Select Committee on Economic Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 160 - 179)

TUESDAY 23 OCTOBER 2007

Professor Christian Dustmann and Professor Ian Preston

  Q160  Lord Layard: It does require, as you said just now, that capital is supplied infinitely elastically, i.e. that the rate of profit is not affected by immigration, whereas it does not seem altogether unreasonable to suppose that lying behind the pressure for immigration is the notion that you can get more profit out of it. Is there anything that can be said about what the impact of immigration has been on the rate of profit?

  Professor Dustmann: We have not looked at that, we looked at the impact on wages and I am not aware of any research which has looked at that. Possibly the two novelties in our particular study would be to look at wage effects along the distribution, which so far has not been done because we looked at average wages, and to give up the assumption that capital is perfectly inelastic, which was the assumption in most previous theoretical models. We suggested the possibility that capital may be in elastic supply. If capital is perfectly inelastic, then any surplus would go to the owners of capital and you may want to call that profit.

  Q161  Lord Layard: Can I just make sure we all understand it. If there is a constant return to scale then if the wages have gone up—let us leave it!

  Professor Dustmann: Maybe one thing I should just add is that what we find for the UK may not be the same for other countries, Migration affects labour markets in very different ways in different countries. Why is that the case? Because the skills structure and capital structure of the receiving economies are different and the skill mix of immigrants is different. Even if the skill mix was the same where we would find immigrants in the wage distribution may differ across countries. So we have shown that in the UK, while on average they are higher educated than native workers, we do find immigrants, at least initially, very much at the low end of the wage distribution, and these things together show the effects that immigration will have on wages at different parts of the distribution and will have on capital.

  Q162  Lord Turner of Ecchinswell: I am sorry to go on about these theoretical points but it is very important that we understand what the theory tells us. I looked at your document for the Low Pay Commission and indeed the bit about averages is on pages 28 to 30; I just want to clarify that I have a correct understanding of what you are saying there and what you are not saying. Am I right, first of all, that you are saying that under certain circumstances the average wages of pre-existing native non-immigrants can rise, but of course that is a different thing from whether average wages rise because there could be a compositional effect which pulls it down.

  Professor Dustmann: Yes.

  Q163  Lord Turner of Ecchinswell: I just wanted to clarify that. Secondly, I think you were rather suggesting in what you said a minute ago that there was a bit of a mystery about a positive effect on the average wages of natives but what I think you are saying the theory suggests is that as long as capital is in elastic supply and as long as the skill mix of immigrants is different, then we would expect a positive effect.

  Professor Dustmann: That is absolutely right.

  Q164  Lord Turner of Ecchinswell: The third point though is a crucial one because what you then say at the end of it is that the very same conditions which are required for there to be a positive effect on average native wages also require that some categories of native workers lose.

  Professor Preston: That is correct as well.

  Q165  Lord Turner of Ecchinswell: So the very factors which tell us that on average native workers might gain would automatically tend to mean that there must be some category of native workers who lose.

  Professor Preston: Yes, that is all true within an equilibrium.

  Lord Turner of Ecchinswell: It is all within an equilibrium but it is useful to get those points clear. Thank you.

  Chairman: Let us move on. Lord Vallance.

  Q166  Lord Vallance of Tummel: can we come off the theory just for a bit, and what we heard from some previous witnesses was that there were real practical data methodological problems in the analysis of immigration issues and the labour impact. What is your assessment of those problems and how robust do you feel are your most recent results on the labour market?

  Professor Preston: There are data problems and there is not much we can do about that if we accept the data. We can try and make it more robust to non-systematic measurement errors in our measures of immigration but if there are systematic errors there then that is going to cause almost insuperable problems. There are other methodological problems which we recognise completely, particularly about identifying the direction of causation. The estimates in the study we have been talking about are all based on comparing the economic outcomes in different regions that have different intensities of immigrant inflow. Of course, if a region is temporarily doing economically well you would expect wages to be rising there and immigrants to be attracted in, so even if immigration had no effect on wages you would expect to see a positive association between wages and immigration. We try as far as we can to overcome that by not relying on association between actual immigration and wage changes but association with that part of immigration that we can predict from past levels of immigration which you would not expect to be affected by temporary changes in economic circumstances. That should make the estimates robust to that sort of problem but there are assumptions behind that that you cannot test; you have just got to take them on faith and if they do not work then that is a problem. But we make as strong an effort as we can to try and make them robust to those sorts of worries, which are the main things that we have been concerned about.

  Professor Dustmann: We had meetings with the Low Pay Commission and several government department representatives before that report was published, and of course these concerns came up and we tried hard to ease these concerns. We not only look at data from the labour force survey when we compute wages but we also use data from NES/ASHE, which is the data set which is used to look at wage inflation in the UK, real wage increases and nominal wage increases. We discuss very carefully the issues Ian has been talking about, but the problem with any empirical work in economics is, of course, that the data is never as good as we would want it to be. But I am at least pretty confident that the analysis we have done here is very robust and I would not expect future work to show dramatically different results for the same wave of immigration that we have analysed here. That is very important because future immigration may have different effects on the British Labour Market.

  Q167  Lord Turner of Ecchinswell: Can I ask one question which is a direct follow-up to this methodological point? To the extent that you are trying to infer it from differences between regions, if capital were fully mobile between regions of the UK and other categories of labour were fully mobile between categories of the UK, you would not then expect to see the regional pattern of results. Does not the regional pattern of results only arise from the extent to which other factors of production are not fully mobile?

  Professor Preston: Mobility of labour at all is going to diffuse the effects out across different regions and we are aware of that issue as well. You can control for that to a degree because you observe native labour of different types and you can put that in as controls in your estimation and we do try and do that.

  Professor Dustmann: We do also extend things and try to publish them, so we have done a lot of additional work among it trying to get a grip on the degree of mobility of native workers as a reaction to immigration, and there is very little evidence for that.

  Q168  Lord Turner of Ecchinswell: Can I ask another point on your empirical results on these questions? You have commented on pay. Is it your belief that immigration has had any significant effects on employment or the participation of British native workers, particularly on those which start off with low participation rates? For instance, if you have long-established ethnic minorities that have very low participation rates, do new waves of immigration affect their employment or are all the impacts that you have found as it were wage-related—price effects rather than quantity effects?

  Professor Preston: In that particular study we did not look at employment but we have done a previous study for the Home Office which was looking explicitly at employment and participation. It was using earlier years, it was the mid-Eighties up to 2000, I think, whereas the later study used the late Nineties and the early part of this decade, and that work has been published. We do find small, negative effects on employment and participation, but these are not very well-determined. Reading them at face value, there are some negative effects on employment and on participation, but as I say the statistical imprecision on them is so great that you could not rule out zero effects. We did compare different groups as well—you tend to find participation going up amongst the skilled and down amongst the medium-skilled and low-skilled which fits with the pattern of wage effects. We did look separately at recent immigrants and minorities and we could not find evidence that they were worse affected, the actual estimates were that they were less affected but they were so imprecisely determined that I would not want to make a strong claim one way or the other.

  Q169  Lord Kingsdown: How have the children of immigrants performed educationally, do you know, and how have they fared in the British labour market?

  Professor Dustmann: I have brought you a paper we have written on that. Let me start with the problem we have in the UK which is that there is no data set except for the BHPS—which is too small to analyse immigrants—which links an individual to their parent. So the way to address the children of immigrants has to rely on something else. What we do based on the labour force survey is we use the different waves of immigrants who have come to this country which, for the ethnic minority community, is a pretty recent event. We have linked children who are born in the UK but who are ethnic minorities to their parents, so we can identify in the labour force survey second or maybe higher generation immigrants but only from ethnic minority groups, not from the white group. To give you the magnitude of what that means, at the moment about half of the foreign-born in this country are white in terms of ethnicity and half are non-whites, so the non-whites would report their ethnicity and we can identify them in the labour force survey. If you look at their educational achievements, across all groups educational achievements are at least as high as those of the white, native-born individuals who, with a very high probability, are descendants of white individuals, but there is a large variation on top of it. For instance, 85% of Chinese individuals who are born in this country go to college, a much smaller percentage of Pakistani and Indian individuals go to college, but even those percentages are higher than those of comparable native whites. So the educational achievement of ethnic minority second or maybe third generation individuals is remarkably high in this country. If we look then at the wages and if you look at the employment, it is also more favourable. However, that is due to the fact that 40% of ethnic minorities do live in London and London has higher wages and also a more buoyant labour market. So if we control for the fact that those individuals of second generation origin live in London, then their wages are slightly lower, in particular for females, and their employment falls slightly. We have done that very carefully in this report and if you find that interesting we will leave this here.

  Chairman: That would be very helpful. Lord Sheldon.

  Q170  Lord Sheldon: Migrants have taken certain jobs where they are over-qualified. Do you expect them to move on to jobs that better match their skills in due course?

  Professor Preston: We can already see this in the evidence that we have in our report of where they are in the wage distribution. If you look at very recent migrants they are quite heavily concentrated down the lower end and if you look at less recent migrants it is the same sort of pattern; but it is less pronounced so you can see evidence of them moving up the wage distribution, which is compatible with the movement towards more appropriate matching up with their qualifications or skills and you would expect that to ameliorate the downward pressure that we found on wages at the bottom end if that continues. I would expect things to go in that direction.

  Q171  Lord Sheldon: What sort of timescale do you expect for that?

  Professor Dustmann: There is a problem again of measurement and that problem is that many immigrants—and we come to that a little bit later when we go down your catalogue of questions—return back to their home countries. So return is not random if only the good guys or only the bad guys in terms of educational achievement go back, then we cannot identify a moving up in the skills distribution due to a particular selective return migration from changes in the application of their skills to the British labour market. So that is a little bit problematic. We could give you precise numbers on that if we did not have this particular problem.

  Q172  Lord Layard: How does the national minimum wage affect the demand for migrant labour? Do you think that minimum wages have other implications we should take into account when we look at the economic impact of immigration and, in particular, do you think that the current UK policies ensure employer compliance with minimum wage regulations applying to migrant workers?

  Professor Preston: It is not something I really have a view on because I do not think I have any evidence on any of those questions, so I am not sure what I can say.

  Professor Dustmann: Given that basically immigration leads to a downward pressure in that part of the distribution where actually we do find the minimum wage which is on the sixth or seventh percentile of the wage distribution, one may deduce from that that the minimum wage does protect some workers at that particular part of the distribution. What effect it has on higher grade immigrants versus natives as Ian says, I do not have evidence. I can answer it in terms of what I think about it myself, which is I do think that European labour markets in general, particularly in continental Europe, have been characterised by a strong rigidity at the lower end of the wage distribution and employers try to undercut that by employing immigrants who come illegally. So I do think there is a lot of that going on in the construction sector or the agricultural sector in countries like Germany, but that again is not something on which we have done research.

  Q173  Lord Layard: The implication would be that immigration at the lower end in the presence of the minimum wage would have increased the unemployment of the low waged domestics. When you did your cross-regional research were you able to look at that issue?

  Professor Dustmann: We did not look. The Low Pay Commission asked us to look at wages, not employment, and we have not looked at employment. We are happy to do another study looking at it.

  Chairman: Let us move on. Lord Vallance.

  Q174  Lord Vallance of Tummel: Does immigration lessen the incentives for employers to train the indigenous workforce or indeed to invest capital in improving productivity?

  Professor Dustmann: There are two types of training we distinguish in labour economics. The one sort of training is general training, that is training you can take with you and every firm finds it valuable and will pay you the same premium on that. The other type of training is firm-specific, which is only of value in a particular firm, so general training in competitive labour markets of the type we usually study will never be borne or never be paid by the employer because the employee can take it with himself or herself. So it will always be the employee who will pay for general training. For specific training the employer is willing to pay but that specific training is not worth anything outside that particular firm, so this is the kind of rudimentary model of analysing firm-based training and we do not see that migration would in any way change that. If you train a worker in general training, you would not be willing to pay for that training whether that worker is a migrant or a non-migrant; if you train him in specific training, the specific training is worth nothing to the worker outside your firm, so you are the beneficiary of that training and you would finance that training.

  Q175  Lord Vallance of Tummel: As far as capital investment is concerned, if there is availability of labour through immigration, does that mean there will be less incentive to invest in productivity improvements through capital investment?

  Professor Dustmann: We have done work so far for Germany and there is work for the US looking at alternative adjustment mechanisms to immigration. The adjustment mechanism we are analysing in this particular work (the LPC Report) is wages, and that is what people have usually in mind when they think about the way immigration affects the local labour market. However, there are other adjustment mechanisms. One is by changing the industry structure and the other is through technology, so the most interesting example or maybe the most illuminating example is the wine industry in Australia and in California, which is highly labour-intensive in California and highly mechanised in Australia, the reason being that it is very easy to get unskilled workers in California but not in Australia. This is anecdotal, but if you look at the evidence there is evidence for the US that, particularly in the traded sector, technological adjustment is more important than adjustment in the mix of what companies produce. We have done the same analysis for Germany; we are still working on that but the preliminary evidence points in exactly the same direction with surprisingly similar magnitudes of estimates. So there is evidence that technology adjusts to the availability of labour in particular parts of the skill distribution.

  Lord Vallance of Tummel: Thank you, that is interesting.

  Q176  Lord Turner of Ecchinswell: The Government has often stressed the positive impact of immigration on total GDP. Do you have a point of view on what its impact is on GDP per capita, which is presumably a balance between the positive effects on the average wages of native workers minus the compositional effect simply due to the influx of people on low wages? Have you ever put that together and worked out whether this is positive for GDP per capita or negative?

  Professor Preston: I have never done that calculation, but it is a mixture of what we said earlier about the effects on native wages. The evidence on recent immigrants is that they tend to be located lower down and you would think that average native wages possibly go up. The typical recent migrant tends to be at the lower end, so those two things work against each other.

  Q177  Lord Turner of Ecchinswell: Presumably, if that overall was a negative effect because of the compositional effect and if society was committed through, for instance, the working and family tax credit to redistribution, it could be the case that the native workers would lose either all or a significant proportion of their beneficial impact from higher pre-tax wages. Has anybody ever done that analysis to see whether they are a net winner after the redistributional effects to which we are committed?

  Professor Preston: I have no more information on that.

  Q178  Lord Kingsdown: In 2003 you were both among the authors of a report for the Home Office forecasting that annual net immigration from the eight countries which joined the EU in 2004 (the so-called A8 countries) would be between 5,000 and 13,000 a year. What explains the difference between your estimates then, if I may ask, and the much larger number of A8 migrants who have come to the UK since May 2004?

  Professor Dustmann: First of all, we should point out that that number is a net number and it was calculated over a ten year period, so net is the difference between in migration and out migration. We expected that return migration of these immigrants would be, over a ten year period, quite large. Secondly, that number was based and at least half of that report was a critical assessment of these numbers. We were very, very careful to put these numbers in the context and in the possibilities we have actually for estimating these things. So while the study we have done for the Low Pay Commission may have some data problems, it is standing on much more robust grounds than any study which was published at that time on EU Accession, and ours was not the only one to predict the inflow of immigrants from the enlargement countries, the reason being that we can only make a prediction if we have some past information about such migration. In this particular case, because of the Cold War and the Iron Curtain, there was no information about how individuals from those countries would react to the wage differential and to other economic differentials between the UK in particular, Europe in general and those particular countries on the other side. What we needed to do, therefore, was take past migration from other countries to come up with a prediction, and that of course leads always to estimates which may get it very wrong. That is the context. We should then point out that the numbers we predict are net numbers. So if, for instance, every year about 200,000 individuals would come to the UK, the stock of immigrants would be increased so that the net average migration over the period would be 200,000 per year and after ten years there would be two million immigrants added to the stock. If, however, they only stay for two years, then after ten years the average net inflow would be 40,000, so that is a very different number. We have to take account therefore of return migration when we look at these numbers and that has not been done in the entire public debate on EU enlargement unfortunately. The other issues which we pointed out very carefully in the report are that our report was based on the assumption that countries like the large European economies, in particular Germany and Italy, would open their borders towards the eastern immigration countries as well. That is something that they announced but then they retreated on that particular announcement, so we looked at those immigrants who would basically go to the UK as an alternative to Germany and we did not consider immigrants who went to the UK because they could not go to Germany or some of the other larger continental countries.

  Q179  Chairman: Do you reckon that accounted for quite a lot?

  Professor Dustmann: I am absolutely sure that if Germany had opened its labour market to the accession countries we would have seen lower inflows to the UK.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Lords home page Parliament home page House of Commons home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2008