Examination of Witnesses (Questions 1-19)
Professor Colin Robinson
11 JANUARY 2005
Q1Chairman: Thank you very much for coming,
Professor Colin Robinson. The Committee has got your paper, for
which we thank you very much, and we welcome you to the Committee.
We have also got your biographical details for those who do not
know you. We are delighted that you were able to come and talk
to us. You are our first witness in this new study that we have
started and we have got a number of questions which you know about.
I am told that I have to remind you that we need to speak slowly
and clearly so that the machines and recorders can hear but you
would probably know that anyway. Do you want to make any sort
of remark to start off with? It is absolutely up to you.
Professor Robinson: Chairman, thank you very
much for asking me. Would it be useful if I made a few summary
remarks at the beginning, and there is one thing I wanted to amplify
anyway, if I may?
Q2Chairman: Yes, please do.
Professor Robinson: I thought I would try to
give an overview of what I have tried to say in this brief paper.
The first point is that the prospect of severe climate change
is now very influential with policy makers in all sorts of fields
but perhaps particularly in energy policy, which is the area in
which I am particularly interested, and if one looks at the most
recent UK White Paper on Energy Policy from February 2003, you
can see that the British Government is aiming for a quite drastic
reduction in carbon dioxide emissions of about 60 per cent by
2050. This is really a very drastic change, based on recommendations
from the Royal Commission on Environmental Pollution. I think
one needs to be critical of these kinds of predictions, first
of all, because, particularly in the energy field in the past,
we have been quite used to alarmist predictions. These have often
been about the over-rapid depletion of energy resources, running
out, this kind of thing, but in this case it is an alarmist prediction
of a somewhat different sort, so it seems to me that is wise to
look at these predictions rather critically. First of all, one
has got to look at the science on which I am obviously not qualified
to comment except to say that economists do have experience of
trying to build models of very complex systems which we do not
understand very well, and this is certainly true of the world's
climate. It does seem to be a very complex system which is not
well understood and yet people try to pick out the effects on
this of human intervention, which is clearly a very difficult
thing to do, so I think the scientists need to be queried about
this, and in particular on two things. First of all, whether this
warming effect on the world's climate, which does now seem to
be established, is really a trend which can be expected to continue
or whether this is merely a kind of cycle in which we can expect
warming to be followed by cooling, and clearly that is a very
important issue for policy. The second issue for scientists is
how confident they really can be about the correlation between
warming and emissions of greenhouse gases. Another issue on which
I commented briefly is these scenarios that have been prepared
by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change which are the
figures that people usually quote when they talk about the warming
of the earth, and people quote figures of a 1.5 to 6 per cent
increase in degrees centigrade over the next 100 years or so.
In the paper I raise some questions about this. I pointed to some
of the criticisms which have been made of this, in particular
by Professor Henderson and Ian Castles who have suggested that
the rates of economic growth embodied in these scenarios are probably
very much on the high side and I think certainly that is one thing
which the Committee might wish to look at, whether it is so that
these are very much on the high side. However, I would like to
raise one other issue about these IPCC scenarios which is not
so much about whether they have been well done but about whether
this kind of exercise has any value at all. They are, after all,
trying to paint these scenarios for about 100 years ahead. If
one merely thinks back and says what would have happened if people
in the early 20th century had taken a base year of 1890 and put
out scenarios for the year 2000, would they actually have produced
anything which was of any value to anybody in solving any problem
that came up in the 21st century? I think one really has to be
doubtful about the value of these long-term scenarios. It seems
virtuous to take a long view but if you cannot see anything useful
I am not sure that is really so. I think it is worth thinking
about whether it is really helpful to use these kinds of scenarios
on which this whole global warming industry seems to have grown
up. It seems to me it is actually quite difficult to disturb the
consensus on the warming of the earth's atmosphere because lots
of people believe in it for various reasons. Lots of people have
an interest in maintaining this idea now and so, as sometimes
happens with established hypotheses like these, it is very difficult
to disturb it. Just a couple more points, if I may, Chairman,
before I finish. From an economic point of view the question which
is worth asking is whether, if warming of the atmosphere is taking
place, it is quite clear that that will be detrimental to world
welfare. There are some scientists who argue that increased CO2
concentrations and increased warming might actually be beneficial.
I think it is worth questioning that and whether that is so or
not. It does seem that there are going to be winners and losers
from the warming trend, and economists tend to shy away from situations
where you have to compare gains to some people against losses
to others. It is a very difficult thing to do and it is not absolutely
clear that there is going to be a net reduction in welfare from
the warming tendency. So the argument I have ended up with is
there is a danger of accepting a consensus which for all sorts
of reasons has developed and which is rather difficult to disturb.
There is a danger, I think, of exaggerated and over-hasty action
in the face of this consensus. I would put the UK Energy Policy
White Paper in this category of exaggerated, quite costly and
over-hasty action. It seems to me that if one is worried about
the problem of warming it is best dealt with not by centralised
action by governments and international institutions in the accepted
sense of trying to pick winners among technologies and fuels;
it is better to rely, as far as one possibly can, on markets which
will adjust as we go along, although in this case they are probably
going to need to be reinforced by some kind of emissions trading
scheme (which has already started in the EU) which would help
us to work out the answers to this difficult problem as we go
along. So that is my quick summary, Chairman.
Q3Chairman: Thank you very much. In some ways
you have answered part of the first question I was going to ask
you but let me just put it to you this way: if you are, as you
clearly are, critical of the way the consensus has emerged and
you have some doubts, could you perhaps give us a view as to why
you think it has happened this way? Why do you think the international
scientific consensus has emerged in this way? Presumably, you
have some questions about whether it makes reasonable assumptions
about economic growth? Those are the two points that I wanted
to pursue further.
Professor Robinson: If you look back at the
way consensuses have formed in the past of this rather alarmist
variety, they appear because when we look ahead we tend to see
problems that at present do not have solutions and consequently
there is a tendency to become alarmed because you cannot see the
solutions to these problems. In the memorandum I put in I quoted
from somebody who pointed out that the problems of 50 years hence
do not have to be dealt with by today's technology; they will
be dealt with by the technology we will have in 30 years' time,
or whatever. I think to some extent it is a simple matter. It
is very easy to become alarmed about almost anything in the future
because you cannot see how these kinds of problems that appear
to be emerging are going to be solved. Thinking about these things
is clearly the way in which they do get solved. On the other hand,
if you become too alarmist about it, you can become precipitated
into this very costly centralised action to solve problems which
would actually have been solved anyway through the normal processes
of human ingenuity. I think that is probably the reason why one
gets these alarmist ideas. On the issue of economic growth, I
think the simple point isand this goes back to what I was
saying a moment agoif you are looking at scenarios 100
years ahead I do not think it is possible to say anything reasonable
about economic growth because we have no idea what will happen
over this period. I am not sure that this scenario approach or
any kind of projection over such a long period has any real value
simply because we are in such ignorance about what is likely to
happen in this period.
Q4Chairman: Speaking as a complete layman on
this subject, if it is difficult to see too far into the future
most people tend to put their heads under the blankets and do
nothing. You argue that it is very difficult to see what is going
to happen in 50 or 100 years' time and yet you have an emerging
consensus which you are challenging which is, by your view, alarmist.
That is contrary to what I would have thought was normal human
nature, that if they cannot understand it they will soon forget
about it. However, they seem to have taken a totally different
view. Can you explain that?
Professor Robinson: I think an industry grows
up around these things as it has done with the global warming
consensus in that many people gain their employment through working
on answers to these supposed problems. Academics obtain research
grants from finding problems. I am not saying there is not a problem
but there is quite a lot of self-interest in these things. May
I take something totally different like the consensus that formed
40 or more years ago that nuclear power was the fuel of the future,
the "too cheap to meter" type of idea that grew up then.
That was very powerful and was unchallenged for many years because
the scientific community benefited hugely from the idea that nuclear
power was going to be the fuel of the future and it took all kinds
of big changes before people changed their view about nuclear
power. These consensuses once they are formed are difficult to
dislodge.
Q5Lord Layard: I wanted to ask about your remark
about the trend being possibly a cycle. Perhaps I could ask three
questions about the science. The first is, do you accept that
there has been a big increase in the density of greenhouse gases
caused by human action? Secondly, do you think the science predicts
that such a change in density would lead to an increase in global
temperature, other things being equal? Thirdly, if the answer
to both those questions is yes, is it not reasonable to think
that the change in temperature which has been observed is in fact
the result of the changes in greenhouse gases caused by human
action? I think I would put it to you a bit like this, is it not
rather similar to how one might have thought about smoking 50
years ago? We were trying to explain the increase in lung cancer.
There had been a big increase in smoking, there was microeconomic
evidence that smoking would be likely to increase lung cancer,
and if you see an increase in cancer and you see an increase in
smoking you put the two together. Is that not a reasonable way
for people to look at this?
Professor Robinson: Obviously I am not qualified
to speak on the science but clearly there has been an increase
in greenhouse gas concentrations and clearly there has been a
period in which the world for a number of years has been warmer
than in recent times. What I am not clear about is to what extent
it has been established that the greenhouse gases are responsible,
because as I understand itand this is something scientists
need to be quizzed onif you take these models which look
forward they do not actually predict what has happened in the
past very well. The amount of warming does not appear to be very
closely correlated with the greenhouse gas emissions and, consequently,
without being qualified to speak about the science, I feel suspicious
about this correlation, and I think it is something on which the
Committee could very usefully, if I might say so, question the
scientists about: the extent to which they feel they have isolated
the warming effects of these emissions, given all the other complicated
things that are going on in the climate. I absolutely agree about
smoking but I think it is more complicated than smoking just because
of all the complications of climate. It is a very difficult, multi-variable
problem, I think.
Q6Lord Sheldon: But is it not clear that if
you ignore long-term forecasts because of their uncertainty you
will need to make sure that you have got short-term solutions?
It is alright to say, "Look here, one is very unsure,"
but you need to have immediate effects that you can bring into
play and without that you are faced with two lots of uncertainty,
whereas you can reduce them to one if you can concentrate on the
short-term forecasts which may be the solution to deal with these
long-term uncertainties. What guarantee can we have that we have
got some shorter-term solutions to deal with them?
Professor Robinson: I think that historically
these kinds of problems have been dealt with through decentralised
types of processes and the exercise of human ingenuity or through
markets, depending on how you like to put it. The problem with
not just effects on the environment but effects on the global
atmosphere is that in classical economic terms there is a market
imperfection and the global atmosphere is not priced and you have
to do something about it to make sure markets will work better
than they otherwise would. I used to be a forecaster but I must
admit that as time has gone on I have more and more gone off forecasting.
I think what you should do is to try to avoid reliance on any
kind of long-term forecast because it is likely to be so wildly
inaccurate that you run the risk of doing precisely the opposite
of what you really ought to be doing. I would rely upon adjusting
as you go along rather than trying to make a decision now about
what the situation might be like at the end of the 21st century.
Q7Lord Skidelsky: I know you have in your paper
expressed quite a lot of scepticism about the IPCC emissions scenarios
on various grounds. Of course, these are story lines rather than
predictions and would not an alternative approach be to develop
explicit probability distributions for key outcomes? Would not
that enable one to get a better handle on the problem? That is
really the first question I would like to ask. Then I wonder what
you would say in generaland I think we have already touched
on thisabout the economic forecasts on which these projections
are based?
Professor Robinson: On the question of probability
distributions, my experience of scenarios arises because once
upon a time I used to work in the oil industry and the oil industry
of course has used scenarios for a long time. People who use scenarios
explicitly avoid the use of any kind of probability on the grounds
that you need to put forward all of these pictures of the future,
each one of which is internally consistent, and present them and
avoid making a judgment about one being more likely than the other.
That is the way it is done. In that sense I think the IPCC are
in line with the received wisdom about scenarios. The problem
about applying probabilities, particularly with something so far
ahead, is it is so difficult to know how you would do it and how
you would attach any kind of subjective probability to any of
these forecasts of economic growth or emissions or whatever. I
think it is a very difficult thing to do and I think that is maybe
another reason for avoiding these kinds of long-term forecasts
if you can. On the economic forecasts themselves, since I wrote
that memorandum I have had a further, more detailed look at the
SRES scenarios and it is quite difficult to know to what extent
the results are actually influenced by the economic forecasts.
I noticed somebody who wrote a critical paper about it who said
that it was not clear how the authors got from their driving forces
to their results, and I also think it is actually very unclear
when you begin to look at them. So I do not know how important
the economic forecasts are but I think that David Henderson and
Ian Castles have made a very important point about these forecasts,
which is they seem to start off with an exaggerated gap between
the rich countries and the poor countries and then, for reasons
that are not very clear to anybody, they assume the gap almost
disappears over the course of 100 years or so. Not surprisingly,
therefore, the rates of economic growth they come up with for
the developing world are really quite rapid compared to what has
happened in the past, so I think one has got to be suspicious
about them on those grounds. Clearly, you cannot rule them out,
but there does not seem to be any backing for these apart from
the idea that it would be nice if we had convergence.
Q8Lord Skidelsky: Can I ask a supplementary
on exactly that point. In your paper, on page 6, you go through
some of the Castles/Henderson arguments and you say, "I would
add, on the subject of these rapid growth rates, that it is not
clear to me that the IPCC authors have considered whether they
are feasible in terms of the resourcesnatural, human and
man-madethat would have to be used to sustain them."
Is that a comment on the capacity of governments to engineer these
kinds of growth rates, quite apart from disagreement about the
income in the base year?
Professor Robinson: Perhaps my comment is really
not very clear there. I think what I was trying to say was it
is difficult to see what the back-up for these forecasts is. They
do not seem to have attempted to justify them, except in terms
of convergence, and it is not clear why they think there is going
to be convergence. They do not seem to have attempted to look
at whether it is feasible to grow this rapidly and what the implications
would be, so it is really reinforcing the Castles/Henderson point
that it is uncertain why they are assuming this convergence.
Q9Lord Macdonald of Tradeston: Just to follow
on, Professor Robinson, on this question of the processes of IPCC.
Obviously in a technical sense the way the chapters are written
and are peer reviewed might be questioned, but there is obviously
something stronger behind the criticism by Henderson and Castles
and indeed the way you yourself talk about the defensive reaction,
the attempt to discredit and the spread of misinformation, which
raises the question of whether this process is then being influenced
by political factors? Is it simply that a consensus has built
up behind this or can you see evidence of more political intervention
or other interests at work? If the objectivity is being skewed
by the politics, is there a way in which you think that this Committee
or the British Government might be challenging and strengthening
the processes involved by the IPCC?
Professor Robinson: I think that once some kind
of consensus has been formed people do become defensive about
it and want to keep the consensus. Whether it is political effects
I am not quite sure. I think, as I indicated, there is an industry
around this now, with all sorts of people involved in this, and
it has I suppose become self-generating, self-perpetuating, and
maybe there is a case for governments becoming a bit more involved.
I think David Henderson, for instance, has argued that finance
ministries ought to become more involved in this and have a look
at things like these economic growth assumptions. If there is
going to be a bill for this it is going to be footed by various
governments and their taxpayers and therefore it would seem reasonable
to have the finance ministries look much more questioningly at
the kind of assumptions that have been made by the IPCC and in
particular these economic growth assumptions.
Q10Lord Macdonald of Tradeston: Looking at the
lead authors, for instance, and the way they have been selected,
is there any suggestion that there might be a pattern behind their
selection or that they are financed in ways that might influence
the outcome of the judgements made by the IPCC? Where do you think
the rigour should be applied in looking at this from our perspective?
Professor Robinson: I certainly would not make
any suggestion that there has been any bias in selection but I
think the review process almost seems to have been internalised.
The IPCC claims constantly that everything is peer reviewed and
there are all these people writing these things and looking at
them and so on. But when you look at the results you would not
really have thought that, so there does not seem to be any outside
influence entering into these forecasts and that is why it seems
it would be useful to have checks from outside economists, particularly
from economists in areas like the British Treasury, on what has
been going on.
Q11Lord Vallance of Tummel: Perhaps we can follow
up a little on the UK's role. Professor Robinson, what do you
see as the current UK role in the IPCC process, and could it be
improved to produce a more robust analysis and, if so, how would
you set about it?
Professor Robinson: Obviously, individual people
have had a role because there are British people among those who
do the scenarios and review them. I do not think, as I understand
it, that the British Government has had much of a role in the
preparation of these very influential scenarios nor in the more
general IPCC processes. As I have indicated, I think it has become
a bit of an industry and become self-generating and it does really
need to be looked at rather more fundamentally than has been done
in the past.
Q12Lord Vallance of Tummel: How would you set
about doing that if you were advising?
Professor Robinson: First of all, my own view
is that this whole approach of trying to write very long-term
scenarios is misguided, so I would not do that. But if you are
going to do that, you really do need to have outside checks on
what is being done for those who are going to be paying the bill.
That is why we need some input from government departments and
in particular from finance ministries. My preference would be
to get away from all this speculation about the very long-term
future, which I suspect is not very helpful, to try to set up
a system that would help us to adapt as we go along. That means
that what you do is you try to use markets as far as possible
and where they are not working very well you try to reinforce
them.
Q13Lord Vallance of Tummel: Do you think that
there might be a role for some institution within the UK then
to set up independently and challenge this approach and take a
different view altogether, in which case what sort of institution
could do it? At the moment what we are talking about is government
departments. Is there anything beyond that?
Professor Robinson: Of course individual academics
have already challenged it but it looks to me as if it is bouncing
off rather and it probably needs greater weight to be applied,
and that is why I suspect that some criticism from government
departments might have more effect.
Q14Lord Elder: I was going to ask about the
view you have on the way governments take decisions on climate
change issues but I think we have rather got the flavour of some
of your thoughts on that, although I must say it is an interesting
and new concept that governments should be being criticised for
taking too long term a view, because that is not the usual criticism
for governments! I understand the logic of your case on this but
it seems to be that it is at least possible that the problems
that future governments will be facing will be ones which, should
your thinking be misguided, will have become so complex and so
difficult that it will be too late to come to some sort of solution.
To use a parallel with the point Lord Layard made, I know from
experience, if you say to a doctor you have got a slight problem
with your skin but it is alright you wear a hat and put on sun
tan lotion, he will say that is all very good and that he is encouraged
by that but the problem arose 40 years ago and it is far too late
to do anything about it. It seems to me that by following this
approach you are suggesting and going on in the hope that in 30,
50 or 70 years' time there will be new technology to deal with
it and that something will turn up. But we might reach a position
where governments will be faced with the awful prospect of having
to admit that there is a huge problem and that it is far too late
to do anything about it. I would be grateful for your comments
on that please.
Professor Robinson: I agree with you it is odd
to criticise governments for taking too long term a view, and
I have often been critical of governments for not looking far
enough ahead, but the problem is looking this far ahead there
is not anything you can see. I am not sure that looking a long
time ahead is particularly virtuous. I think the point about leaving
it too late is a very interesting one and that is the reason that
I have suggested that if you are concerned about warming of the
earth that the way to approach this is to say let's try to take
out some insurance so that, even though we do not know what is
going to happen, if things do go wrong that we have taken some
action in time. That is why I have suggested that the best approach
to this is to reinforce the normal operation of markets by some
kind of scheme that will help to offset the possible effects of
human action on the environment. This is where these kinds of
schemes like emissions trading schemes can come in. There are
problems with these too and I certainly know that, but nevertheless
they do give you an opportunity to avoid making big bang decisions
now and to make your decisions over a period of time during which
you adjust.
Q15Lord Skidelsky: How much effect are the new
deposits going to have on climate change in the next 100 years
as opposed to the effects that the old deposits are having? I
know this is probably a scientific question more than anything
else but what is the expected ratio of new deposits of CO2 emissions
which are envisaged by these scenarios to existing deposits which
have been accumulating over, I do not know, the last 100 or 200
or 300 years of polluting activity? Is there any good information
about that, because it seems to me rather important in judging
what we could actually do to slow down climate change?
Professor Robinson: Insofar as it is carbon
dioxide concentrations, as I understand it, and I think this probably
is a question for scientists, the consensus view among scientists
is that you should avoid concentrations of CO2 in the atmosphere
and you should not allow them to go above 550 parts per million,
which is twice the pre-industrial level. We are some way off that
at the moment. I think that is the scientific consensus. I think
it probably is an interesting question for climate scientistswhat
we can do and to what extent we are already committed. We obviously
are committed already from what has happened in recent years to
a substantial increase in concentrations in the atmosphere.
Q16Lord Lawson of Blaby: Professor Robinson,
you mentioned the Government's White Paper UK National Priorities
in the Energy Strategy. In the climate change section of that,
the first page presents in a very prominent position a graph which
is used a great deal to demonstrate that there is likely to be
warming, which shows from the year 1000 AD to the present, and
indeed projections into the future, that the world temperature
remained pretty well static until about the early 20th century
when it started to rise, and this is projected to continue. You
said, quite rightly, that one of your concerns was that the rise
that there has been over the past 100 years may be something that
should be projected in the future or it may be a cyclical phenomenon.
If you look at this graph it does not look like a cyclical phenomenon.
Have you made any studies of the reliability of this particular
graph, which has had a very, very prominent place not merely in
the Government's White Paper but in most of the climate change
literature?
Professor Robinson: I think a large part of
the graph to which you are referring is a projection and consequently
it would not be possible to spot any kind of cyclical effect because
it is a projection that shoots up.
Lord Lawson of Blaby: Yes, from the year
2000 to 2100 you are absolutely right, it is a projection; but
from the year 1000, shortly before the Battle of Hastings, to
the present day, whatever else it is, that is clearly not a projection.
Q17Chairman: Have you got a copy?
Professor Robinson: Yes, thank you.
Q18Lord Lawson of Blaby: Are you aware that
this, which has had a very profound influence on thinking, is
explicitly stated in the Government's White Paper to be based
on proxy data, whatever proxy data may be, because there are no
instrumental observations, they did not begin until the late 19th
century, and that for these proxy data, which it says in small
writing at the bottom, that the IPCC relies entirely on a study
by a Professor Mann in 1998 and this has subsequently been examined
and it was found that that Mr Mann got it all wrong in a rather
fundamental way. Professor McKitrick, for example, has gone into
this in great detail and so I believe have others. Is this something
you have studied?
Professor Robinson: I have not studied in any
detail this question about whether we are in a trend or in a cycle
but if you simply cover the projection part at the end of that
graph with your hand you can see (it is not all that clear) what
is happening. I am merely raising the question because I think
it is an important issue because if we were in the warming phase
going to a cooling phase, and the Government takes action on the
assumption it is warming, then we are doing precisely the wrong
thing presumably. So it is quite an important issue and I was
really raising it as a question that might be addressed to the
scientistswhat confidence they have that this is a genuine
trend.
Q19Lord Lawson of Blaby: Yes, I think that this
is nevertheless something which would be useful if we knew a little
bit more about how these proxy data were derived since some people
are placing a great deal importance on this straight line based
on these so-called proxy data. They may be absolutely right, they
may be wrong, but I think we need to know something about it.
You referred earlier to the point that the IPCC's fundamental
assumption of world growth does not relate to the 10 variations
lowest and highest but that all their estimates are based on the
assumption that the developing world will by the end of this century
have the same national income per head as the developed world,
even allowing for the growth in the developed world. In other
words, there will be complete catch-up by 2100, which is wonderful.
It means that the problem of global poverty has been solved. It
is the most wonderful assumption I have ever heard. Do you know
what evidence there is for this assumption?
Professor Robinson: Well, I do not think there
is any. I think to be precise what they say is that the present
ratio of GDP per head in the developed world to the developing
is about 16:1 and it is going to go down to somewhere between
1.5:1 to 3:1. It is very substantial convergence and there does
not seem to be any evidence or any back-up for this assumption.
I think at one point they do talk about equity or equitable distribution
of income but there seems to be almost some kind of value judgment
built into this that this is what one might hope will happen.
It does not seem to me to be in the category of an objective expectation
of what might happen but more of a kind of hope. All these scenarios
are based upon this idea.
Lord Lawson of Blaby: You are an economist
and in the economics tradeI hesitate to call it a professionthere
is a considerable difference of opinion as to whether when you
are making these projections you should use market exchange rates
or purchasing power parity, and of course there is no dispute
that the gap at the present time between the developing and the
developed world in terms of market exchange rate is much greater
than it is in purchasing power parity. I remember, if I may, Professor
Bauer, who was a Member of this House, pointing out to me that
if you tookand I hope this will not be considered in bad
taste, it is meant to be a demonstration
Chairman: We will tell you that after.
|