing before the Committee
and will therefore explain his critique of IPCC (only part of
which I have summarised), and that Dr Pachauri will appear to
explain the IPCC's position.
4. WILL CLIMATE
CHANGE REDUCE
WELFARE?
If it could be established that there is a climate
change trend that will continue into the future and that human
activities are primarily responsible, does it follow that in the
absence of government and international action world welfare will
be reduced? If that were an established fact, there would be a
prima facie case for centralised action. (The case would
not be fully made because, as explained in 5 below, the imperfections
of government and international action would also have to be taken
into account.)
The impact on world welfare of a global warming
trend is a difficult issue. It depends on the details of how the
warming occursfor example, whether minimum temperatures
increase at the same rate as maximum temperatures and whether
cold regions and warmer regions are affected similarly. From an
economic point of view, the distribution of gains and losses is
important. The chances are that, with a warming trend, there would
be considerable numbers of both winners and losers. Thus to decide
whether the world as a whole would be better or worse off becomes
a heroic task in which gains to winners would have to be offset
against losses to losers by using some weighting system (which
could only be subjective).
Furthermore, some analysts have argued that,
on balance, the likely increase in carbon dioxide emissions and,
more broadly, the likely extent of global warming, however caused,
would be beneficial. Robert Bradley, for example, after reviewing
the evidence, argues that ". . . the balance of evidence
leans more towards climate optimism than climate pessimism"[12].
Whether or not one subscribes to this optimistic view, there clearly
are many uncertainties about how increased greenhouse gas concentrations
(assuming they occur) will affect different people in different
parts of the world, as also about the impact of global warming.
There is also the question of the extent to which people in different
areas might be able to adapt to climate change without serious
costs. I would suggest that the Committee questions witnesses
about what distribution of losses and gains from climate change
they expect, how they would assess the net effect and what is
the capacity for adaptation.
5. IS COLLECTIVE
ACTION REQUIRED
AND, IF
IT IS,
WHAT SHOULD
IT BE?
In terms of standard economic theory, the case
for collective action to combat climate change may appear to be
clear. The standard case is that individuals and organisations
that burn fossil fuels have little incentive to reduce the ensuing
emissions of carbon dioxide because they bear merely the private
costs of their actions (the price of the fuel and associated costs):
these private costs are less than the full social costs of those
actions, including the adverse impact on world climate. Hence
the costs they do not bear ("external costs") should
be incorporated, directly or indirectly, by governments and international
institutions, thus applying a price to use of the environment.
A solution that can often be applied to environmental problemsto
allocate and enforce property rights so that the holders of those
rights will defend them against pollutersis, it is argued,
inapplicable in this case because of the difficulty of allocating
property rights to global assets such as the earth`s atmosphere.
So, to avoid over-use of the atmosphere as a sink for wastes,
it should be priced.
However the standard argument, as is often the
case, seems to me to assume more scientific knowledge than actually
exists. Without further evidence it appears uncertain whether
a warming trend has been established; if there is such a trend
its future course and the contribution to it of carbon dioxide
and other greenhouse gases seem very unclear; and there are doubts,
virtually impossible to resolve, about whether costs to losers
will in aggregate exceed benefits to gainers. Thus, estimating
the appropriate price is virtually impossible.
Moreover, there are two issues I have not so
far discussed. The first is what the costs might be of action
to combat climate change. "Costs" in this case mean
not only the direct costs to consumers and taxpayers of subsidies,
taxes, administrative controls and other devices designed to avoid
climate change and/or to modify its effects, substantial though
those direct costs might be[13].
Such actions will inevitably affect choices made by producers
and consumers, causing economic distortions, and will have unintended
consequences that will increase the full opportunity costs of
government actions[14].
The Committee will no doubt want to enquire into the likely size
of these costs.
The second matter is that we must expect any
national government or international action to be flawed because
governments, as well as markets, are "imperfect". Indeed,
there are reasons of principle to doubt whether governments in
representative political systems have a long enough view to be
efficient and effective protectors of the environment. They are
generally reluctant to impose costs on voters for actions that
will produce any benefits only in the very long run during the
administrations of far distant governments.
Experience tells us that actions by governments
and international agencies are likely to be influenced by all
manner of objectives as well as concern for the environment and
that they have unintended consequences. Thus it is uncertain whether,
even in the case that collective action is justified and does
not seem unduly costly, it will make matters better rather than
worse.
6. POLICIES TO
COPE WITH
THE UNCERTAINTIES
ABOUT CLIMATE
CHANGE
Subject to the evidence the Committee receives,
it seems to me that a possible policy approach might be as follows.
The intention would be to avoid free use of the global environment
but to minimise the potential for government failure.
Probably the best argument that can at present
be mustered in favour of collective action to combat apparent
climate change is on insurance lines. This case admits current
ignorance, accepting that the future extent of climate change
and its consequences are inherently unknowable, but acknowledges
that, if significant change were to occur, the economic and social
effects might be severe. Thus, the argument proceeds, governments
should insure their citizens against these possible consequences.
The difficulties of effecting such insurance efficiently are obvious:
in our present state of knowledge the consequences and their probabilities
of occurrence are unclear and the attitude of "society"
towards risk is unknown. Thus only arbitrary calculations of the
premium it would be worth paying are possible.
However there is a case, in terms of insurance,
for employing a general economic instrument to deal with carbon
emissionsa tax on carbon or better an emissions trading
scheme (as instituted by the EU in January 2005). A trading scheme
requires the initial setting of the aggregate amount of the permitted
emissions and their allocation among emitters (preferably by auction
to minimise government failure). Subsequent trading would then
"discover" a price for carbon and allow a decentralised
response to the emissions problem. The quantity of emissions permitted
could be adjusted over time, with governments selling more permits
or buying them back. "Conservationists" and others could
also purchase permits, if they wished.
This kind of trading scheme is likely to be
a more efficient way of reducing carbon emissions than the strategy
of "picking winners" (such as renewables) that has been
resurrected by the British government in its 2003 energy White
Paper. In my view, it would also represent a more considered,
cheaper and flexible response to an issue which may or may not
turn out to be a serious problem than the drastic and costly programmes
of centralised action that the more alarmist observers, like doomsters
of earlier times, are urging should be adopted in the immediate
future.
5 January 2005
1 Department of Trade and Industry, Our Energy
Future: Creating a Low Carbon Economy, Cm 5761, 2003. Back
2
Ibid. para 1.10. Comments on the size of the programme
and its unintended consequences are in Eileen Marshall, "Energy
Regulation and Competition after the White Paper", in Colin
Robinson (ed), Governments, Competition and Utility Regulation,
Edward Elgar, forthcoming, 2005. Back
3
For instance, "Gas, Electricity and the Energy Review",
in Colin Robinson (ed.) Successes and Failures in Regulating
and Deregulating Utilities, Edward Elgar, 2004. Back
4
Going back at least to the mid-nineteenth century. See, for example,
W S Jevons, The Coal Question, 1865, reprinted Augustus
M Kelley, 1965. Back
5
One of the forerunners of these predictions was D L Meadows et
al, The Limits to Growth, Earth Island, 1972 that forecast
shortages of most raw materials by the end of the twentieth century. Back
6
Colin Robinson, The Technology of Forecasting and the Forecasting
of Technology, Surrey Papers in Economics, 1972, pp 8-9. Back
7
Dennis Gabor, Inventing the Future, Secker and Warburg,
1963. Back
8
The Special Report on Emissions Scenarios (SRES) is prepared
for the IPCC's Working Group III. Back
9
See, for example, Ian Castles and David Henderson, "Economics,
Emissions Scenarios and the Work of the IPCC", Energy
and Environment, Vol 14, No. 4, 2003. Back
10
IPCC Press Release, Milan, December 2003, now posted on the Panel's
website. Back
11
An IPCC response in the literature is Nebojsa Nakicenovic et
al, "IPCC SRES Revisited: A Response", Energy and
Environment, Vol 14, Nos 2 and 3, 2003, but it does not deal
satisfactorily with the main points made by Castle and Henderson. Back
12
Robert L.Bradley Jr, Climate Alarmism Reconsidered, Institute
of Economic Affairs, Hobart Paper 146, 2003, page 71. Back
13
The UK's 2003 White Paper, Cm 5761, op cit puts the annual
costs of its renewable energy programme at over £1 billion
which exceeds 10 per cent of the wholesale value of electricity. Back
14
Marshall, op cit. Back
|