Memorandum by Open Europe
1. What should be the Objectives of the EU's
Structural Funds? How can the Funds become more effective in supporting
public policies in Member States and regions? What mechanisms
of delivery could make the policy more performance-based and more
user-friendly?
1.1 For the Structural and Cohesion Funds
(SCF) to become more effective in supporting public policy, at
least five major reforms need to take place:
(iii) Better project selection to focus
on genuinely growth and employment enhancing programmes.
(iv) Better coordination with, and less
constraints on, national policies.
(v) Stronger systems to reduce fraud and
mismanagement.
1.2 We argue that these flaws predominantly
stem from the very involvement of the EU in regional policy in
the first place, and will be very hard to fix through micro-reforms.
Rather, we suggest the complete repatriation of regional policy
to the UK. We also suggest that all Member States should have
the option to opt out of the SCF.
1.3 First, the poor targeting (both in
terms of projects and areas) has its roots in the EU's budget
negotiations themselves. Historically and today still, the evidence
suggests that the SCF are treated more as "political sweetener"
than a development tool. The influential Sapir report for the
Commission rightly argued that,
"National political constraints mean
that each government worries more about being able to flag a negotiation
success (ie obtaining a significant share of EU money to be spent
in its own territory) than about being sure that money is spent
on worthwhile projects, let alone those fostering convergence
in the EU as a whole".[1]
1.4 Likewise, as often pointed out in
academic literature, the classic EU horse-trading often makes
the SCF function as a "side-payment", as with the so-called
"Integrated Mediterranean Programme" from which Greece
was promised some 2 billion, in return for its vote on the
accession of Portugal and Spain.[2]
The Cohesion Funds was likewise set up to "compensate"
for the forthcoming monetary union. Hence, the SCF are not a needs-driven
policy, but more based on contingencies in negotiations. This,
in turn, paves way for arbitrary allocation processes. Should
control of regional policy be brought back to the Member States
which so choose, at the very least, the bargain-driven element
of the SCF would be become less significant.
1.5 The poor targeting is also tied to
EU-specific rules on the rate of spending. The European Court
of Auditors (ECA), amongst others, has pointed to problems with
the Commission's N+2 rule. The rule means that the commitment
by the member states to spend the allocated funds must lead to
payments within two years of being entered into the budget or
the money will be cancelled. The objective behind the rule is
to prevent unused funds from storing up and ensuring that the
spending is well planned. However, the ECA argues, it provides
a tremendous incentive for the member states to spend where the
money can be quickly absorbed, rather than where it can lead to
long-term and sustainable gains.
1.6 An ECA report concluded that for
the 2000-06 financial period, "budgetary allocations were
determined less by a well established development strategy and
the effectiveness of the Structural Funds than by maximising likely
take-up of funding".[3]
It found several instances where money had been reshuffled from
projects that were deemed effective and deserving, to projects
that simply could absorb the funds.
1.7 A better solutionwhich would
make the delivery of the SCF substantially more result-basedwould
be to leave governments free to choose the investment project
to be financed by EU transfers, but oblige them to declare beforehand
the expected results of the project. Disbursement of the funds
could then be made in lump sums, and would depend upon reaching
these resultsrather than ability to spend. This is essentially
the solution the Sapir-report and others have suggested. However,
from such a system there is a relatively small step to bringing
back regional policy to the national level altogether.
1.8 Moreover, if the SCF truly are to
add value to domestic policy, the heavy bureaucracy of the SCF
must be downsized and the deadweight loss drastically reduced.
The cumbersome bureaucracy involved in the SCF is universally
acknowledged.[4]
1.9 On the EU level, substantial resources
are spent on administration and overlapping committees. For example,
the Committee of the Regions (CoR), costing some 140 million
a year; some 70 million is spent under the label "Working
in Europe: Social dialogue and mobility" and another 120
million on "Employment, social solidarity and gender equality".
There is also the Assembly of the European Regions. Also the EU's
Economic and Social Committee, costing some 120 million
a year, has a specific unit for the SCF. It is far from clear
what all these committees and groups actually achieve. All in
addition to the admin costs involved in DG Regio.[5]
1.10 On the national level, there are
no less than seven different Whitehall departments involved in
the SCFthe DWP, BERR, Treasury, DEFRA, CLG, DFT and DCMS.
For the DWP, the yearly administrative cost involved in the ESF
is reported at £10 million.[6]
For the other departments, such figures have not been possible
to obtain but could well be of the same magnitude.
1.11 On top of this the regional tier
adds substantial costs. An evaluation of the Peace 2 programme
in Northern Ireland concluded that out of the £641.2 million
that was allocated for the programme, £57.1 millionor
11%was absorbed by administration.[7]
A report from the Scottish Parliament put the annual figure for
administering the SCF in Scotland at £30.9 million, equivalent
to 10% of the funds allocated.[8]
1.12 The English GOs and RDAs (and at
present regional assemblies) cost £366 million to administer.
It has not been possible to distinguish between the administrative
costs created by the SCF and other spending. Nor would it be possible
to get rid of the regional tier while the EU's current spending
framework stays in place. Regardless, it is clear that also at
the regional level, the bureaucratic cost is high.
Region
|
Admin cost,
RDA |
Overseas
spending, RDA
| Admin cost,
Government Office
for Region
| Grants,
Regional
Assembly |
Total |
North East | 22,607
| 836 | 13,055 |
2,073 | 38,571 |
North West | 38,144
| 577 | 17,400 |
3,045 | 59,166 |
Yorks & Humber | 19,290
| 606 | 13,286 |
2,339 | 35,521 |
West Midlands | 20,000
| 1,056 | 14,972
| 2,518 | 38,546
|
East Midlands | 16,000
| 375 | 11,496 |
2,507 | 30,377 |
East | 10,900 |
180 | 12,672 | 2,469
| 26,221 |
South West | 19,290
| 672 | 14,766 |
2,470 | 37,198 |
South East | 21,222
| 443 | 14,095 |
3,771 | 39,531 |
London | 29,500
| | 17,881 | 65(admin)
| 112,381 |
Total | 166,063
| 4,745 | 129,624
| 21,436[9]
| 366,868 |
Sources: GLA, Greater London Authority Consolidated Budget 2006-07, February 2006, p 9; Hansard, 19 July 2007, Column 494W; Hansard, 22 May 2006, Column 1460W; Hansard 10 May 2006, Column 376WA onwards; Hansard, 11 January 2007, Column 738WA.
| | | |
| |
| | |
| | |
1.13 The combined SCF-related administrative costs
of the EU, national and regional policies suggests that even while
spending the same amount of money on regional/regeneration policies
as at present, it would be possible to save hundreds of millions
in administrative costs by sweeping away the costly bureaucracy
necessitated by the EU's regional policies.
1.14 Beyond this, cutting out the EU-level would presumably
lead to significant savings also for recipients, given that the
EU's bureaucracy and regulations, almost universally, are perceived
as more cumbersome than its national counterparts.[10]
1.15 Again, as widely acknowledged, the EU's regulations
are today overdone and too inflexible to accommodate the specific
needs of 27 countries and hundreds of regionsat different
stages of their development. Something that is made worse by the
lack of "opt-outs" for smaller-sized projects, or projects
with special needs. The requirement to keep records for 12 years,
regardless of project size, is a case in point. As has been noted
elsewhere, it seems odd that a small café offering intermediate
job opportunities for the mentally ill should be under the same
accounting rules as a multi-million pound infrastructure project.[11]
1.16 The obvious risk is that the cost of both the
extra bureaucracy and regulations are passed down to the stakeholders
at the bottom of the chain, hitting smaller players that have
a much harder time to absorb the costs, ie small or struggling
firms and community or voluntary organisations. There are examples
of small projects that drown in this paper work, such as a training
organisation funded by the ESF with only 12 trainers that had
to employ five support staff in order to fulfill all the administrative
requirements of the SCF.[12]
This runs completely contrary to the supposed aim of the SCF,
in as far as the policy is meant to encourage local initiatives
and subsidiarity.
1.17 The entire structure of administrative control
and audit seems to be both disproportionate to the small amount
of funds given and out of touch with economic reality. As a DTI/ODPM
report pointed out, there is little evidence that the rigorous
regulations have actually led to better and more efficient spending.[13]
It would of course make sense to create a system of opt-outs for
smaller actors, and regulate with more attention paid to specific,
local needssuch as including social housing among the eligible
funding activities.
1.18 However, notwithstanding some flexibility for
the UK in 2007-2013 in terms of reporting requirements, British
proposals to simplify and streamline the regulations seem often
to conflict with the Commission's ideas and rules. For example,
a type of fast-track procedure for projects of less than £50,000which
would make life a lot easier for smaller playersdid not
comply with the Commission's rules on open and competitive tendering.
Similarly, the UK attempted to drop the requirement to keep records
for 12 years, but was found to be in breach of EU-regulations.[14]
Gordon Brown has acknowledged that, "There are many things
that we want to do to encourage local skills and research and
development, and local businesses, but we're not able to do because
of the existing rules".[15]
1.19 All of this seems to support the conclusion that
the best way for the SCF to support public policy in the UK is
through the complete repatriation of the funds.
1.20 In addition, corruption and mismanagement remain
at large, undermining sound public spending and policy. The ECA
found that at least 4 billion euros of the money that the EU Commission
handed out in 2006 "should not have been". Of the projects
the ECA audited, only 31% "were found to be free from error".
The ECA warned that there was a "high risk" that the
project costs were "overstated" and that there were
large numbers of claims for "ineligible expenditure."
The report stated that there was generally "a lack of evidence
to support the calculation of overheads or the staff costs involved".[16]
1.21 But the ECA usually only monitor some 90 projects,
and the Commission only audits 5% of the projects given money.
Its figures could well be underestimates. For example, Italy's
tax and fraud investigator, Guardia di Finanza, noted in its latest
annual report that 433 million worth of EU money was subject
to outright fraud in Italy alone in 2006.[17]
1.22 As the ECA also has pointed out[18],
the SCF are particularly prone to errors, due to the set-up. There
are several reasons for this:
(i) The large number of programmes and projects which
are implemented over several years.
(ii) The large number of eligibility conditions which
are hard to follow and sometimes open to divergent interpretations.
(iii) The variety of entities and actors which for
different reasons intervene in the management process.
(iv) The large number of diverging countries and regions
subject to the same centralised regulations.
1.23 These are all issues relating to the scale and
complexity of the SCF. By bringing back regional policy to the
national level, the number of instances where fraud and mismanagement
could take place would radically decrease. And the spending would
be easier to audit.
2. Do Structural Funds meet the principle of subsidiarity?
Could the same cohesion objectives be met through repatriation
of these funds?
2.1 The complex regulatory culture of the SCF can undermine
both localised, small-scale projects (see above), as well as the
ability of regional and local authorities to channel money to
where the needs are and where the funds can do most good.
2.2 A well-known example is that the SCF cannot be used
for schooling or social housing projectsparadoxically as
this was initially seen as breaching precisely the subsidiary
principle. Stephens (1999) has noted that "Arguably, the
current asymmetry between allowing European funds to be used to
attract physical capital, but excluding housing as a key aspect
of enhancing human capital, is itself a breach of subsidiarity."[19]
2.3 An obvious example is Cornwallthe only region
in the UK that will receive Objective One funding throughout the
2007-13 financial perspective. One of the main problems in Cornwall
is of course the disproportionately high property prices, due
to the number of houses sold as second homes to wealthy outsiders
(estimates varysome argue levels are as high as up to 50%
in some districts). In some areas the average house price is 17
times the average annual income in the regionwhile average
income, in turn, is 25% below the national average. As a consequence,
Cornwall has seen what MP Matthew Taylor calls a "shocking"
rise in the number of people seeking social housing.[20]
2.4 In this scenario it would be sensible to at least
have the flexibility to direct structural funds money towards
social housingas that is clearly a need on the ground.
2.5 Conversely, while it is clear that EU management
of the structural funds prevents the UK Government from doing
things it wants to do, it is difficult to argue that the EU's
involvement in running UK regional policies allows anything to
happen which could not be achieved by the UK Government. It is
clear that EU management of UK regional policy is a violation
of the subsidiarity principle.
3. What impact has the enlargement had on Structural Funds,
and are any changes necessary to meet the challenges of further
enlargement?
3.1 One of the more apparent effects is that the SCF
since enlargement have become bigger and therefore even harder
to manage and audit.
3.2 As for the UK, the significance of the SCF has obviously
decreased due to the "statistical effect". For the UK
as a whole, the annual allocation of the structural funds will
amount to about 0.1 -0.15% of national GDP for the 2007-13 financial
perspective. Across the regions, the share of GDP varies between
approximately 0.2% (Northern Ireland) and 0.02% (South East).[21]
This is of course not enough to have any significant macro-economic
effect. Despite the further decreased significance of EU funds,
the complex regulations and the bureaucratic structure will stay
in place, and hence so will the limitations on how the UK can
run its regional policy.
3.3 In an enlarged Union, it therefore makes even less
sense for the EU-15particularly countries such as the UKto
be enrolled in the SCF. Allowing for the option of opting out
of the policy, could be a major step towards focussing the SCF
on the MS and regions that actually are in most needas
well as sizing down the programme and thus making it more manageable.
In addition, the targeting of the SCF must be radically improved
(see above and below) if the SCF are going to have a real impact
on growth and jobs in the EU-27 and beyond.
4. What criteria should guide the decisions on the proportion
of the EU budget to be allocated to Structural Funds?
4.1 The key is to move away from bargain-driven deals
and towards development-focussed strategies. As long as the richer
MS are in the game, political domestic constraints will inevitably
force them to strike deals, and the budget will continue to balloon,
without the funds necessarily having their desired effect. Both
for the purpose of fiscal discipline and better targeting of funds,
the UK Government's proposal to have all MS with a GDP above 90%
of the EU average managing and paying for their own regional policy,
should be one of the main criteria for deciding how much money
to inject into the SCF. If this indeed is the main criteria, the
EU's overall regional budget could be cut by as much as 48% (given
that 48% of the funds were allocated to the EU-15 for the 2007-13
period).[22]
4.2 There must also be an honest discussion about the
SCF's track record. As with the CAP, the failed aspects of the
SCF cannot be allowed to simply stay in place. For example, the
absence of evidence in support of the SCF's added value must be
considered also in the budget negotiations.[23]
Where MS consider the value added to be absent, funds should not
be allocated.
4.3 In addition, focus must be put on impact. While it
is widely agreed that the evidence is inconclusive as to the precise
effectiveness of the SCFand that the counterfactual is
virtually impossible to determineseveral indicators seem
to suggest that the SCF are simply not delivering where they should.
Most generally, convergence between regions is simply not happening.
4.4 A recent OECD report noted that regional disparities
in Europe are not falling, or at best are declining very slowly.
At the current rate of convergence, the report stated, it would
take 170 years to halve divergence across the regions in the EU.[24]
The report argued that this should put a big question mark next
to the SCF.
Source: OECD 2007.
4.5 A paper by Gardiner et al concludes that both
when looking at regional GDP per capita and regional productivity,
regional convergence in the EU is at best a slow process of only
1-2% per annum. Meaningful convergence would take decades to achieve.[25]

Source: Gardiner et al 2004.
4.6 And as the Sapir report has argued, the available
empirical data on economic convergence in the EU gives a very
different picture depending on whether one looks at the Member
States, or its NUTS 1 regions across the Union.[26]
Although convergence of GDP per capita has taken place between
member states, inequality within each country accounted for roughly
half of total EU regional inequality in the early 1980s, but this
rose to about two thirds by the mid-1990s (while inequality between
countries fell by about a third during that period).
4.7 Even the Commission's report admits the continuing
divergence across the regions (in passing), stating that "in
spite of progress, absolute disparities remain large. This is
partly as a result of recent enlargement and partly as growth
tends to concentrateduring the initial phases of developmentin
the most dynamic areas within countries".[27]
4.8 Elsewhere, the report also points out that in the
period 2000-04, real GDP per head fell in 27 regions and in 24
regions it grew by less than 0.5% a year. In five regions, GDP
per head slipped below 75% of the EU average.
4.9 The Commission seems to argue that such discrepancies
reflect different stages of development and will naturally disappear
in due course. However, first, as we saw, convergence is very
slow170 years to halve welfare gaps can hardly be an acceptable
rate. Secondly, Objective One regionsthose with an average
GDP under 75% of the EU averagehave remained remarkably
stable. Of the 44 regions originally granted Objective One status
in 1989, 43 were still eligible for such funding in 2003.
4.10 Meanwhile, households in the EU's poorer regions
have increased their dependency on grants and social transfers
for their disposable income.[28]
4.11 In the UK, when comparing EU funding with the GVA
per indices there seems to be little evidence that the structural
funds have had a net effect on wealth and job creation. If the
structural funds were efficient, we would expect to detect some
sort of boost in a regions' GVA as EU funding increases. This
is not the case, however. Although not a hugely meaningful comparison,
it still undermines the Commission's case, as the very idea behind
the SCF is to raise GVA per head, as poorer regions are granted
aid precisely on the basis of their low levels of GVA per capita
relative to the EU average.
4.12 Also more meaningful measures show that economic
opportunities remain unevenly spread across the UK, and are unaffected
by the SCF. The one-fifth of the UK's population that live in
the poorest local areas still only accounts for about 13% of national
incomewith few signs of any significant upward mobility
taking place in the last decade.[29]
North East[30] Wales

Sources: ONS 2005; DTI/BERR allocation of the structural
funds, 89-93, 94-99, 2000-06.
4.13 Like in the case of value added, if there is no
solid evidence that the SCF lead to convergenceevidence
usually tend to tip the other waynor any measurable impact
of funds, what is the justification for continuing with the programme
in its current size and shapeparticularly with the deadweight
losses in mind. These are all issues that have to inform the decision
on how much money to allocate to the regional budget post-2013.
5. Are the current eligibility tests for regions to receive
support under the EU's Structural Funds relevant, fair and appropriate?
Should they remain in place after 2013? Is it appropriate that
they are discussed simultaneously with wider agreements on allocating
EU budget spending?
5.1 First, the EU's criterion for special status regions75%
of average EU GDPis outdated. It may have made sense when
the regions were either well above or well below the threshold.
Since enlargement, however, the regions are now much more evenly
scattered, with several areas being around the threshold. This
opens up for regions with similar wealth levels, receiving very
different amounts of funding.
5.2 Secondly, the Commission's preferred measure for
wealththe Gross Value Added (GVA) measureis open
to substantial criticism.[31]
GVA measures the contribution to the economy of each individual
producer, industry or sector. GDP is derived from GVA by adding
taxes and subtracting subsidies on products.[32]
Essentially, GVA measures output divided by population.[33]
5.3 However, as often noted, since GVA does not take
commuting into account, it tends to produce an upwards bias for
regions that have large levels of inward commuting, and vice versa.
Thus, for example allocation of Objective One (now Convergence)
spending can be distorted by the fact that some NUTS 2 regions,
for example, are urban areas or cities (ie Hamburg, Bremen or
even Inner and Outer London), whereas others are coastal or rural
areas. The urban areas naturally have higher GVA per head, due
to concentration of financial and business services, more value-added
activities and so forth. Areas with a large share of inwards commuters
will have artificially high GVA per head. The reverse is then
true for areas where commuters tend to live. Some estimates put
the Greater London's upwards bias in the GVA calculation in the
area of 15%.[34]
5.4 This is precisely the case with the infamous example
of Lüneburg outside Hamburg, Germany. The district serves
as residential area for Hamburg's professionals, and is considered
one of the wealthiest commuting areas in Germany, growing by 2,000
residents each year. However, since GVA focuses on workplace,
the high income of Lüneburg's residents counts towards Hamburg
wealth statistics.[35]
Consequently, Eurostat has identified Lüneburg as an Objective
One region, marginally poorer than Merseyside. Lüneburg was
granted a staggering 900 million from the SCF for the 2000-06
periodonly slightly less than what was given to Merseyside
for the same time period. This, of course, adds to the criticism
of the insufficient targeting of the SCF.
5.5 In addition, GVA does not adequately account for
demographic trends, productivity factors and population structure.
Neither does it reflect lifestyle choices. For instance, an area
that has a large number of pensioners, students or part-time workers
will have low GVA per head since that type of income is omitted
in the GVA measure. This, without the area necessarily experiencing
a shortage of economic opportunities.[36]
Many have pointed to Cornwall and Cumbria as being on opposite
ends of this problem.
5.6. The ONS' recommendation for measuring regional prosperity
and hence for deciding how to allocate the SCF, strike us as fairer,
more appropriate and more relevant:
(a) regional GVA per full-time employee, which they argue
is the best way to measure regional differences in productivity
as it is not affected by the number of non-working residents;
and
(b) regional gross household disposable income, which
indicates the prosperity of residents.[37]
5.7 But even beyond the measure per se, the appropriateness
of the EU's distinctly region-based funding system is questionable.
Due to the set-up, the SCF often fail to target smaller pockets
of poverty that can exist within a region. The flip side is that
more affluent areas can end up with substantial amounts of money
for no apparent reason.
5.8 This is a major shortcoming in a country such as
the UK, where local pockets of poverty often exist within affluent
larger areas. In urban areas, for example, discrepancies can come
down to as small units as a block of council estates. The SCF
are way too inflexible to address such gaps. This problem is also
exacerbated by what many observers consider the artificial nature
of the UK's regions.
5.9 The South East is a good case study. In 2004, the
South East was the 13th wealthiest region in the EU[38]
with a household disposable income 12% above the national average.
The region was unsurprisingly given Objective Three statuswhich
reflected its wealth levelsand was granted close to £300
million for the 2000-06 financial perspective.[39]
5.10 However, within the South East there are smaller
economically deprived areas such as Hastings, where 27% of all
children come from families living on out of work benefits.[40]
This and other indicators make it one of the poorest areas in
England. But Hastings is situated within the NUTS 3 region of
East Sussex, which has a GDHI above the national average. NUTS
3 is the smallest unit in the EU's classification system. Consequently
Hastings is completely omitted. For the 2000-06 financial period,
it has only been given ESF grants worth £1.1 million. This
translates into 0.4% of the total ESF amount given to the South
East.[41]
5.11 Likewise, some parts of Thanet belong to the 1%
of the most deprived areas in the UK.[42]
Its NUTS 3 region, however, is Kent, whose GDHI is above the national
average. Thanet received some £1.8 million from the ESF over
a six year period. Although both towns get substantially more
money from the ERDF, it still seems rather odd that they would
end up with so little money from the ESF.
5.12 In comparison, Canterburya wealthy area by
all measureshas been given some £2.6 million from
the ESF.
5.13 Examples like these seem to suggest that a substantial
share of the SCF ends up with projects and individuals that, comparatively
speaking, are not in need of the money, and that the reverse is
true.
5.14 We used the ACORN system for UK postcodeswhich
categorises the UK population according to income, lifestyle choices
and a whole range of demographic statisticsto get an idea
of where the SCF actually end up. In the South East, we found
that postcode areas whose populations are classified as "wealthy
achievers" received 5.5% of the funds. The upper half of
the population, from the "wealthy achievers" to "secure
families" in the "comfortably off" category got
almost 30% of the money granted. Only 10% of the funds had gone
to the bottom one fifth of households that fall under the category
"hard pressed". For the upper categories, we excluded
grants that have been given to councils under general headlines,
as opposed to specific projects. It is fair to assume that lump
sums given to councils could be redistributed elsewhere.
5.15 As said, one of the major problems with evaluating
the SCF is the poor quality of the available data. The South East
is the only region that provides detailed information on where
its SCF money has gone in terms of smaller units. In virtually
every other region, data is only available for the NUTS 2 levelat
best. As discussed, this is not very useful if we want to investigate
whether the funds in reality are targeted at areas where they
can do most good.
5.16 If we assume that the South East is indicative for
the UK as a whole and using the SCF allocated to the UK for the
2000-06 financial period, which is around £10 billion, more
than £3 billion has gone to the "top" 50% of the
population in terms of wealth. The wealthiest 20% have received
about £550 million from the SCF. Meanwhile, as little as
£1 billion has gone to the bottom 20% of the UK's population.
Even assuming that all the grants that have been given to Councils
in the wealthiest areas have been redistributed to the bottom
20% (something that seem very unlikely), the bottom one fifth
has still only been granted £3 billion out of the allocated
£10 billion.
5.17 This is a very rough estimate, but it does give
an idea of how off target and unfair the SCF can be. Furthermore,
it provides a strong argument as to why the EU's criteria and
region-based spending structure should not stay in place after
2013.
5.18 As the flaws are so fundamental and cut to the very
heart of the distribution/impact of the SCF, it seems highly appropriate
to consider them simultaneously with the wider discussions on
spending allocation.
6. What would be the effect of linking the availability
of the Structural Funds with compliance to Broad Economic Policy
Guidelines?
6.1 It would not be appropriate for member states which
are not members of the euro to face financial penalties (in the
form of lost structural funding) for non compliance with the Broad
Economic Policy Guidelines.
6.2 The euro member states, where macroeconomic policy
is arguably a matter of greater mutual concern, already have in
place rules on fiscal policy in the form of the stability and
growth pact. Creating a parallel process to enforce the BEPG would
be likely to create confusion.
9 January 2008
http://www.communities.gov.uk/communities/neighbourhoodrenewal/deprivation/deprivation07/
1
Sapir et al "An Agenda for a Growing Europe; making the EU
Economic System Deliver", July 2003. Back
2
Allen, "Cohesion and the Structural Funds: Competing Pressures
for Reform?" in Wallace, Wallace and Pollack Policy-Making
in the European Union, 2005. Back
3
European Court of Auditors, "Special Report No 1/2007,
concerning the implementation of the mid-term processes on the
Structural Funds 2000-06", 5 June 2007. Back
4
For the administrative burden of the SCF, see: "`London's
Perspective'-Consultation on the future of EU Structural Funds
post-2006", London Partners, House of Commons, May
2006, 2003; Hansard, 17 June 2004 : Column 275WH; DTI/ODPM,
"Evaluation of the Added Value and Costs of the European
Structural Funds in the UK", November 2003; Bachtler, John
& Taylo, Sandra, European Policies Research Centre,
"The Added Value of the Structural Funds: A Regional Perspective",
June 2003. Back
5
Ibid. Back
6
House of Commons Work and Pensions Committee, "European
Social Fund", Sixth Report of Session 2002-03 Volume I. Back
7
PA, 10 September 2007. Back
8
Scottish Parliament, European and External Relations Committee
Official Report 6 June 2006. Back
9
Figure include £244,000 for the English Regions Network. Back
10
A report for the DTI and the ODPM found that 60-65% of SCF stakeholders
thought that more or significantly more resources were required
to implement and apply for SCF programmes, when compared to UK
domestic programmes. Only 5% found the EU easier to deal with.
(DTI/ODPM 2003). Back
11
Hansard, 17 June 2004 : Column 275WH. Back
12
Ibid. Back
13
DTI/ODPM, "Evaluation of the Added Value and Costs
of the European Structural Funds in the UK", November 2003. Back
14
Hansard, 17 June 2004 : Column 275WH. Back
15
BBC, 6 March 2003. Back
16
European Report, 10 July 2007. Back
17
Spiegel Online, 22 March 2007. Back
18
European Court of Auditors, "Special Report No 1/2007,
concerning the implementation of the mid-term processes on the
Structural Funds 2000-06", 5 June 2007. Back
19
Quoted in "The EU budget: a historic missed opportunity,
Open Europe, 20 December 2005. Back
20
Observer, 19 November 2007. Back
21
DTI, 2007; ONS, 2007. Back
22
Inforegio 2006. Back
23
For a discussion on the lack of value added, see: HM Treasury,
"A Modern Regional Policy for the United Kingdom", March
2003; CRG Research, Cardiff University & Fitzpatrick
Associates, "Mid-term Evaluation of the Objective 1 Programme
for West Wales and the Valleys", September 2003; Jan Shury
et al". A quantitative survey of companies supported by European
Social Fund Objective 3", Department for Work and Pensions,
Research Report No 361; Sapir et al "An Agenda for a Growing
Europe; making the EU Economic System Deliver", July 2003. Back
24
OECD, "Economic survey of the European Union 2007:
Making the most of regional cohesion policy", 20 September
2007. Back
25
Gardiner et al, "Competitiveness, Productivity and Economic
Growth across the European Regions", Regional Studies,
December 2004. Back
26
Sapir et al, "An Agenda for a growing Europe: Making the
EU Economic System Deliver", Report of an Independent High-Level
Study Group established on the initiative of the President of
the European Commission. Back
27
European Commission, Fourth Report on Economic and Social
Cohesion, 5 May, 2007. Back
28
Eurostat, Private household income in the European Union
regions, 2003, 25/2007. Back
29
Financial Times, 15 December 2007. Back
30
The tables compare GVA per head indices to the allocated SCF per
head for the North East and Wales regions between 1989 and 2005.
For the North East, SCF doubled during the period while GVA per
head dropped 6% compared to the UK average. In Wales, funding
increased by close to 16%, while GVA fell by 7%. The trend recurs
in Yorkshire, where funding almost doubled during the time period
while the GVA dropped by some 4%. Back
31
House of Commons/ODPM, 2003b; Gripaios & Paul Bishop, "Objective
One Funding in the UK: A Critical Assessment", Regional
Studies, November 2006. Back
32
CLG, Technical note accompanying the Public Service Agreement,
2002. Back
33
Reasons given for using GVA rather than, say, GDP per capita combined
with other measures, are, amongst other factors, that the former
is internationally comparable and may also be less susceptible
to political manipulation. Since it is a single measure, it cannot
be manipulated through shifting the weights of the various measures. Back
34
Roberts 2004. Back
35
Daily Telegraph, "600m EU aid for Germany's thriving
`fat belt' commuters", 21 June 2007. Back
36
Gripaios & Paul Bishop, "Objective One Funding in the
UK: A Critical Assessment", Regional Studies, November
2006. Back
37
House of Commons/ODPM, 2003. Back
38
According to the GVA measure. Back
39
DTI/BERR, UK Structural Funds Allocations 2000-06. Back
40
End Child Poverty, 2007. Available at http://www.ecpc.org.uk/south-east.html. Back
41
South East Government Office 2007, List of all projects
by post code and ESF value. Back
42
DWP, Indices of Multiple Deprivation 2007. Available at Back
|