Memorandum by Dr. Kern Alexander
1. UK banking supervision and regulation
has come under intense scrutiny as a result of the credit crisis.
Before the credit crisis, UK banking supervisors and their practices
were universally esteemed and their regulatory regime of principles-based
regulation was emulated across many countries. The credit crisis,
however, has exposed major weaknesses in UK banking supervision
and regulation. It is the purpose of these written comments to
set forth the main principles of prudential bank regulation and
supervisory practice, and to comment on the weaknesses in the
UK regulatory regime which contributed to the recent financial
crisis.
BANKING AND
PRUDENTIAL REGULATION
2. The role of banks is integral to any
economy. They provide financing for commercial enterprises, access
to payment systems, and a variety of retail financial services
for the economy at large.[1]
Some large banks have a broader impact on the macro economy by
facilitating the transmission of monetary policy and making credit
and liquidity available in difficult market conditions.[2]
The integral role that banks play in the national economy is demonstrated
by the almost universal practice of states in regulating the banking
industry and providing, in many cases, a government safety net
that compensates depositors when banks fail and lender of last
resort facilities for banks when they have difficulty accessing
credit and liquidity.[3]
3. The main rationale of prudential bank regulation
has traditionally been the safety and soundness of the financial
sector and protection of depositors.[4]
A safe and sound banking system requires the effective control
of systemic risk.[5]
Systemic risk arises because banks have an incentive to underprice
financial risk because they do not incur the full social costs
of their risk-taking.[6]
The social costs of bank risk-taking can arise from the solvency
risks posed by banks because of imprudent lending and trading
activity, or from the risks posed to depositors because of inadequate
deposit insurance that can induce a bank run.[7]
Systemic risk can also arise from problems with payment and settlement
systems or from some types of financial failure that induce a
macroeconomic crisis.[8]
Prudential regulation and effective supervision therefore aim
to reduce the social costs which bank risk-taking creates by adopting
controls and incentives that induce banks to price financial risk
more efficiently.[9]
4. Prudential regulation mainly includes
capital adequacy requirements, asset composition and concentration
rules, fit and proper standards for bank officers, senior management
and board members and internal controls for bank operations. Effective
supervision involves surveillance of individual bank risk-taking
along with overall leverage levels in the financial system. It
also involves enforcement actions which can take the form of authorisation
and licence revocations and administrative penalties and civil
sanctions imposed against firms and individuals who violate regulatory
rules. Capital adequacy has attracted the most regulatory attention
in recent years because of the adoption of the Basel II international
capital adequacy standards. UK capital adequacy rules are found
in the FSA Handbook and derive through secondary legislation
from the EU Capital Requirements Directive (2006), which implements
Basel II into EU law.[10]
5. Basel II's main aim is to make bank regulatory
capital more sensitive to the economic risks which individual
banks face, while ignoring the larger social risks which bank
risk-taking poses to the financial system. Basel II permits banks
to use their own economic capital models to measure credit, market
and operational risk and to estimate lower levels of regulatory
capital than what regulatory rules would normally require. An
important weakness of Basel II is that fails to address liquidity
risk, which precipitated the present credit crisis, and allows
banks to hold lower levels of regulatory capital for assets which
banks securitise into special purpose vehicles in the wholesale
debt markets. Moreover, another weakness of Basel II is that it
is procyclical because regulatory capital calculations are based
on the riskiness of assets on the bank's balance sheets. Rather,
regulatory rules should impose counter-cyclical capital requirements,
such as higher capital charges during an asset price boom and
lower charges during a market downturn. Prior to the credit crisis,
the FSA had implemented the Capital Requirements Directive which
incorporated Basel II principles into the UK regulatory regime.
This contributed to the under-capitalisation of the UK banking
system and exposed the broader financial system to systemic and
liquidity risk that arose from excessive risk-taking in collateralised
debt obligations that originated from US subprime mortgages. The
FSA has acknowledged its mistakes in its 2008 review of its handling
of the Northern Rock collapse and has published a paper containing
liquidity risk management principles for UK banks. Despite this
progress, UK banking regulation still suffers from many of the
flaws contained in the CRD and Basel II. It is now time to amend
substantially Basel II and the CRD based on principles that recognise
the true social costs posed to the financial system by bank risk-taking.
6. In addition, effective supervision and
regulation require banks to have robust corporate governance arrangements
that incentivise bank management and owners to understand the
risks they are taking and to price risk efficiently in order to
cover both the private costs that such risk-taking poses to bank
shareholders and the social costs for the broader economy if the
bank fails.[11]
Corporate governance plays an important role in achieving this
in two ways: to align the incentives of bank owners and managers
so that managers seek wealth maximisation for owners, while not
jeopardising the bank's franchise value through excessive risk-taking;
and to incentivise bank management to price financial risk in
a way that covers its social costs. The latter objective is what
distinguishes bank corporate governance from other areas of corporate
governance because of the potential social costs that banking
can have on the broader economy.[12]
7. Major weaknesses in UK bank corporate
governance have resulted not only in substantial shareholder losses,
but also have contributed significantly to the significant contraction
of the UK economy, which has, among other things, led to massive
layoffs in the financial services industry and related economic
sectors and dramatically curtailed the availability of credit
to individuals and businesses. Most UK bank senior managers and
board members did not understand the risky business models that
drove UK bank lending and which led to much higher levels of leverage
in deposit banks and investment banks. Moreover, they failed to
grasp the true risks which their banks' risk managers had approved
based on faulty value-at-risk models that were used to determine
credit default risk and market risk. Equally important, they allowed
irresponsible compensation packages to be awarded to bankers which
incentivised them to book short-term profits based on excessively
risky behaviour which increased systemic risk in the financial
system and weakened the medium and long-term prospects and profitability
of the bank. Moreover, weak governance contributed to the poor
performance of banks and in some cases to their failure and bailout
or nationalisation by the government.
8. The UK regulatory regime should establish
new corporate governance standards that cover most areas of bank
management, including controls on remuneration that are linked
to the long-term profitability of the bank, while foregoing short-term
bonuses. The FSA should exercise the power to approve bank director
appointments and ensure that bank directors have the knowledge
and training to understand the bank's business and risk models
and its financial implications not only for the bank's shareholders,
but for the broader economy. Bank management should be required
to understand the technical aspects of stress-testing, which the
regulator should require to be done on a much more frequent basis
than what was done prior to the crisis. Essentially bank corporate
governance regulation should focus not only on aligning the incentives
of bank shareholders and managers, but also on aligning the broader
stakeholder interests in society with those of bank managers.
BANK SPECIAL
RESOLUTION REGIMES
9. The social costs that banks pose for the
economy also demonstrate the need for a special resolution regime
for banks that provides a legal framework for the regulator to
decide whether to attempt to save a bank by recapitalisation or
other restructuring pre-insolvency, and if this fails, to oversee
in insolvency the unwinding of the bank's multiple positions and
to sell off its viable assets to other banks or investors.[13]
For many countries, including the UK,[14]
ordinary insolvency law procedures have applied to the administration
and liquidation of a failing bank. Generally, corporate insolvency
law applies an elaborate framework to rank the economic claims
of creditors and other stakeholders against a firm which is unable
or unwilling to honour its financial obligations. Insolvency law
may prove socially costly, however, for certain firms, such as
banks, because insolvency procedures may result in restrictions
on a bank performing its essential function as a financial intermediary
in the economy.[15]
The inadequacies of general insolvency law to address the risks
which banks pose to the broader economy has led many countries
to enact special bank resolution regimes.
10. An important element of these resolution
regimes is that they permit the regulator to take certain measures
pre-insolvency which may alter or reduce shareholder rights and
the claims of third parties in order to protect depositors in
the weakened bank and to maintain overall financial stability.
The rationale for a pre-insolvency intervention regime is that
the regulator should have the authority to take certain measures
in response to a rapid loss of market confidence which may result
in the bank losing access to the short-term inter-bank loan market
and wholesale capital markets which may result in increased systemic
risk in the banking system. Through regulatory intervention, a
market-based solution may become possible. If a market solution
is not possible, however, the intervention may be the first step
by the regulator or central bank taking control of the failing
bank and transferring its shares and other property, including
contractual rights and obligations, to a state-owned bridge bank
or a private purchaser. Further steps may involve the bank being
declared insolvent and being subject to administration or liquidation.
11. The credit crisis of 2007-09 has demonstrated
the importance of bank special resolution regimes and the need
to balance the competing interests of shareholder rights with
the regulatory objectives of financial stability and depositor
protection. The constraints of corporate insolvency regimes can
be too cumbersome for effective resolution of a banking enterprise,
especially during a financial crisis when a failing bank needs
to maintain open lines of credit with other financial institutions
and to manage its balance sheet while achieving regulatory objectives.
Bank resolution regimes must be designed not only to protect shareholders
and creditors, but also to achieve other regulatory objectives
that are vital for the efficient operation of the economy. The
UK Banking Bill 2009 contains a special resolution regime that
seeks to achieve these objectives by granting the Treasury and
the Bank of England sweeping powers to restructure a failing bank
and to transfer its shares and property to a government-owned
bridge bank or to a private purchaser. Although the stabilisation
regime provides a comprehensive framework for bank corporate restructuring
and insolvency, it suspends corporate governance rules for shareholders
and thus interferes with shareholder rights. This raises important
issues under EU company law and the European Convention on Human
Rights regarding the protection of property rights and interests
in a bank that is undergoing restructuring to achieve regulatory
objectives.
THE UK TRIPARTITE
SYSTEM
12. The UK Tripartite System was established
by a legally non-binding Memorandum of Understanding in 1998 that
was designed to provide flexibility to the FSA, the Bank of England
and the Treasury to coordinate their regulatory interventions
and systemic oversight in times of crisis. Although the Chancellor
chaired the tripartite bodies and exercised ultimate decision-making
authority, there was no clear delineation of responsibilities
between the three for acting in a financial crisis. The FSA, the
Bank and the Treasury had only committed themselves to consult
and there was no clear procedure for determining how the bodies
would act in a banking or financial crisis and who would take
what decisions. The Tripartite Arrangement failed to work effectively
in the summer of 2007 when Northern Rock failed and had continuing
difficulties in its operations until the Banking Act 2008 was
adopted that established stronger legal grounds and procedural
rules for the Tripartite system's operations. Presently, the Banking
Bill 2009 reinforces many of the reforms that were made to the
Tripartite system's operations in 2008. One weakness, however,
which should be remedied is the Banking Bill's creation of a Financial
Stability committee which is chaired by the Bank of England. Membership
of the committee is composed of two of the Bank's deputy governors
and representatives from the Treasury, but there is no representation
from the Financial Services Authority on the Committee. It is
necessary to have the FSA as a member of the committee for the
oversight of systemic risk because we have learned in the credit
crisis that systemic risk can arise not only from individual banks
(which the FSA regulates), but also from the broader wholesale
capital markets (which the FSA also regulates). Therefore, the
FSA should be given statutory authority to supervise both individual
institutions and to oversee the broader financial system (ie.,
wholesale capital markets) to ensure against systemic risk and
other threats to financial stability.
February 2009
1 See M. Dewatripont and J. Tirole, "The Prudential
Regulation of Banks", (1995) (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA) 17-18. Back
2
See J. Hawkins & P. Turner, "Managing foreign debt and
liquidity risks in emerging economies: an overview", pp.
8-9, BIS Policy Papers (Sept. 2000) http://www.bis.org/publ/plcy08
(last accessed 15 Jan 2009). Back
3
See J. Stiglitz, "Principles of Financial Regulation: A Dynamic
Portfolio Approach" (Spring 2001) 16 World Bank Research
Observer 1:. 1-18, 1-2. Back
4
See T.L. Holzman (2000) "Unsafe or Unsound Practices: is
the Current Judicial Interpretation of the Term Unsafe or Unsound?"
19 Annual Review of Banking Law 425-54. Back
5
See E.P. Davis, Debt, Financial Fragility and Systemic Risk
(1995) ch. 5, (Oxford: OUP). Back
6
The social cost of bank risk-taking can take the form of a general
loss of confidence by depositors in the banking sector (bank run)
which will force banks to sell off their assets at prices far
below their historic costs. Also, a defaulting bank's uninsured
liabilities to other banks or financial institutions can serve
as a source of contagion that can create substantial losses for
other banks whose unfunded exposures to counterparties derive
from the original defaulting bank. Bank risk-taking therefore
creates a negative externality for the broader economy that provides
the major rationale for banking regulation. See F.S. Mishkin (2004)
The Economics of Money, Banking and Financial Markets (7th
ed.) pp. 271-74 (Pearson, Addison-Wesley, UK). Back
7
Under-priced financial assets can result in imprudent lending
and trading activity for banks and lead to increased solvency
risks. Back
8
See Dewatripont and Tirole, above n. 1, 23-24 Back
9
J. Eatwell and L. Taylor (1999) Global Finance at Risk chap.1. Back
10
EU Capital Requirements Directives (2006). Back
11
H. Mehran, "Critical Themes in Corporate Governance",
(April, 2003) FRBNY Economic Policy Review; see also, J.
Macey, and M. O'Hara, "The Corporate Governance of Banks"
(2003) FRBNY Economic Policy Review, Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, 91-107. Back
12
Moreover, it should be noted that regulatory intervention is necessary
to address the social costs of bank risk-taking because the regulator
is uniquely situated to assert the varied interests of other stakeholders
in society and to balance those interests according to the public
interest. Back
13
See Consultation Document of the Bank of England, HM Treasury
and the Financial Services Authority (FSA) "Financial stability
and depositor protection: special resolution regime" (July
2008). See UK Banking Bill 2009, discussed below. Back
14
See Consultation Document of the Bank of England, HM Treasury
and the Financial Services Authority (FSA) "Financial stability
and depositor protection: strengthening the framework" (Jan.
2008) 2-4. Back
15
For instance, insolvency law may result in a stay on payments
and a balance sheet freeze, which would make it difficult, if
not impossible, for the bank to rely on the wholesale funding
markets and to manage its counterparty exposures through netting. Back
|