The Barnett Formula - Select Committee on the Barnett Formula Contents


CHAPTER 5: IS REFORM NECESSARY?

49.  There was general agreement among most of our witnesses that the Barnett Formula is no longer an appropriate mechanism to allocate funds to the devolved administrations. Only a minority of witnesses argued for the Formula to be retained. The Treasury told us that they considered the Barnett Formula to be effective and appropriate and they had no plans to consider any alternatives (QQ 413-423). The Chief Secretary to the Treasury described the Formula as "fair enough" (QQ 979, 982, 984, 988, 992-4). John Swinney MSP, Cabinet Secretary for Finance and Sustainable Growth in the Scottish Executive, argued for retaining the current Formula but only unless or until there was further reform of the devolution settlement to include fiscal autonomy (Q 226).[41] Professor Arthur Midwinter, in a submission to the Calman Commission, highlighted the importance of stability, predictability, political acceptability and simplicity.[42]

50.  The Barnett Formula has several important advantages: it is simple, stable and not pre-committed; allowing freedom of choice to the devolved authorities as to how the grant is spent. There have been improvements in the transparency of the Formula and its application, prompted in part by devolution in the late 1990s,[43] but the price of that has been reduced flexibility in funding the devolved administrations. We have found that the way in which the Formula has been administered in the past is opaque and subjective.[44]

51.  If the existing Formula is to be replaced or reformed, any alternative must represent an improvement on the current system. The advantages of the Barnett Formula—simplicity, stability and the absence of ring-fencing—are important and should be maintained whatever the future method of allocating funds to the devolved administrations.

52.  Although the advantages of the Formula are clear, the disadvantages call into question whether the Formula is an adequate mechanism to allocate funding to the devolved administrations. Whilst most witnesses conceded that the present system was relatively quick and easy for the Treasury to administer, only a minority thought that it could be justified in terms of fairness (Q 979).

THE BASELINE

53.  The most serious criticism of the current basis of funding is that, whilst the core allocation (the baseline) has been built upon since the Formula was first applied, it has never been reviewed. "The Formula does not determine the overall sizes of budgets (these are based on past allocations and decisions) … any perceived inequity is due to the historical levels of funding since these are by their very nature 'locked-in' the system" (p 351). "Baseline expenditures to which 'consequential' increases were cumulatively added were based on expenditure patterns prior to 1978: indeed in the case of Scotland allocations were partly related to the Goschen formula established in the late nineteenth century" (Q 568, pp 134, 353). According to The Economic Research Institute of Northern Ireland, the core funding allocated through the Barnett Formula reflects and preserves "a myriad of past changes" (p 227). Therefore it cannot be said that the baseline reflects the needs of each devolved administration as they are today.

POPULATION EFFECTS

54.  After many years during which the population statistics were not kept up to date, population statistics are now updated every three years with the reissue of the Statement of Funding Policy. But they are applied only to the annual increment of the Formula. The underlying baseline grant (the most significant proportion of the funds allocated through the application of the Barnett Formula) is not re-examined to take account of population changes. If the populations of the four countries and regions had followed similar paths over the years, this would not have mattered very much. But as Figure 1 shows, the populations have diverged. Over the period since 1981, the populations in Wales, England and Northern Ireland have grown by some six per cent, nine per cent and 14 per cent respectively. By contrast, the Scottish population, after a period of absolute decline, is now only back at its 1981 level.

FIGURE 1
Actual and projected populations 1971 to 2031, as a percentage of the 1981 level
[45]


55.  What matters, as far as the Formula is concerned, is not whether populations grow or decline in absolute terms but how they change relative to one another. As well as showing that change of this sort has been going on for several decades, Figure 1 also shows (using projections made by the Government Actuary) that they are expected to continue to do so at least up until the 2030s. Whilst some changes took place to annual increments to reflect population statistics, the failure of the Barnett Formula to adjust the baseline to reflect this population effect is a serious weakness. Over the short time for which it was originally expected to operate, this would not have mattered. But left to run unchecked for decades, the absence of any correction mechanism has led a pattern of grant per head which is now arbitrary.

56.  The changing populations of the devolved administrations and the failure of the Formula to take account of population changes over time within the baseline create a significant problem for the Barnett Formula today. In our view, the resulting per capita allocations are arbitrary and unfair. In essence the baseline of the grant provides funds for a level of population that has changed.

The administration of the present system

OPAQUE DECISION MAKING

57.  Treasury officials argued that their decisions on the categorisation of expenditure as "England" only or "UK-wide" spend were relatively clear because they simply flowed from legislation that specified which areas were devolved and which were reserved (Q 471). However the issue is not as simple as they suggest. Under the Scotland Act 1998, all matters are devolved save those expressly excepted or reserved to Westminster (set out in Schedules 4 and 5 to the Act). For Northern Ireland, all matters are similarly devolved save those excepted or reserved (though the lists of such matters are different there, and the meaning of 'excepted' and 'reserved' is also different under the Northern Ireland Act 1998). For Wales, under the Government of Wales Act 2006, only matters expressly devolved are within the competence of the Welsh Assembly Government and National Assembly for Wales. While, in substance, many matters are devolved in each case, there are important variations in both the topic devolved and the form in which they are devolved. While some functions—such as education and health care—are devolved in each case, policing and criminal justice are devolved in Scotland but not Wales (and have yet to be devolved to Northern Ireland). These variations mean that the system is inherently complex and asymmetric.

58.  There was general agreement from all our witnesses, except the United Kingdom Government, that the application of the Formula is unclear. Some decisions, especially those relating to Formula by-pass, are taken within the Treasury with little or no consultation. Phil Jarrold of the Wales Council for Voluntary Action summed this up for us: "Our members are regularly confused, I think, by the way the Formula applies, or maybe does not apply, to individual announcements. Spending announcements are frequently silent on whether they apply to the devolved nations and whether or not there is any consequential. I do think that that lack of transparency creates problems for organisations that are trying to track these issues" (Q 624).[46]

59.  Treasury Officials argued that the dispute resolution process set out in the Statement of Funding Policy was adequate to resolve any issues arising from Treasury decisions (QQ 476-78). However, they admitted that the dispute resolution process has never been used (Q 478). It remains untested. Moreover, the fact that the dispute resolution process has never been used is not to be taken as indicative of satisfaction across the United Kingdom with the decisions made by the Treasury on grant allocations, bypass and 'consequentials'. The Committee has heard considerable disquiet in the nations and regions over the decisions taken by the Treasury (paragraphs 42-48 above). Whilst devolution legislation provides a broad framework within which administrative decisions are taken, a published set of detailed criteria by which the Treasury make decisions on how to categorise expenditure would improve transparency.

60.  On every funding decision the Treasury is judge in its own cause, including whether to bypass or include any expenditure within the application of the Barnett Formula. We recommend that before decisions are made on whether the system is bypassed or create a 'consequential' there is a clear process and open consultation with the devolved administrations.

INADEQUATE AND INACCESSIBLE DATA

61.  A further concern relates to the data available on the operation of the Formula. Despite its importance, the Treasury only publish limited data about devolved public spending, and the published official data appear in a number of places—in the Statement of Funding Policy, the Public Expenditure Statistical Estimates, and the annual reports of the Scotland and Wales Offices. Older published data do not distinguish clearly which level of government is responsible—United Kingdom or devolved—for particular spending in the breakdowns published in the Public Expenditure Statistical Estimates. There is no time series showing how expenditure has changed as a result of spending decisions made in previous years or spending reviews. It is difficult to establish comparable levels of spending in England for devolved functions as they are different in each part of the United Kingdom. At the start of our inquiry we asked the Treasury to provide data to show how the Formula has been applied to shape the grant allocations to the devolved administrations since 2003-04. We now publish this information in order to make sure that it is placed in the public domain (see pp 103-120). The Chief Secretary to the Treasury acknowledged that Treasury data could be improved and he suggested that the Committee had a role in making recommendations to that end (Q 1030).

62.  Although we acknowledge that the data on public spending have improved since 1999, we continue to be concerned that clear, thorough and readily accessible data on public spending across the United Kingdom are not yet being provided.

63.  Rather than having a multiplicity of official documents providing some data on devolved finance, we recommend that the Treasury publish their statistics of the workings of the Barnett Formula, or its successor, in a single, coherent and consistent publication. This annual publication should contain all material data on devolved finance, showing the allocations of grant to the devolved administrations, changes from previous years and explanations for any changes made. We recommend that the statistics be monitored by the UK Statistics Authority.


41   We are prevented from considering fiscal autonomy by our orders of reference. Back

42   A Midwinter written submission to the Commission on Scottish Devolution 18 March 2009 pp 30-34 available at: http://www.commissiononscottishdevolution.org.uk/engage/submissions-received.phpBack

43   See Chapter 4. Back

44   See paras 57-63. Back

45   Source: ONS population trends dataset, table 1.2. In the interests of clarity, values for the years when official estimates were not produced (those years not ending in either a 1 or a 6) have been interpolated. Back

46   See para 43-48. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Lords home page Parliament home page House of Commons home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2009