Select Committee on Economic Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 275 - 279)

TUESDAY 17 OCTOBER 2006

THE LORD RENWICK OF CLIFTON

  Q275  Chairman: We welcome somebody from the home team, if you like. We are delighted that you are able to come along and help us with the inquiry. In fact, some of us read I will not say every word you wrote all those years ago but certainly we read parts of it, right at the very beginning of this inquiry, and we are very grateful to you for coming along. You are an old hand at this, but I am told I have to say to everybody, please speak up clearly so we get a proper record. We have got a number of questions which you know about. Is there anything you want to say right at the beginning?

  Lord Renwick of Clifton: No. Thank you very much for the opportunity to participate in this; it is a fascinating subject.

  Q276  Chairman: If I may start off, I just wondered what you saw as the most important developments in sanctions policy and its implementation since the publication of your book in 1981 on the subject. Has policy-making in this area improved generally, have we learned the appropriate lessons from the past, or is there perhaps a tendency to repeat the old mistakes?

  Lord Renwick of Clifton: I would like to talk for a few moments about South Africa, which is the sort of experience where I had a very direct line of sight. I think the main lesson is a rather unpalatable one, that sanctions are most successful when they are applied against a rational adversary, so they were largely ineffective in changing the behaviour of the South African regime under P W Botha. When F W de Klerk took over, he made a sustained effort to reverse South Africa's isolation; ironically, the demands for the continuance, and even intensification, of sanctions continued even when he had set out on that course. One or two quick observations on which sanctions "worked best" against South Africa and which did not, at least, in my estimation. One of the most effective sanctions was the arms embargo. As the South Africans found themselves confronting Cuban and Russian forces in Angola, with sophisticated military aircraft, missiles and more capable tanks than theirs, their inability to access state of the art western military equipment had a potentially serious effect for them. With a very limited number of suppliers, this kind of embargo is easier to enforce than most others, despite some leakages. The other most effective measures were sanctions imposed by the financial markets, following the decision by Chase and other banks not to roll over South Africa's loans in 1995 and thereafter. This caused the Governor of the Reserve Bank and some other influential figures to point out that South Africa could not hope to create the employment opportunities needed to meet the needs of a rapidly-growing population on the basis of a continuing capital outflow. That message was received and understood by de Klerk but not by his predecessors. Another relatively effective sanction was the sports boycott; even though, I must confess, I did not like it myself, being a sports lover, because it was targeted directly at the white population and it did bring home to them the extent of their isolation. I recall persuading Nelson Mandela that, to help de Klerk win the white referendum in support of the movement towards majority rule, he, Mandela, needed to advocate lifting the sports boycott, which he did. The most undesirable sanctions were those which targeted, for instance, South Africa's agricultural exports, a measure ardently supported by their southern hemisphere competitors and which succeeded in putting out of work a considerable number of black farm workers. I noted with interest, the other day, Mr Cameron's assertion that we were wrong not to support sanctions against South Africa, as we did participate, in fact, in a lot of sanctions. What is true is that at the Kuala Lumpur Commonwealth Conference, as I recall and Lord Powell will recall even better, Margaret Thatcher was alone in opposing further sanctions against South Africa at a time when de Klerk had already released most of the ANC leaders, was getting ready to release Mandela and to terminate South Africa's nuclear programme. I am trying to make the point that a serious sanctions policy has to be able to be graduated, to be intensified or relaxed according to the target country's behaviour. In the case of Rhodesia, for instance, we found it quite difficult to get sanctions lifted even when we had taken over responsibility for the running of the country. I have to say that I think South Africa and de Klerk were an exceptional case. We were very fortunate with him, because, in relation to sanctions generally, there is plenty of other evidence to show that a sufficiently ruthless regime can pass on the economic effects of sanctions to the civilian population while largely immunising itself from them and blaming foreign adversaries for their misery. That certainly was the case in Iraq under Saddam Hussein and it has been the case in Zimbabwe under Mugabe. The relatively feeble sanctions against that regime, in Zimbabwe, and their obvious lack of effect have been demoralising for the opposition there and we are not sending a clear enough signal to Mugabe's potential successors. Those sanctions, despite the best efforts of colleagues behind me in the European Commission, have been honoured more in the breach than in the observance; a travel ban, for instance, was followed by the egregious example of President Chirac inviting Mugabe to attend the Summit of African Leaders in Paris, and so on. It is a case of what not to do. Except in that case, I do feel that policy-making in this area has improved in two important respects. Firstly, and most important, we no longer make such ambitious claims for sanctions policies. We no longer claim that, of themselves, they are likely to solve or cure the problem. We are no longer likely to say, as Harold Wilson did, that the Rhodesian problem will be solved in weeks rather than months. Secondly, we are paying more attention to the target country, and Lord Lamont is absolutely right to say that targeted sanctions are difficult to enforce and quite often are relatively ineffective. There is a case, nevertheless, for targeting sanctions on nuclear programmes and arms embargoes and the regimes, to the extent we can, rather than going in for catch-all sanction solutions. There is a continuing problem; these measures often are and sometimes have to be accompanied by aid programmes to the very same countries, and those aid programmes typically have the unintended effect of reinforcing the regime. That certainly was the catastrophic effect of the `oil for food' programme in Iraq, which was administered horrendously; also, it has been the effect of aid programmes in Zimbabwe, where the disbursement of aid is controlled, to a large extent, by the regime. I am not arguing that we should not do it but we should understand that it has the practical effect of assisting the regime.

  Q277  Lord Lawson of Blaby: There are so many questions arising from that. First, however, may I bring you back to the specific question of your book and ask whether there are any other ways in which you would modify it, the conclusions you reached in your book? For example, your book did not say very much, as I recall it, about targeted sanctions, which were not very involved at that time. You did say, however, for example, minor or petty sanctions are virtually certain to produce a reverse political effect without exerting any real pressure. Would you say that, very often, targeted sanctions can come into that category?

  Lord Renwick of Clifton: Yes, they can, in some cases.

  Q278  Lord Lawson of Blaby: As I understand it, what you were advocating in what you have just said to us was that sanctions which deny military material are really much more what we should be thinking about rather than economic sanctions. I will leave out sporting sanctions. You were absolutely right about sporting sanctions in South Africa but I do not think sporting sanctions against Iran are going to have much effect. But tell me if I am wrong. Could you reply to that perhaps, and also to the original question which I asked a moment ago?

  Lord Renwick of Clifton: Certainly. Being summoned before this Committee, I reread at least the Conclusions of the book. I would not actually change them but certainly, I think, one should try to refine them. On targeted sanctions, you are absolutely right that I think `slap on the wrist' sanctions do more harm than good. If sanctions are to be imposed at all they need to be made to hurt, in some measure, and that can be done with asset freezes if they are really enforced, it can be done with regime travel bans if they are really enforced, otherwise they appear just derisory to both the recipients and to those who are trying to oppose the people we are trying to penalise. I think targeted sanctions, as I have said, for sure, arms embargoes properly enforced, especially if the recipient country, the target country, has relatively sophisticated military means. It is very difficult to stop the supply of rifles or mines or hand-grenades, but certainly you can stop the supply of very sophisticated strike aircraft, and so forth, missiles, etc. Sanctions targeted on nuclear materials and nuclear equipment, again, we have seen lots and lots of leakages; nevertheless, it can be made more difficult for countries to acquire more of that sort of material, which is very much the issue with North Korea and Iran. At the end of the day, I would start from my initial point, which was why are sanctions imposed; typically, they are not imposed because we think that they are such a blindingly good idea, they are imposed because we cannot think of anything else to do. The alternatives are to do nothing, other than rhetorical admonition, or to take military action.

  Q279  Lord Lawson of Blaby: Is that absolutely right? I realise it cannot be avowed but there is something in-between doing nothing and going to war, and that is subversion, which will be well known to you, in many contexts. I will not embarrass you by talking about the United Kingdom, but it is well known, for example, that the United States, in the past, with varying degrees of success, has employed that in Latin America and there are many other examples that are known to all of us, and obviously, in particular, to you. Indeed, there would be some people who would think that this is perhaps the most appropriate course of action in the case of Iran. As I say, I think it is very difficult, and this is not something that could be avowed, but it is an important part of the real world, is it not?

  Lord Renwick of Clifton: I am not against subversion, in the sense that I have been declared an `enemy of the state' in Zimbabwe and I regard that as a rather honourable category to be in, but I do not think the Committee's discussion is mainly about subversion. Could I make just one other point; sanctions typically are addressed to different audiences. Audience number one, very often, is your own domestic constituency. Audience number two is the regime you are trying to hurt. Audience number three sometimes may be members of that regime who are less intransigent than others. Another audience is people in that country who may be opponents of the regime. But, and this is very relevant to Iran and North Korea, you are also trying to send a clear signal to other countries about, the consequences of going down that course, there will be consequences, there are not no consequences.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Lords home page Parliament home page House of Commons home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007