Memorandum by British Energy
(I) BACKGROUND
British Energy welcomes the opportunity to contribute
its views to the House of Lords (HoL) Economic Affairs Committee
Inquiry, The Economics of Renewable Energy, an issue that has
the potential to have significant economic impacts on the power
sector in the UK.
British Energy is the UK's largest electricity
generator. We own and operate the country's eight most modern
nuclear power stations, one coal-fired power station, four small
gas plants and we also hope to develop wind generation projects.
Our fleet of nuclear stations make the largest single contribution
to tackling climate change in the UK. Carbon emissions from our
coal plant are subject to the constraints of the EU Emissions
Trading scheme. We provide electricity to the large Industrial
and Commercial electricity market, which requires us to buy and
sell renewable electricity to satisfy our supplier's obligation
under the renewables obligation.
It is proposed that the EC's renewable energy
target will be delivered from three sectors: heat, transport and
electricity. In this Submission British Energy focuses on the
cost implications of the targets on the electricity sector.
We have engaged fully in the climate change
and energy policy debate over the years and have responded to
many significant consultations and Inquiries, including the HoL
recent Inquiry into the EU's renewable target. All our recent
Submissions can be found on our website (www.british-energy.com).
(II) SUMMARY
KEY POINTS
There should be greater focus on
the three key objectives of reducing greenhouse gas emissions,
maintaining security-of-supply, and the provision of affordable
energy for consumers, rather than on the delivery of particular
types of technology.
Renewables should form part of a
portfolio of electricity generation in the UK but it should not
be at the expense of the liberalised market. Government should
minimise its interventions in the market as these can have far
reaching consequences, not least the cost to the consumer.
Current barriers to renewable electricity
include the costs, which remain in the main higher than other
low cost options, and the constraints of planning.
Once a technology has demonstrated
itself as cost competitive with existing technologies it should
receive no further funding support. Any support beyond this is
a distortion to the market and places additional unnecessary costs
on the consumer. No such mechanism to limit support is in place.
Bearing in mind there are now only
12 years to go before 2020, the original BaU renewables contribution
of 5% would have been difficult to reachachieving a trebling
of this value (ie 15%) would seem extremely challenging, even
with heavy market interventions and involve substantial additional
cost to the consumer.
A robust carbon price is needed to
incentivise the market to make the necessary emissions reductions
being sought by government to meet its targets, through the adoption
of the most cost-effective low carbon options.
(III) DETAILED
RESPONSE TO
QUESTIONS
Question 1. How do and should renewables fit
into Britain's overall energy policy? How does the UK's policy
compare with the United States, Australia, Canada, and other EU
countries?
1. Within Britain's energy policy there
should be greater focus on the three key objectives of reducing
greenhouse gas emissions, maintaining security-of-supply, and
the provision of affordable energy for consumers.
2. Renewables provide one form of greenhouse
gas abatement technology but there are other technologies and
approaches that can deliver reductions in greenhouse gas emissions.
These include nuclear and fossil fuel generation fitted with carbon
capture and storage technology.
3. Security of supply is important from
both the context of indigenous primary energy and the availability
of energy on demand. Renewable technologies contribute to the
former but in the case of the later, the effectiveness of a number
of renewable technologies is reduced due to the fact that they
can be extremely variable, requiring back-up generation when they
cannot operate.
4. Access to affordable energy is central
to this Inquiry so it is important to note that, in general, electricity
from renewable sources costs the consumer more than other conventional
technologies.
5. Renewables should form part of a portfolio
of electricity generation in the UK but it should not be at the
expense of the liberalised market. Government should minimise
its intervention in the market as these interventions can have
far reaching consequences. Depending on the initiative Government
intervention can lead to increased costs to the consumer.
6. When comparing energy policies it is
important to remember that the UK is in a different position when
compared to other European Countries. The UK is largely an island
generator with limited electrical interconnection to Europe thus
variable generation requires significant back-up.
7. EU Policy is derived centrally and all
Member States are involved in the process of determining energy
policy. The Green Package introduced the draft renewables directive
with the aim of delivering 20% of Europe's energy from renewable
sources by 2020. The UK's national 15% renewable energy targets
is extremely challenging, bearing in mind renewable energy currently
contributes less than 2% of the total.
8. The renewable energy target will be delivered
from three sectors: heat transport and electricity. Independent
analysis (see Table 1 below) suggests that the largest single
contribution is likely to come from the electricity sector, and
implies about 40% of the electricity generated in 2020 must come
from renewable sources.
Question 2. What are the barriers to greater
deployment of renewable energy? Are there technical limits to
the amount of renewable energy that the UK can absorb?
9. Current barriers to renewable electricity
include costs, which are high for most technologies (please see
question 7) and planning constraints.
10. Planning constraints are currently being
dealt with under the Planning Bill and these will address planning
issues across England and Wales. Planning reforms have taken place
and are in force across Scotland.
11. Significant technical issues arise as
a result of increasing the quantity of variable renewable generation
onto the grid. As well as those issues specifically mentioned
above there will be an increased requirement for fast response
units or spinning reserve to load follow and potentially to cover
periods when variable units are not available or do not export
as expected. This results in additional cost to the system and
ultimately the consumer.
12. Under a scenario where we are required
to deliver a very high percentage of renewable electricity it
is possible that there will be periods in the year when there
is an excess of generation and it will become necessary for some
stations to "spill" excess electricity to the grid or
to force their closure, both of which result in a significant
economic loss to the generator. This potential outcome does not
appear to have been addressed by Government analysis to date.
13. National Grid is charged with control
of frequency within very specific constraints and in order to
do this they have contracts with plant that is specifically operated
to maintain the frequency within these limits. An increased dependence
on more variable renewable generation will increase the complexity
of this balancing, and the cost to the system.
14. There is a capacity landscape for renewable
energy which needs to be assessed region by region. This must
also account for the cumulative impact on the land and visual
aspects of renewable generation.
15. We are concerned about the inconsistency
of interpretation by statutory bodies of the Habitats Directive.
An example is the Scottish Ministers' recent decision on the application
by Lewis Wind Power, in which British Energy is a joint venture
partner. Lewis Wind Power and its advisors believe the interpretation
in this case to be inconsistent with that in other parts of the
EU. This may set an unnecessarily restrictive precedent, which
could affect other projects.
Question 3. Are there likely to be technological
advances that would make renewable energy cheaper and viable without
Government support in the future? Should, and how could, policy
be designed to promote such technological advances?
16. Currently under the Governments Renewables
Obligation (RO) projects are not undertaken unless they are seen
to be profitable. The current situation is particularly perverse
as an economic rent is being paid to those organisations that
have been able to obtain planning permission and access to the
grid. This economic rent increases annually as the obligation
on suppliers increase and developers are unable to build and connect
new equipment to the grid. This means consumers are paying for
the RO whether there is delivery or not. This situation is highly
undesirable and needs to be addressed.
17. British Energy highlighted in their
response to the consultation on the banding of the RO that we
do not agree with the approach because:
it will not adequately address the
issues associated with the range of technology options and will
create an uncertain obligation in which investor confidence is
damaged;
for developed technologies, such
as onshore wind, it would be preferable to address the planning
and infrastructure constraints first, since this would likely
prove effective in delivering further development, before embarking
on the reforms that may not deliver the desired outcomes;
we believe a system of grants would
be more effective for developing technologies. This could account
for the project specific nature of these developments, and could
reflect the cost reductions that occur as technologies evolve.
18. Onshore wind is now a mature technology
with no significant further learning expected. According to some
commentators[13],[14]
it is now cost competitive without economic support with traditional
power generation technologies when a carbon price is included
in generation. (It should that there may be short term price increases
in turbine price due to manufacturing constraints and the price
of steel.)
19. Once a technology has demonstrated itself
as cost competitive with existing technologies it should receive
no further funding support. Any support beyond this is a distortion
to the market and places additional unnecessary costs on the consumer.
No such mechanism to limit support is in place.
Question 4. Has Government support been effective
in leading to more renewable energy? What have been the most cost-effective
forms of support in the UK and other countries and what should
the balance be between subsidies, guaranteed prices, quotas, carbon
taxes and other forms of support? Should such support favour any
particular form of renewable energy over the others? For instance,
what are the relative merits of feed-in tariffs versus the UK's
present Renewables Obligation Certificate (ROC) regime?
20. It is worth noting that the 2% of energy
for the UK in 2005 in Table 1 below is the result of a policy
to promote renewable electricity through the NFFO and RO schemes
since 1990; also, this figure has a significant contribution from
hydro electricity which was largely built before 1990. Bearing
in mind there are now only 12 years to go before 2020, the original
BaU renewables contribution of 5% would have been difficult to
reachachieving a trebling of this value (ie 15%) would
seem unrealistic, even with significant market interventions and
substantial cost to the consumer.
Table 1
RENEWABLES CONTRIBUTION TO TOTALS
|
| 2005(1)
| 2020 BaU(2) | 2020 EU Directive(3)
|
|
EU (% of total energy) | 7
| 12 | 20
|
UK (% of total energy) | 2
| 5 | 15
|
UK (% of electricity) | 4(4)
| | 41(5) |
UK (TWh electricity) | 17(4)
| | 150(1)
|
|
References: | |
| |
(1) Compliance costs for meeting the 20% renewable target for 2020, A Report for BERR, POYRY Energy Consulting, March 2008
|
(2) European Energy and Transport: Trends to 2030, EC, update 2005
|
(3) Draft Directive on the promotion of the use of energy from renewable sources, EC, 23 January 2008
|
(4) Digest of UK Energy Statistics (DUKES), July 2007
|
(5) Based on 368TWh electricity generation in 2020, Energy White Paper, May 2007
|
21. The Government recently intervened in the market
to adjust the renewables obligation and introduce banding. Key
to any support mechanism designed to encourage deployment of any
large scale technology is certainty. To intervene again and change
the mechanism will further reduce investor confidence.
22. A feed-in tariff delivers capacity on the ground
but it costs more than the RO and it requires perfect knowledge
of the renewable electricity supply curve. Without this knowledge
it is difficult to correct the tariff for significant changes
in the electricity market particularly changes in fossil fuel
prices and the carbon price, both of which are very difficult
to forecast. A poorly functioning market intervention can increase
cost to the consumer, distort the market, and may still fail to
deliver the objectives.
Question 5. On top of the costs of building and running
the different types of electricity generators, how much investment
in Britain's transmission and distribution networks will different
renewable energy sources require compared to other forms of generation?
Are the current transmission and distribution systems capable
of managing a large share of intermittent renewable electricity
generation and, if not, how should they be changed? Are the rules
about how we connect capacity to the grid supportive of renewables?
23. As identified earlier there are a number of constraints
in the system currently on the flow of electricity between regions
leading to grid congestion. This is particularly apparent in Scotland
and between Scotland and England and this problem will become
more acute as greater quantities of renewables are connected in
these regions. It is important to note that the areas of highest
natural renewable resource are also areas of low population and
low demand for electricity, and often in regions of great natural
beauty.
24. Particular renewable technologies require connection
to the grid from more remote regions. This includes wind and marine
technologies. As well as the issue with grid congestion there
is a requirement to enlarge the network to more rural regions
requiring either completely new transmission lines or an upgrade
of the existing systems, bringing with it additional cost to the
consumer.
25. Greater quantities of renewable technologies with
higher degrees of variability on the grid will require more fast
response units and/or more plant running part loaded. Part loaded
plant is less efficient than plant running at full load and it
is necessary to compensate this plant for running in this manner.
The costs of variable generation will get smeared across generators
through the Balancing Services Use of System Charge and will ultimately
get passed to the consumer further increasing costs.
Question 6. How do the external costs of renewable generation
of electricitysuch as concerns in many affected rural areas
that wind farms and extra pylons spoil areas of natural beautycompare
with those of fossil fuels and nuclear power? How should these
be measured and compared? Is the planning system striking the
right balance between all the different considerations?
26. External costs (or externalities) include issues
such as emissions of pollutants, health impacts, visual impacts,
noise, and land use change. The damages caused by these impacts
are not integrated into the pricing system and are consequentially
referred to as external costs.
27. The ExternE (Externalities of Energy) research project[15]
of the European Commission defined external costs as follows:
"An external cost, also known as an externality, arises when
the social or economic activities of one group of persons have
an impact on another group and when that impact is not fully accounted,
or compensated for, by the first group"
28. The ExternE project calculated the external costs
of a number of technologies by member state and the UK specific
figures are summarised in Figure 1.
Figure 1
ENVIRONMENTAL COSTS ASSOCIATED WITH VARIOUS TECHNOLOGIES[16]

29. Externalities of energy are of course not limited
to environmental and health related impacts but may also result
from macro-economic, policy or strategic factors not reflected
in market prices such as security of supply, cost stability and
broad economic impacts on employment and balance of trade. If
such externalities were also to be internalised the effect would
be positive for low carbon options such as renewables and nuclear
power.
Question 7. How do the costs of generating electricity
from renewables compare to fossil fuel and nuclear generation?
What are the current estimates for the costs of "greener"
fossil fuel generation with carbon capture and storage and how
do these costs compare to renewable generation? What impact do
these various forms of electricity generation have on carbon emissions?
30. The Governments Energy Review completed in 2006 prepared
comprehensive models to deliver levelised costs of a number of
major power generating technologies. The results from this analysis
showed that with a carbon price nuclear is a very cost competitive
form of electricity generating technology.
31. Figure 2 from the Energy Review shows the results
of this analysis with the high gas price assumption[17]
from the time of the analysis together with a 25/tCO2[18]
carbon price. Nuclear is cost competitive on this basis. This
analysis shows that a high carbon price has to be reached to make
wind technologies cost competitive.
Figure 2
ENERGY REVIEW (CHART B6) BASE CASE COSTS WITH CARBON PRICE
(25/TCO2) AND HIGH GAS PRICE (53P/THERM) SOURCE: BERR ENERGY
REVIEW, JULY 2006

32. Figure 3 extracted from a report by IPA Energy to
the Renewable Energy Foundation[19]
shows levelised costs in p/kWh. The cost ranges are as a result
of considering carbon price ranges from 10-50/tCO2.
This clearly shows nuclear to be the emerging benchmark technology
in this scenario. It should also be noted that the cost for wind
technologies in this analysis makes onshore wind cost competitive
without financial support in this scenario.
Figure 3
SEVERN BARRAGE COSTING EXERCISE, IPA FOR THE RENEWABLE
ENERGY FOUNDATION, MARCH 2008

33. Figure 2 and 3 show levelised costs vary, depending
on assumptions. It is important to note the there are high capital
costs associated with building nuclear power stations that require
long term certainty. Nuclear power is built in large installations
typically over 1GW in sizethis reduces the impact of having
to construct multiple smaller installations. (Please see Appendix
1 for a calculation that shows that nearly 2,000 onshore wind
turbines would need to be constructed to deliver as much output
as Sizewell B, British Energy's 1.2GW nuclear power station in
Suffolk.)
34. Levelised costs is only one tool that investors will
consider when choosing whether to invest in new power generation
technology. Whilst levelised costs are a quick means to compare
power generation technologies there are a number of aspects they
do not capture:
Policy uncertainty (and the option value of waiting).
Price risks (fuel price, CO2 price, electricity
price).
Technical risks (capital cost, operating and maintenance
cost, decommissioning and waste regulation, utilisation levels,
build times).
Financial risks (weighted cost of capital, credit
risk, contractual risk).
Of these risks the electricity price risk is very significant
for highly capital intensive projects such as renewables and nuclear.
35. Costs associated with Carbon Capture and Storage
vary because there are no such systems operating at the current
time.
36. As noted in our response to the Question 1, British
Energy believes that reducing greenhouse gas emissions should
remain a key priority for Government. For this reason we encourage
Government to consider the marginal abatement costs of the different
technologies considered:
nuclear power is a known technology with very
low lifecycle levels of carbon emissions[20]
associated with it;
when considering life cycle emissions of variable
renewable technologies it is important to factor in the emissions
resulting from the requirement for part loaded plant or fast response
reserve. This is particularly relevant at high penetrations of
the technology; and
the Governments CCS competition suggests that
the CCS capture target is 90% which results in 10% of the carbon
dioxide emissions being released. Together with a higher cost
this increases the marginal abatement cost of this technology.
37. Figure 4, based on analysis by British Energy, shows
the marginal abatement costs for a number of different technologies.
Appendix 2 outlines the methodology and sources used to derive
these costs. What this chart shows is that at current carbon prices
(around 25/tCO2) nuclear is a viable economic option for
delivering low carbon electricity and reducing emissions of UK
greenhouse gases.
Figure 4
MARGINAL ABATEMENT COSTS OF VARYING LOW CARBON TECHNOLOGIES[21]

38. The carbon associated with balancing the system and
back-up generation has to be considered, when calculating carbon
savings as a result of the implementation of "variable"
renewable technologies (particularly at higher penetrations):
in order to balance a system with a high penetration
of variable generation it is necessary to run some thermal plant
at reduced load which means that the plant operates less efficiently
and produces more carbon dioxide per unit of output. This plant
is able to respond to fluctuations in generation from the variable
plant and maintain the required frequency; and
when variable generation is not producing power
(periods of low wind or the tides are wrong) it is necessary to
operate back-up generation that has been specifically built for
this purpose. These are often fast response plant such as Open
Cycle Gas Turbines which have lower efficiencies than Closed Cycle
Gas Turbines.
It is necessary to account for these emissions in the policy
to deliver higher proportions of renewable technologies as they
are a direct result of the policy choice.
Question 8. How do the costs and benefits of renewable
electricity generation compare to renewables in the other key
forms of energy consumptiontransport and heating?
39. Renewable energy from heat and transport have a number
of complications associated with them:
the use of biofuels needs to be carefully considered
as it can lead to undesirable consequences. These include competition
for food (and associated cost impacts), a greater use of monocultures
and impacts on global biodiversity. Amongst these sustainability
concerns there are growing questions over whether biofuels actually
reduce carbon emissions due to their impact on land use;[22],[23]
the use of heat from power stations leads to a
loss of electrical efficiency unless the plant has been optimised
for this purpose;
it is not clear whether or not the developments
required in renewable heat and renewable transport will come forward;
the potential for renewable heat and renewable
transport to contribute by 2020 is limited; and
this places a significant burden on the electricity
sector to deliver the overall UK renewable energy target of 15%.
Question 9. If the UK is to meet the EU target that by
2020 15% of energy consumed will come from renewables, will most
of this come from greater use of renewable sources in electricity
generation? If so, why? Should British support for renewables
in other countries be allowed to contribute towards meeting the
target for the UK?
40. For the reasons identified above, electricity from
renewables will form a higher proportion of the UK's final renewable
energy share. This results in significant impacts on the power
generation sector including:
higher costs, both for the technologies and managing
the networks, which will subsequently be borne by consumers;
requirement for more variable generation technologies;
necessity for significant grid expansion;
modifications to the market (through financial
subsidies for some technologies) leading to greater price volatility;
and
greater possibility of stranded assets.
41. It should be noted that the burden sharing process
for the renewables directive was not based entirely on the countries
technological potential to deliver renewable energy but also on
its ability to pay (through a link to the MS's GDP). For this
reason all available economic tools should be allowed for MS's
to deliver their renewables targets and this should include a
measure of trading of guarantees of origin (or green certificates).
Question 10. How would changes in the cost of carbonunder
the European emissions trading schemeaffect the relative
costs of renewables and other sources of energy? Would a more
effective carbon emissions trading scheme remove the need for
special support of renewable energy?
42. As the carbon price increases it supports low carbon
forms of generation including renewables, nuclear and fossil fuel
fitted with CCS. As noted in response to Question 7, a higher
carbon price is required to support wind generation according
to the Governments figures.
43. A robust carbon price will incentivise the market
to make the necessary changes, including the construction of low
carbon forms of power generation in order to deliver the emissions
cap. When it becomes economically viable to use renewables with
only the carbon price as support then the market will deliver
renewables. Until this stage should the Government wish to deliver
renewable technologies then it will be necessary to provide additional
support.
Question 11. What are the costs and benefits of the present
generation of biofuels? Will there be a second generation of biofuels
and, if so, what are the estimated costs? What are, or are likely
to be, the carbon emission impacts of first and second generation
biofuels, and what are the other relevant environmental effects?
44. It is important to successfully deliver a first generation
of biofuels before the market is able to assess the potential
for a second generation.
45. British Energy believes the Government should concentrate
on the lowest cost abatement options first. There are limited
gains to be had with biofuels in the near term and improving the
efficiency of cars and encouraging consumers to carry out a modal
shift to lower carbon intensity forms of transport should be addressed
first.
46. The quantity of bio-fuels delivered will impact on
the overall renewable energy target and possibly place additional
burdens on other sectors involved in the targets. As noted earlier
this is most likely to impact the electricity sector.
13
http://www.ukerc.ac.uk/Downloads/PDF/06/0706_Investing_in_Power.pdf
in which the levelised cost of onshore wind is quoted as £39/MWh Back
14
Severn Barrage costing exercise, IPA for REF, March 2008 (see
diagram later in this report) Back
15
http://www.externe.info/
English Press Release Back
16
Adapted from ExternE, Externalities of Energy, Volumes 7 and
8, EC (1999) Back
17
The high gas price assumptions from the Energy Review (53p/therm)
have been chose as they better reflect today's gas prices. The
fossil fuel prices in the Energy Review were lower than Governments
most recent fossil fuel price projections Back
18
Today's carbon price is currently trading higher than this for
phase 2 Back
19
Severn Barrage costing exercise, IPA for REF, March 2008 Back
20
A study on our Torness AGR Nuclear power station identified that
there were approximately 5g/kWh of carbon dioxide released over
the stations complete lifecycle (http://www.british-energy.com/pagetemplate.php?pid=251)
compared to nearer 1,000g/kWh for coal power stations (POST note
268 http://www.parliament.uk/documents/upload/postpn268.pdf) Back
21
Sources: Based on Investment Analysis for Energy White Paper,
Redpoint, May 2007, Data from Severn Barrage Costing Exercise,
IPA for REF, March 2008. Notes: Left hand bar denote abatement
costs for 2007 and right hand bar for 2031 Back
22
"Use of U.S. Croplands for Biofuels Increases Greenhouse
Gases Through Emissions from Land-Use Change" Timothy Searchinger
et Al, Journal of Science, February 2008 Back
23
"Land Clearing and the Biofuel Carbon Debt" Joseph Fargione
et Al, Journal of Science, February 2008 Back
|