Select Committee on Economic Affairs First Report


CHAPTER 4: IMMIGRATION AND LABOUR SHORTAGES

99.  The Government, business community and other groups argue that migrants are needed to fill labour and skills shortages in the UK, and that British people often cannot or do not want to fill vacancies. The speech of the previous Prime Minister, Tony Blair, to the CBI just before EU enlargement on 27 April 2004 expressed this view clearly:

    "There are half a million vacancies in our job market and our strong and growing economy needs migration to fill these vacancies ... some [of which] are for unskilled jobs which people living here are not prepared to do ... [moreover] a quarter of all health professionals are overseas born ... 23% of staff in our higher education institutions are non-UK nationals ... our public services would be close to collapse without their contribution".

100.  Most employers giving evidence to us echoed this view, citing a better "work ethic" and "attitude" as one of the main reasons why they employed immigrants rather than British workers. Sainsbury's said: "We have found migrant workers to have a very satisfactory work ethic, in many cases superior to domestic workers" (p 492). The National Farmers Union (NFU) told us that migrants "are an attractive source of labour to UK employers because of their work ethos, efficiency and dependency" and that they do jobs "the domestic workforce is unwilling to do" (p 100). Tom Hadley of the Recruitment and Employment Confederation (REC) suggested that "sometimes in the UK you almost feel that there is an attitude gap rather than a skills gap" (Q 147). The British Hospitality Association suggested that "in many cases, they [migrants] are seen as having more to offer than the domestic workforce" (p 406).

101.  A recent study of employers' use of migrant labour[49], commissioned by the Home Office and cited in their evidence to us (p 198), suggests that employers' preference for immigrants because of their "general attitude and work ethic" is not exceptional but fairly prevalent across various sectors, especially in low-skilled occupations. Susan Anderson of the CBI explained that employers are simply making a rational business choice:

    "If you have the choice between two individuals, one of whom seems really enthusiastic about work, who wants to get on ... who wants to learn and wants to move on and wants to perform well, then you are going to choose that individual with that positive attitude. If those positive attitudes are coming more from the migrant worker than the UK-born, then I am afraid you are going to go for the migrant workers. We know what the solution to that disadvantage would be: a bit more enthusiasm from the indigenous worker" (Q 103).

102.  Although clearly benefiting employers, immigration that is in the best interest of individual employers is not always in the best interest of the economy as a whole. If, as Liam Byrne MP says, the Government is "not actually running British immigration policy in the exclusive interests of the British business community" (Q 534), it is important to examine the economic basis of the arguments that immigrants are needed to fill and reduce vacancies, and that immigrants have a superior work ethic, and thus are needed to do the jobs that British workers cannot or will not do.

Immigration and vacancies

103.  As Prime Minister, Tony Blair argued that immigration was needed to lower the number of vacancies. But as Figure 4 shows, the recent increase in immigration to the UK has not resulted in a decline in the number of overall vacancies in the UK, which has remained around or above 600,000 since 2001. The recent ITEM Club report cites data from a survey carried out by the British Chamber of Commerce, showing that the proportion of firms reporting recruitment problems across all skills levels has not substantially declined since 2000.[50]

FIGURE 4

Vacancies in the UK (thousands), 2001-2007


Source ONS, seasonally adjusted vacancies

104.  Rising immigration has not resulted in a decline in vacancies because the number of jobs in an economy is not fixed. Immigration increases both the supply of labour and, over time, the demand for labour, thus creating new vacancies. As William Simpson of the CBI explained, "immigrants do not just plug existing holes in the labour market … they create new demands for products and services which are already available, but also those that cater to the immigration population. So this will, in a dynamic economy, lead to creating new vacancies" as companies seek to recruit more employees to increase production to meet this extra demand. (Q 103) In other words, because immigration expands the overall economy, it cannot be expected to be an effective policy tool for significantly reducing vacancies. Vacancies are, to a certain extent, a sign of a healthy labour market and economy. They cannot be a good reason for encouraging large-scale labour immigration.

Immigrants' work ethic

105.  There is little doubt that many immigrants are extremely diligent and highly motivated. However, Dr Bridget Anderson pointed out that notions of good attitude and work ethic are "highly subjective and potentially simplistic. Indeed it is interesting to see them feature in otherwise scientific analyses of immigration" (p 138). In practice, "work ethic" often refers to a range of attributes and qualities including, for example: willingness to accept low wages and poor working conditions; effort and reliability; flexibility; willingness to train and acquire new skills; and ease of retention. In low-skilled jobs non-EU immigrants are often easier to retain than British workers and EU immigrants because immigration rules restrict them to the employer specified on the work permit (Anderson p 138). For example, the NFU argued that non-EU migrants employed on Seasonal Agricultural Worker Scheme (SAWS) permits "provide a source of labour that is guaranteed to remain on the farm during the crucial harvest period" (p 100).

106.  Recent research suggests that, because of the availability of a large and diverse pool of labour, some employers develop a specific demand for immigrant workers, sometimes even for particular nationalities of workers. In some low-wage sectors, such as domestic care and hospitality, some employers use highly stereotyped perceptions of "national characteristics" as a key proxy for assessing candidates' suitability for specific occupations.[51] However, Mr Hadley of the REC said employers ask for workers with specific nationalities only in "isolated cases" (Q 146).

107.  Dr Anderson commented that when employers compare immigrant workers with British workers available for low-skilled jobs, "they are not necessarily comparing like with like … You have people [immigrants] with a high level of education … [who] simply would not be working in food processing if they were British" (Q 216). Immigrants often compare their earnings and employment conditions in the UK to those in their countries of origin. This is especially true among immigrants staying temporarily. Consequently, there are significant differences between the wage and employment expectations of immigrants and British workers, and also between immigrants from different countries, depending on the differences between the economic conditions in immigrants' home countries. There is research suggesting that employers are often acutely aware of the economic and other trade-offs that immigrants are willing to make by tolerating wages and employment conditions that are poor by the standards of their host country but higher than those prevailing in immigrants' countries of origin.[52]

108.  In many cases, immigrants will be better qualified and more accepting of the wages and employment conditions offered than the British workers available and competing for the same low-skilled jobs. Profit-maximising employers can be expected to have a preference for the workers who best suit their needs but, for the economy as a whole, immigrants' strong work ethic cannot be a sufficient reason for promoting labour immigration. Government policy is to ensure that employers make efforts to recruit British or other EEA workers before turning to migrants from outside the EU. How effective this policy has been is unclear and we urge the Government to ensure it is properly monitored. Our concern is to avoid the development of a specific demand for immigrant workers that is based on immigrants' lower expectations about wages and employment conditions or on a preference for labour whose freedom of employment in the UK is constrained by the worker's immigration status.

Price adjustments and other alternatives to immigration

109.  Professor David Metcalf, Chairman of the new Migration Advisory Committee (MAC) that advises the Government on immigration and labour shortages, told us that "the whole notion of shortages is a bit of a slippery concept" (Q 557). Basic economic theory suggests that labour shortages occur when the demand for labour exceeds the supply of workers who are qualified, available and willing to do the job. Vacancies exist because employers wish to recruit more workers than are willing to work at the prevailing wage. In a simple economic model of a competitive labour market, where demand and supply of labour are critically determined by the price of labour, most labour shortages are temporary and eventually eliminated by rising wages.

110.  In practice, labour markets do not always work as the simple textbook model suggests. How, and how quickly, prices clear labour markets can depend on the source of the labour shortages, which could include sudden increases in demand or inflexible supply (because, for example, it takes time to train local workers). Moreover, how local labour supply reacts to a change in wages varies across sectors and occupations. A 10% wage increase may be enough to encourage more British workers to fill vacancies in hospitality, but it may not be enough to increase domestic labour supply in sectors such as agriculture and others that involve work that some workers consider as "low status". In a few sectors, wages may have to rise significantly to attract local workers. However, Professor Rowthorn argued that "there may be one or two jobs like that but markets exist … if wages are higher, eventually people will be drawn into occupations" (Q 17). The recent ITEM Club report notes that "we do not know how the domestic labour supply would have reacted to rising growth in 2004-06 in the absence of increased immigration. It might have proved surprisingly [responsive] via increased participation rates in marginal groups".[53]

111.  Most of our witnesses from employer organisations were explicit about low pay being a key explanation of the difficulties employers have with recruiting local workers and of the high share of immigrant labour in their sectors. For example, explaining the reasons for shortages in the social care sector, Mr Hadley of the REC, said that "we just cannot get enough people on our books to fill the need and part of it is the pay is actually quite low and is a factor possibly" (Q 145). Josie Irwin of the Royal College of Nursing argued that "if nurses were paid a fair salary, then they clearly would have an economic impact in attracting domestic trained nurses to join the workforce" (Q 296). Ms Irwin further suggested that there would be a greater supply of domestic trained nurses if the Government had provided more training places and made nursing more attractive by offering higher salaries and better employment conditions 10 to 15 years ago (Q 299).

112.  The NFU said that wages in agriculture are significantly lower than in other sectors and that "migrants perform tasks, at rates of pay, which most domestic workers would be unwilling to work at" (p 100). This last comment illustrates a key issue, namely, that employers' expressed "need" for immigrant labour is often a demand for labour that can be employed at current rates of pay, rather than at higher wages that are generally necessary to attract labour in a competitive market.

113.  Immigration keeps labour costs lower than they would be without immigrants. These lower labour costs also benefit consumers, who then pay less than they otherwise would for products and services (including public services) produced or provided by immigrants.

114.  A number of witnesses argued that raising wages for workers employed to provide services in or for the public sector is severely limited by cost pressures in the public sector. Lesley Rimmer of the UK Home Care Association told us that "two thirds of employers say it is difficult or impossible to recruit locally at current rates of pay and these pay rates are primarily a reflection of what councils are willing to pay since they make up 80% of the purchasers of care services" (Q 300). Dr Anderson argued that increasing wages to attract local workers would require a reform of the UK's social care system. "If there were no immigration, there really would have to be a big re-think about how social care and care of the elderly was organized; really big, back-to-first premises" (Q 30).

115.  Dr Borman of the BMA explained how the UK public health sector benefits from the employment of immigrant doctors. He said: "Migrants are carrying their primary qualifications and their expertise to the United Kingdom effectively for free. It costs in the order of … a quarter of a million pounds to qualify a doctor within the United Kingdom medical school system and clearly, having a doctor who has qualified abroad, bringing those qualifications means a net gain to the United Kingdom" (Q 300). Making a similar point, Ms Irwin of the Royal College of Nursing suggested in her evidence on the employment of foreign nurses in the UK that "in general terms, the employment of migrants is a deliberate policy choice to employ a workforce at a lower cost" (Q 294).

116.  It is clear that various low-wage sectors of the UK economy (in both private and public sectors) are currently heavily dependent on immigrant labour. Increasing wages to attract more British workers to produce or provide a certain product or service can be expected to lead to an increase in the price and thus affect consumers of that product or service. In the public sector, higher labour costs could result in higher taxes and/or require a restructuring of the way in which some services such as social care are provided. Nevertheless, the fundamental point remains that labour demand, supply and thus the existence and size of labour shortages critically depend on wages—the price of labour. Arguments about the "need" for migrant labour that ignore price adjustments are meaningless and misleading.

117.  Increasing wages is only one among various potential alternatives to immigration for responding to perceived labour shortages. The list of potential options for employers includes:

  • increasing wages and/or improving working conditions to attract more local workers who are either inactive, unemployed, or employed in other sectors;
  • changing the production process to make it less labour-intensive, for example, increasing the capital and/or technology intensity;
  • relocating to countries where labour costs are lower;
  • switching to production (provision) of less labour-intensive commodities and services;
  • employing immigrant workers.

118.  Although not all of these options will be technically feasible for all employers—for instance, the work of waiters in the hospitality sector cannot be off-shored—many employers will face a number of options. An employer's decision on how to respond to a perceived labour shortage will naturally depend on the relative costs of each of the alternatives. Just as immigration may discourage employers, including those in the public sector, from raising wages and investing in training and skill development of the domestic workforce (see the discussion in chapter 3), the ready access to cheap migrant labour may reduce employers' incentives to consider other options, in particular changing production methods.

119.  Professor Chiswick noted that, if there were fewer low-skilled workers in the harvesting of field crops: "Farm managers would pay higher wages to attract native-born workers and this would speed up the mechanization of the harvesting of field crops. The technology is there, but with low wages for farm labourers there is little economic incentive for the growers to mechanize or invest in other types of new technology" (p 425). This was precisely the experience of the US tomato-processing industry where growers argued that the industry could not do without migrants. But subsequent mechanization increased productivity and reduced prices.[54]

120.  Professor Christian Dustmann pointed out that "there is evidence that technology adjusts to the availability of labour in particular parts of the skill distribution" (Q 175). He gave the example of "the wine industry in Australia and California, which is highly labour intensive in California and highly mechanised in Australia, the reason being that it is very easy to get unskilled workers in California but not in Australia" (Q 175).

121.  Mr Ratcliffe of the Construction Confederation suggested that off-shoring certain types of production, or importing certain products, is possible in the construction industry but critically depends on the cost incentives that employers are confronted with: "... [offshoring] is quite feasible but it is a question of economics as to whether it is cheaper. Certainly in Catterick they are doing some military accommodation up there and all the bathrooms are simply transported in, having been made in factory, so certainly one of the responses to skills shortages will be more off-site prefabrication; it is an idea which is catching on quite nicely in the industry" (Q 143).

122.  We recognise that many public and private enterprises currently rely upon immigrants—from the NHS to City institutions, from the construction industry to residential care. We do not doubt the great value of this workforce from overseas to UK businesses and public services. Nevertheless, the argument that sustained net immigration is needed to fill vacancies, and that immigrants do the jobs that locals cannot or will not do, is fundamentally flawed. It ignores the potential alternatives to immigration for responding to labour shortages, including the price adjustments of a competitive labour market and the associated increase in local labour supply that can be expected to occur in the absence of immigration. Each of the alternative ways of responding to labour shortages involves its own economic costs and benefits. Rather than deducing a need for immigrant labour from the existence of vacancies in the economy, the discussion about how to respond to labour shortages should be based on analysis of the feasibility and net benefits to the resident population from the various alternatives including immigration.

123.  Immigration encouraged as a "quick fix" in response to perceived labour and skills shortages reduces employers' incentives to consider and invest in alternatives. It will also reduce domestic workers' incentives to acquire the training and skills necessary to do certain jobs. Consequently, immigration designed to address short term shortages may have the unintended consequence of creating the conditions that encourage shortages of local workers in the longer term.

124.  We recognise that there is a case for enabling employers to hire significant numbers of highly-skilled foreign workers. But whether this implies net immigration is an issue to which we return later.


49   Dench, S., Hurstfield, J., Hill, D., and K. Akroyd. 2006. Employers' use of migrant labour Home Office Online Reports. 03/06 and 04/06 Back

50   Ernst & Young ITEM Club Special Report: op.cit. Back

51   Matthews, G. and M. Ruhs (2007) "The micro-foundations of labour shortages: Deconstructing employer demand for migrant labour in the UK's hospitality sector", COMPAS Working Paper, www.compas.ox.ac.uk Anderson, B. (2007) A very private business: exploring the demand for migrant domestic workers, European Journal of Women's Studies (14) 3 Back

52   Anderson et al 2006 Waldinger, R. and Lichter, M. 2003. How the Other Half Works: Immigration and the Social Organization of Labour. London, U.K.: University of California Press Ltd. Back

53   Ernst & Young ITEM Club Special Report: op.cit. Back

54   Martin, P. et al (2006) Managing Labor Migration in the Twenty-first Century, Yale University Press, New Haven, p. 126-127 Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Lords home page Parliament home page House of Commons home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2008