CHAPTER 3: The length of the parliamentary
term and election timing
Five year terms
47. Aside from the principle itself, arguably
the most significant constitutional provision in the Fixed-term
Parliaments Bill is the length of the term. Clause 1(3) of the
Bill provides for fixed terms of five years.
48. This provision reflects the maximum term
currently permissible under the Septennial Act 1715, as amended
by the Parliament Act 1911. In introducing the 1911 Act, the Prime
Minister, Herbert Asquith, told the House of Commons:
"We propose to shorten the legal duration
of Parliament from seven years to five years, which will probably
amount in practice to an actual legislative working term of four
years. That will secure that your House of Commons for the time
being, is always either fresh from the polls which gave it authority,
orand this is an equally effective check upon acting in
defiance of the popular willit is looking forward to the
polls at which it will have to render an account of its stewardship."[72]
49. Asquith's expectation of four year parliamentary
terms has been broadly borne out. There have been 18 post-war
general elections, and the average length of time between general
elections since 1945 is three years and ten months.[73]
Had all Parliaments since 1945 lasted the full five year term,
four fewer elections would have been held. Having said that, there
have been three particularly short post-war Parliaments: 1950-51,
1964-66 and 1974. Parliamentary terms have been more uniform in
length since 1979, principally because Governments since then
have, more often than not, been returned with large overall majorities.
Of the seven Parliaments since May 1979, four have lasted for
roughly four years and three for roughly five years.
TABLE 2
Length of time between general elections
post 1945[74]
1945-1950
| 4.6 yrs
| | 1974-1979
| 4.6 yrs
|
1950-1951
| 1.7 yrs
| | 1979-1983
| 4.1 yrs
|
1951-1955
| 3.6 yrs
| | 1983-1987
| 4.0 yrs
|
1955-1959
| 4.4 yrs
| | 1987-1992
| 4.8 yrs
|
1959-1964
| 5.0 yrs
| | 1992-1997
| 5.1 yrs
|
1964-1966
| 1.5 yrs
| | 1997-2001
| 4.1 yrs
|
1966-1970
| 4.2 yrs
| | 2001-2005
| 3.9 yrs
|
1970-1974
| 3.7 yrs
| | 2005-2010
| 5.0 yrs
|
1974-1974
| 0.6 yrs
| | | |
THE CASE FOR A FIVE YEAR TERM
50. The Deputy Prime Minister set out the Government's
case for a five year term:
"It is ... a length of time ... with which
people are familiar ... [and] there is a pattern of five year
Parliaments, at least recently ... Given the tendency for governments
to be somewhat hamstrung and paralysed for a considerable period
before a general election is held ... you are in practice talking
about a government that can get on and do difficult things ...
for about four years ... That provides a degree of stability and
transparency to the political system which outweighs the self-evident
fact that if you did that over a period of time, people would
be voting less frequently ... I think that is a reasonable balance
to strike. If one goes to four years, one is talking about a three-year
period in which governments are not blighted by their own sense
of mortality ... That strikes me as a rather short period. For
all of those factors, we have tended to settle on five years."[75]
51. Dr Gary Levy, former Professor of Political
Science at the University of Western Ontario and Ottawa University,
submitted the only evidence which unambiguously backed the Government's
case for a longer term. He observed that opinion polls suggest
that voters "abhor elections", and that constant electioneering
would mean it would not be possible to keep pace with China and
other developing countries where elections "do not consume
the time, energy, money and political capital of the western style
elections that we hold so dear."[76]
David Howarth, a former MP whose own private member's bill had
set out a term of four years, saw "no obviously dispositive
method for deciding between the two proposals ... fairness points
more to four years, stability to five."[77]
THE CASE AGAINST A FIVE YEAR TERM
52. The vast majority of witnesses who commented
on the question advocated a shorter, four year term. Many did
so in forceful terms[78]
raising a number of specific objections to the Government's proposals.
53. Several witnesses argued that it was wrong
in principle to reduce the frequency with which elections are
held. The Hansard Society stressed the distinction between five
years as an absolute maximum and five years as the norm;[79]
Professor Dawn Oliver, Emeritus Professor of Constitutional Law,
University College London, thought that the cumulative effect
of successive terms would amount to a democratic deficit;[80]
and Democratic Audit expressed alarm that a five year term would
present "a reversal of a long struggle for more accountable
government."[81]
54. A five year term does not reflect devolved
and international experience. Appendix 3 shows the variety of
experience in terms of the length of a term in international democratic
institutions. Four years, whilst not universal, is clearly the
norm.[82] Moreover, where
fixed terms have been introduced or altered in recent years, legislatures
have invariably opted for four year terms.[83]
55. Four years has also been the default option
in terms of recent debate in the UK.[84]
The devolved legislatures in Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland
all operate according to four year fixed terms. Recent private
members' bills have proposed four year terms.[85]
Liberal Democrat policy papers in 2007 were explicitly in favour
of four year fixed terms.[86]
56. Professor Milner told us that "there
seems to be a kind of natural rhythm around four years in other
elections that the citizen might be participating in, such as
municipal elections, Scottish elections and American elections
if we are following them. The four year term is ... culturally
established, even in Britain".[87]
Professor Bradley argued that a four year term would be more consistent
with voters' expectations.[88]
57. As we note in Chapter Five, there has been
a lack of public debate on this issue. Professor Bradley told
us that "if one is making the fundamental switch from the
present situation to fixed-term Parliaments, then one needs a
full debate on what the period should be."[89]
When asked whether there should have been consultation on this
point, the Deputy Prime Minister questioned whether "people
are straining at the bit to vote in elections more frequently
... I have never met anyone who says to me, 'Well, I kind of like
voting every four years.'"[90]
This does not reflect the Government's stated view that the legislature
should be made more accountable to the people.[91]
58. Democratic Audit dismissed the Government's
reasoning, alleging that five years "seems to have been arrived
at on a basis of the political calculations of the two parties
involved in the Coalition ... It would be regrettable if short-term
political calculations were ... to have a long-term negative impact
upon political accountability in the UK."[92]
CONCLUSION ON TERM LENGTH
59. Of all the issues arising from the Fixed-term
Parliaments Bill, the proposal for a five year fixed term has
created the most unease. Despite the Government's arguments in
favour of a five year term, the consensus emerging from the evidence
is that this is too long, and that a four year term would be preferable.
The Government's central argument is that a five year term is
necessary in order to allow an administration to govern effectively.
This is an important consideration, yet it must not be viewed
in isolation. The need to deliver effective government must be
balanced against the need to maintain democratic accountability.
60. The evidence we received did not support
a term shorter than four or longer than five years. Neither do
we believe that such a term would be appropriate. The question
therefore is whether a four or five year term would provide the
most appropriate balance between effective government and democratic
accountability. The difference between a five year maximum and
a five year norm should not be understatedthe cumulative
effect on democratic accountability of successive five year terms
would be considerable.
61. The length of previous parliamentary terms
in the UK has depended on a number of factors, including the popularity
or success of each particular government.[93]
There has, however, been no fixed-term principle under which governments
would normally last for the full five year term. It is therefore
not possible to judge from the UK experience whether governments
required to last for five years would be any less popular or successful
than they would otherwise have been.
62. Whilst acknowledging the case made by
the Deputy Prime Minister for a five year term, nonetheless the
majority of the Committee consider that a four year term should
be adopted for any fixed-term parliamentary arrangement at Westminster.
In the view of the majority, the shift from a five year maximum
to a five year norm would be inconsistent with the Government's
stated aim of making the legislature more accountable, inconsistent
with existing constitutional practice and inconsistent with the
practice of the devolved institutions and the clear majority of
international legislatures.
63. Any change in the general election cycle
is of the utmost constitutional significance. The strong views
that witnesses have expressed on this question demonstrate the
need to consult on and debate fully and openly the relative benefits
and drawbacks of different term lengths. The Government have failed
to do this. We consider these process issues further in Chapter
Five.
Resetting the clock
64. We discuss in Chapter Four the ways in which
Parliament may be dissolved early. One significant issue which
has arisen from this is the question of the length of the ensuing
term. There are two basic options: allowing any subsequent Parliament
to last for a new full term (resetting the clock) or keeping the
set election date so that the subsequent Parliament would only
last for a part term.
65. Professor Bradley stressed that if you reset
the clock:
"you will not have made a real psychological
change to your constitutional arrangements to the fixed-term system,
because in the minds of major parties there will always be the
view that if we do have an election now, will this give us what
at the moment we would like, which is a four or five year period
in office? That goes against what should be the spirit of a fixed-term
system."[94]
66. This issue must be examined in the context
of the Bill's provision of a five year term. Were an early election
to take place, the newly elected government could have a full
five years in which to govern, creating a strong incentive to
bring about an early election. The shorter the maximum term, the
weaker that incentive. Professor Milner and Stephen Padgett, Professor
of Government, University of Strathclyde, agreed that the shorter
the term, the better the argument for resetting the clock.[95]
67. Professor Milner also noted that it is possible
to agree to reset the clock in some circumstances, but not in
others. He told us that:
"Working on the premise that it would be
four years, I would argue that the principle [of resetting the
clock] is not wrong. I could imagine a compromise that said that
if the dissolution was in the first two years of Parliament, the
original date should be maintained, but if it was in the second
two years of Parliament, the election should be four years from
that date."[96]
68. Clause 1(3) of the Bill provides for the
clock to be reset. However, ordinary elections must always be
held on the first Thursday in May, therefore this provision is
modified by clause 1(4) which prevents any subsequent Parliament
lasting for more than five years. So, for example, the next ordinary
election should take place on 7 May 2015. If this Parliament were
dissolved early in October 2013, the next Parliament would last
until May 2018: a term of four and a half years. This prevents
an early election held at a less convenient time of year (for
example, close to Christmas) resulting in all subsequent elections
having to be held at that time of year. It should be noted that
these provisions could result in a subsequent term of just over
four years.
69. The Government justified their decision to
reset the clock on the ground that "the public would think
it odd if you were to have an early election and the public were
to make a clear decision about a governmentperhaps returning
it with a good majorityand a very short time afterwards,
you were to ask the public to go back and vote all over again."[97]
70. The Government also stated, in their response
to the report of the Commons Political and Constitutional Reform
Committee on this Bill,[98]
that: "The people expect that when they go to the polls,
they are being asked to elect a government which will last for
a full term with a full programme. The proposals in the Bill will
provide certainty as to the length of a Parliament and minimise
the possibility of multiple elections happening in quick succession."[99]
71. These arguments are not conclusive. Firstly,
what the people might expect under a fixed-term arrangement would
be dependent on the provisions of the relevant legislation. Secondly,
any Parliament which lasted only until a set election date would
have a definite length. Indeed, the length of the parliamentary
term might be more certain since it would be less likely that
a Parliament with a shorter time left to run would itself be dissolved
early. Thirdly, it can be questioned just how likely multiple
elections in quick succession would be. It is possible to modify
arrangements so that a newly elected government does not have
to return to the polls within a short period of, say, six months
or a year. Consultation and pre-legislative scrutiny would have
provided the opportunity for such arrangements to be properly
considered.
72. It is also the case that the clock is not
reset in the Scottish Parliament or the Welsh Assembly.[100]
Although the Scottish and Welsh legislatures have been in existence
only since 1999, it is notable that they have produced both minority
and coalition governments and that no early elections have yet
been held.
73. Many of our witnesses were equivocal about
this issue. Some argued that whilst only allowing the remainder
of the term would act as a disincentive to abuse of the early
dissolution provisions by an existing government, a different
government elected with a fresh mandate should be allowed a full
term.[101] The Government
acknowledged that the arguments were balanced and that it was,
in the end, "a judgment issue".[102]
74. We agree that there is a case to be made
for resetting the clock. Whatever the maximum term, we accept
that an elected government should have a full term in which to
develop their policies and take their legislative programme through
Parliament.
Election timingthe devolved
institutions
75. Five year terms would create a clash with
elections to the devolved institutions in May 2015 and every 20
years thereafter.[103]
There was a widespread view that such a clash was undesirable.[104]
Professor Padgett pointed to the dangers of a clash when he told
us that in Germany, "Where state elections have coincided
with the federal election, the federal election's issues and campaigns
have totally engulfed the regional campaign."[105]
76. Once again, concerns were raised about the
process by which the Government's proposals were announced, and
in particular about the lack of consultation with the devolved
institutions.[106]
The Deputy Prime Minister told us that he had met the leaders
of the devolved administrations and the Presiding Officers in
two of the devolved legislatures. He conceded that:
"there is undoubtedly some potential for
overlap and some degree of confusion if one has two elections
for legislatures on the same day. We are consulting people and
trying to see whether there are workable or desirable alternatives
... whether people think that the issue is big enough that we
need to take remedial action."[107]
77. This issue may not be resolvable in the Fixed-term
Parliaments Bill. The Government have pointed out that if the
Bill provided for a four year term, an early dissolution which
resulted in a clash could lead to a clash occurring every four
years thereafter.[108]
Only by providing for fully fixed four year terms, with the next
Parliament due to commence in 2013, could a more satisfactory
permanent cycle of biennial UK and devolved elections be established.
The arguments we set out in the next chapter in favour of early
dissolution arrangements mean that such an arrangement would not
be acceptable. A different solution is therefore required.
78. A number of potential solutions were suggested
to us, including allowing the UK Parliament to continue only until
October 2014,[109]
moving Westminster elections to take place just before or after
the devolved elections,[110]
or giving the Scottish Parliament the power to set its own election
dates.[111]
79. The Minister for Political and Constitutional
Reform has announced that he is consulting the Scottish Parliament
and the Welsh Assembly about bringing forward amendments enabling
these legislatures to avoid a potential clash by varying the election
date by six months either way if two-thirds of members vote in
favour. In relation to the Northern Ireland Assembly, the Government
are proposing to wait until after the combined elections in May
before deciding how to proceed.[112]
80. A potential date clash with elections
to the devolved institutions in May 2015 and every twenty years
thereafter could occur if the Government's proposals are adopted.
Ideally, this should be avoided in order to protect the integrity
and separate identity of Westminster and devolved elections. We
await the outcome of the Government's consultations with the devolved
institutions, and stress the importance of ensuring that any proposed
solution is broadly acceptable to all concerned.
81. It is regrettable that the Government
did not seek to engage with the devolved institutions in order
to find a satisfactory solution to the consequences of their proposals
before the Bill was introduced.
Sessional arrangements
82. Traditionally, parliamentary sessions have
begun and ended in the autumn, with the exception of years in
which there is a spring general election. In these instances,
it is usual for the first session to last approximately eighteen
months until the following autumn, with the final session of a
Parliament lasting around six months. The Government have announced
that future parliamentary sessions will last from spring to spring
in order to bring them into line with elections on a fixed date
in May.[113]
83. The Government have proposed the shift on
the basis that it would form a common-sense corollary of their
legislative proposals.[114]
It should be noted, however, that this change is not a necessary
corollary of the Bill's provisions: in recent times, the Queen's
speech has been held in the autumn, despite elections being held
in spring or summer.
84. The Government also announced that the current
session would last for two years until spring 2012. The Minister
for Political and Constitutional Reform told us that:
"given that the first session in a new Parliament
is traditionally a longer one anyway ... we thought that on balance
it was better to extend the current session and then align the
State Opening and the new sessions with the new fixed-term cycle
... I do not see that it changes the balance between Parliament
and the Executive at all."[115]
85. Professor Bradley considered this to be "a
rather remarkable situation. We are in an area of reworking a
lot of aspects of the constitution that have been around for a
long while ... to postpone [the State Opening] for a complete
year is quite a major change."[116]
He argued that it would strengthen the executive at the expense
of Parliament, noting that "time and the need to get agreement
by a certain date are a vital part of the power of the House of
Lords."[117]
86. Conversely, the Clerk of the Parliaments
stated that:
"the long session may strengthen the power
of the House. Use of the Parliament Act procedure requires the
bill concerned to be introduced in the following session. If that
session is not to begin until April or May 2012 then the House
has a significant power of delay in relation to a bill which otherwise
would be expected to complete its passage in 2011."[118]
87. The Government's proposal to extend the
current session until spring 2012 may increase the power of the
House of Lords to delay legislation but it also affords the Government
more time to get its legislative programme through both Houses,
thus potentially increasing the power of the executive in relation
to Parliament. This appears to be inconsistent with the Government's
stated aim of reducing the power of the executive.[119]
72 HC Deb 21 Feb 1911 col 1749. Back
73
Figure calculated from the general election on 5 July 1945 to
the general election on 5 May 2010. There were 17 Parliaments
during this period. Back
74
Source: HC Research Paper 10/54, Fixed-term Parliaments Bill,
26 August 2010 p 32. That paper also lists the lengths of the
parliamentary terms as well as the time between elections (the
latter is longer as it takes account of periods of dissolution).
Only the latter are listed here since this reflects the Bill's
provisions for a fixed election date. Back
75
Constitution Committee, 5th report (2010-2011), op. cit. Q 54;
see also QQ 63-65. The Government emphasised their view during
the Committee Stage debate in the Commons: HC Deb 16 November
2010 cols 837-841. Back
76
FTP 23. Back
77
FTP 19, summary and paras 5-7. Back
78
Q 7 (Professor Bradley); FTP 10, paras 11-18 (Democratic
Audit); Q 50 (Professor Padgett). Back
79
FTP 16, para 7. Back
80
Q 7. Back
81
FTP 10, paras 11-18. Back
82
QQ 50, 52 (Professor Milner). See also Constitution Unit op.
cit., Fig 4.1; FTP 10, Table 2 (Democratic Audit). Back
83
Including Sweden in 1994 and Canada in 2006. In addition, all
Australian states and territories and Canadian provinces and territories
that have introduced fixed terms in recent years now operate four
year terms. Back
84
Q 87 (Dr Fox). Back
85
Fixed-term Parliaments, Bill 54 (2001-2002); Fixed Term Parliaments,
Bill 30 (2007-2008). Back
86
The Liberal Democrats, Real Democracy for Britain op. cit.;
For the People, By the People op. cit.. Back
87
Q 52. Back
88
QQ 7-8. See also FTP 31, para 6 (Richard Pond). Back
89
Q 7. Back
90
Constitution Committee, 5th report (2010-2011), op. cit. Q 66. Back
91
See para 15. Back
92
FTP 10,para 17. Back
93
Q 8 (Professor Bradley); FTP 16, para 7 (Hansard Society); Constitution
Unit, op. cit., para 4.1. Back
94
Q 16 (Professor Oliver). See also Q 99 (Professor Bogdanor). Back
95
Q 56. Back
96
Q 48. Back
97
Q 161 (Minister for Political and Constitutional Reform). Back
98
Political and Constitutional Reform Committee, 2nd Report (2010-2011)
op. cit.. Back
99
Government response to the report of the Political and Constitutional
Reform Committee on the Fixed-term Parliaments Bill, Cm 7951,
November 2010, para 42. Back
100
It is reset for the Northern Ireland Assembly. Back
101
Q 21 (Professor Oliver); Q 49 (Professor Padgett); Q 99 (Professor
Bogdanor). Back
102
Q 161 (Minister for Political and Constitutional Reform). Back
103
On the assumption that the electoral cycle is not disrupted by
early general elections. Back
104
QQ 13-14 (Professor Bradley and Professor Oliver); Q 90 (Dr Fox);
FTP 32, para 2 (Mark Ryan). Back
105
Q 59. Back
106
QQ 13-14 (Professor Bradley and Professor Oliver); Q 90 (Dr Fox);
FTP 32, para 2 (Mark Ryan). Back
107
Constitution Committee, 5th report (2010-2011), op. cit. Q
63; see also Q 64. Back
108
HC Deb 16 November 2010 col 844. Back
109
Constitution Committee, 5th report (2010-2011), op. cit. Q 13
(Professor Hazell); see also Constitution Unit, op. cit.,
para 4.2. Back
110
FTP 32, para 13 (Mark Ryan). Back
111
Q 90 (Dr Fox citing Professor John Curtice). This proposal could
equally apply to the Welsh Assembly and the Northern Ireland Assembly.
Back
112
HC Deb 16 November 2010 cols 841-845. Back
113
HC Deb 13 September 2010 cols 33-34WS. Back
114
HC Deb 13 September 2010 cols 614-619. See also Q 135 (Minister
for Political and Constitutional Reform). Back
115
QQ 135-6. Back
116
Q 4. Back
117
Q 6. Back
118
FTP 43, para 9. Back
119
See above para 15. Back
|