Chapter 3: approach
64. Across the evidence we received, five broad
models of procedures and interventions were put forward as candidates
for new approaches to media plurality policy; these are captured
roughly in the diagram below.
Figure 1
Approaches
65. The purpose of this chapter is to present
our analysis of these different approaches to media plurality
policy: their motivating concerns, their pros and cons, and other
relevant questions. Our hope is that our presentation of these
issues will help to clarify, for expert and uninitiated audiences
alike, the merits and demerits of these different approaches as
compared to each other.
66. However, making clear comparisons between
different policy approaches to media plurality is not straightforward.
This is not only because they do not elicit consensus, but because
the different perspectivesat least those we have heardtend
to enter the debate on such different terms: technocratic, polemic,
and pragmatic. Each of these ways into the plurality debate is
likely to get some parts right and to miss others.
67. Against that background, we will make concluding
remarks on each of the possible approaches put to us and we try
to give understandable and balanced reasons for reaching these
conclusions. To be clear, our conclusions are also informed by
certain principles which we arrived at in the course of our analysis.
A summary of these is set out in chapter 5, but as two of these
principles, in particular, shed light on our thinking in this
chapter, we include them here first:
68. The framework of plurality assessment
and intervention must strike a balance between providing certainty
to the market and flexibility to the regulatorboth are
important.
69. The assessment of plurality should drive
the decision about which remedy or intervention is appropriate,
not the other way around.
70. Finally, we note that the background to all
of these approaches is a fairly common set of criticisms about
the current arrangements for media plurality, including that they
fail to address digital media enterprises or the impact on plurality
of organic change. These points are well documented, so we do
not comment on them further, other than briefly to address the
"20/20" rule about which we did take some evidence.
71. The "20/20" rule applies to cross-media
ownership at a national level and consists in the following:[73]
· No
one can own more than 20% of a Channel 3 licence[74]
and at the same time own national newspapers with more than 20%
market share.
· The
same restriction applies to anyone who is more than 20% owned
by someone who has more than 20% of the national newspaper market.
72. For some, the argument for retaining the
"20/20" rule is weakening because they claim that the
relative importance of the media to which it applies has waned.
For example, David Elstein questioned "whether the famous
20/20 rule
any longer makes sense, given that the first
of these "20"s (ownership of more than 20% of the national
newspaper market) related to daily sales of 16 million newspapers
when the clause was enacted, but now relates to daily sales below
9 million."[75]
Others, such as Professor Barnett, still see the Channel
3 licence and the national newspaper market as particularly important
in the context of plurality: "The notion of separating what
are still the most powerful forms of mass communication is entirely
appropriate. I would keep that rule."[76]
73. The balance of the evidence about whether
to retain or remove the "20/20" rule did not point heavily
in one direction or the other. The important point was made by
Dr Tambini: "the answer to all of these questions depends
on what is replacing it"[77]
which chimes with Ofcom's argument in its supplementary advice
to the Secretary of State: "the main factor that might inform
whether the 20/20 rule is the most effective way of addressing
the original policy aimsis the extent to which a new regulatory
regime
might address these same aims."[78]
This can only be decided with any certainty once it is clear what
that new regulatory regime should be, and perhaps even only when
it is in place. We, therefore, leave our conclusion on this point
to chapter 5 in which we set out our proposal on media plurality,
having first considered in this chapter the range of approaches
put to us in the evidence we received.
Conceptual Shift (Positive Intervention)
WHAT ARE THE MOTIVATING CONCERNS FOR PROPONENTS OF
THIS APPROACH?
74. Proponents of a 'conceptual shift' towards
positive intervention generally have serious concerns about measures
designed to prevent media enterprises from growing, such as media
ownership caps. Indeed their call for a conceptual shift is often
triggered by a fear that such proposals and the analysis behind
them are barking up the wrong tree, focussing too heavily on abuses
of concentrated media power and not enough on the growing fragmentation
of the media and the decline in its commercial sustainability.
Professor Collins told us that "there is a significant
structural change going on in the media sector, notably, the migration
of advertising revenue to the internet, which is undermining a
business model that has sustained relatively high quality and
relatively pluralistic media in the UK and elsewhere for a long
time."[79] Accordingly,
he added that "changing the regulatory order is going to
have relatively little bite on this structural problem. Focusing
on changing media ownership regulation is taking attention away
from looking at what the main issue is."[80]
75. As a result they call for a new focus within
plurality policy on positive interventions to promote diversity,
either as a principal recommendation in and of itselfas
is suggested by Professors Collins and Caveor as part of
a wider package of measuresas is suggested by Professor Picard
and Mr Foster. The premise of this approach is that, ultimately,
"media plurality depends largely on commercial organisations
investing in news and journalism."[81]
Accordingly, it is argued that "a conceptual shift is needed
Rather than conceiving of media pluralism as an objective
to be realised by prohibiting mergers, it should be thought of
as pointing towards intervention designed to facilitate and encourage
entry."[82]
76. This case is made with particular reference
to newer, smaller online providers of news and current affairs
content, 'minnows' as some have called them:
"maybe we should spend a bit less time limiting
and a bit more time fostering
so that these minnows
can establish themselves as genuine authoritative alternatives
to the
media we have now."[83]
77. Proponents of this view also point out that
positive interventions are not unprecedented. Accordingly, the
conceptual shift they call for may simply involve thinking more
widely and imaginatively about the purpose of existing public
intervention in the media.
"We see the remedyif there is a remedymore
in terms of public intervention to redress or mitigate classic
market failure. We have got that very well established in the
UK with the BBC and other publicly funded broadcasters, other
jurisdictions, press subsidies and so on."[84]
WHAT MIGHT PUBLIC INTERVENTION FOR MEDIA DIVERSITY
LOOK LIKE IN PRACTICE?
78. There has been no definitive answer to this
question. Indeed responses have generally suggested that it is
a vast and complex question to consider in its own right and would
deserve its own inquiry:
"That would be a very interesting topic
for another inquiry. One would not want to hand out public money
to just anyone who applied; you have to think of the criteria."[85]
79. Nonetheless a number of tentative early thoughts
on what positive intervention might look like were mentioned.
Professor Collins told us that "There are two past papers
of Ofcom that really bear on this issue very interestingly. The
first is the one in which they advocated the establishment of
a public service publisher. Secondly, I think it is 2007 and I
am pretty sure the reference is in our evidence to you: New News,
Future News. This paints a rather gloomy picture of how this sector
is going to develop."[86]
Professor Barnett also put forward as a model:
"Independently Funded News Consortia
which were finally passed in the wash-up under the old Labour
Government and then dismantled by the coalition Government. I
believe they offered at least a sort of model for allowing local
media platformsTV, radio, online, newspapersto come
together, partly with some help from public funding, to ensure
that something existed at that local level."[87]
80. Even these tentative early suggestions, however,
raise difficult challenges. One of the criticisms which the newspaper
industry regularly makes is, of course, that the BBC is in receipt
of public money and it is a competitor. There can be little doubt
that any case for additional public money to be spent on public
interest media would attract understandable criticism from a range
of players currently in the marketplace who are suffering difficult
economic times.
HOW WOULD POSITIVE INTERVENTION TO PROMOTE MEDIA
DIVERSITY FIT IN WITH EXISTING PUBLIC FUNDING OF THE MEDIA?
81. While views we heard about the specific manifestations
of public intervention to support diversity were overwhelmingly
tentative, debate over how any such idea might interact with existing
forms of public support for the media (such as funding of the
BBC) was, by contrast, relatively firm and occasionally heated.
82. A very clear divide, for example, exists
between those who believe that the question of public intervention
merits a reconsideration of licence fee funding, particularly
in light of existing precedents for this money being used for
non-BBC purposes such as S4C, and those who do not, and instead
believe that additional public funding to support media diversity
should come from new sources such as a levy on digital intermediaries.
For example, on one side there are those like Professor Collins
who told us that "if one
ask[s]
Where would
the money come from?"
the only obvious candidate for
that funding is the licence fee. We have had a number of precedents
where very small amounts of the licence fee have been directed
to
supporting new media entrants. We think that might not
be a bad way to go in future."[88]
On the other side there are those like Professor Barnett
who put it to us that:
"top-slicing the BBC
is a profoundly
bad idea
Punishing the BBC by taking money away from an
organisation that is not just world-renowned but deeply trusted
in this country to give that money to other start-up operations
that may or may not be successful is frankly a daft idea
there are other potential sources of public funding through levies
on the news aggregators, on ISPs."[89]
83. The evidence we have heard also featured
discussion not simply about allocation of public funds for media
diversity but about theperhaps slightly softermatter
of what the BBC's responsibilities towards fostering plurality
should be. On internal plurality, the BBC agreed that it did not
have a specific duty to promote internal plurality, but equally
did not believe that introducing such a duty would necessarily
be helpful:
"It does not have a specific requirement
but despite not having that specific requirement, the trust regards
that as a major requirement of the BBC and it is a key part of
our editorial policy guidelines. It is infused structurally and
culturally in the organisation. You are right, there is not something
in the charter and agreement that says we must do it, and that
may be something that Government and Parliament want to look at.
I would be slightly nervous about overly prescribing how the BBC
conducts its news affairs within the charter and agreement, but
it is certainly an interesting idea"[90]
84. Whether or not the BBC should have a specific
duty to foster internal plurality, others suggested there is a
strong case for the BBC to adapt more generally with a view to
creating greater internal plurality. In his oral evidence to the
Committee, David Elstein accused the BBC of being a 'unitary organisation'
and suggested that BBC radio, News channel, World Service and
Online are insufficiently independent from each other editorially.
"[The BBC] is a unitary organisation
Under John Birt and his then head of news and current affairs,
Tony Hall
news and current affairs were merged inside the
BBC
My concern is
with the lack of pluralism in
the way BBC news and current affairs is organised. I would love
to see Tony Hall taking the principled view that the way to deliver
internal plurality is to reverse the process that he has played
such a large part in, which is to allow BBC radio, the BBC News
Channel, BBC World Service and BBC online to be independent editorially."[91]
85. The BBC Trust rejected this view and indeed
it is overstated. As Diane Coyle, Vice Chairman of the BBC Trust
told us: "I do not recognise that monolithic BBC that he
is describing. Nobody dictates an editorial line to BBC journalists
The services and programmes serve different audiences and
they are very different in character."[92]
86. In addition, while recognising the importance
of presenting a diverse range of views on any one topic within
its individual services, the BBC argue that in the context of
Delivering Quality First, the BBC's programme of cuts, the organisation
needs to find efficient ways of working which may not be compatible
with the establishment of competing centres of editorial control.
The cuts being made, they claim, are being implemented with the
goal in mind, as far as possible, to maintain investment in public
interest journalism, locally and internationally:
"The hope is that, with all BBC news funded
from the same source under one roof, you can start to develop
a more integrated news operation where the domestic benefits from
the international and the international benefits from the domestic."[93]
87. Moreover, the BBC put it to us that there
is clearly an important role for a diversity of views to be presented
in any one service, but that the idea of delivering internal plurality
through a system of alternative and competing news agendas did
not necessarily reflect audience demands. These tend to rate more
highly than internal plurality the importance of finding, across
any service from the BBC, a news offer which is trusted, impartial,
accurate and up-to-date:
"When we ask audiences why they choose a
news provider the top answers they give are around impartiality,
accuracy, trustworthiness and being up-to-date. For us, those
have to be the priority. So, while internal plurality is important,
it is not the top audience priority"[94]
88. By contrast, when it came to external plurality,
the BBC itself appeared to be more open to the potential of developing
its activities and responsibilities further:
"the extent to which the BBC could play
a broader role in enhancing external plurality, I agree that the
BBC, given its scale in the market, should think hard about how
it uses that scale and presence to support other parts of the
market. An obvious way in which it does this is around online.
Effectively, online news gives you the shelf space to do far more
in-depth analysis and detailed treatment and background and context
on stories, and what you can do there is effectively push consumers
to a range of other suppliers in the market, whether that is to
other newspaper websites or other sources of news. That is something
the BBC does and the stats are quite significant on the amount
of traffic it pushes outside BBC Online. They could be stronger.
We could be more sophisticated in how we link out to websites,
both local websites and national websites, but that is one obvious
example. We would be up for a conversation, dialogue, with newspaper
groups about how the BBC can use its position in the market in
a positive way, something that we have tried to do in the past
with the way we syndicate our news content. It is something we
did in the Olympics whereby we shared Olympics audio-visual footage
with newspapers. There are also other things we are up for an
active discussion on with newspaper organisations."[95]
THE COMMITTEE'S VIEW
89. As a Committee we have looked at the idea
of new exercises in public and charitable funding of the media
before in our Report on The Future of Investigative Journalism.[96]
We recognise there may be some potential merit in these ideas.
We support those working in this area.
90. On the BBC, we think that the proper place
to consider its responsibilities, including with regard to matters
such as internal or external plurality, is within the Charter
Review framework.
91. On internal plurality, David Elstein's idea
of rerouting the internal wiring of BBC news services to establish
different editorial centres of control is certainly, in some respects,
an attractive intellectual proposal. We are persuaded, however,
that there are practical pressures and other priorities in the
BBC which compete with this, which argue against the idea of establishingnow,
at any ratea distributed system of editorial centres creating
competing news agendas available across BBC's services. However,
in light of the foregoing discussion about external plurality
and the potential for the BBC to act not only as a trusted provider
of its own news and current affairs content but also as a gateway
to external sources of diverse opinion on news and current affairs,
at least in its online incarnation, we make the following recommendation:
92. We encourage the Government and the BBC
in negotiating Charter Renewal to consider whether the BBC might
be given a more explicit responsibilitywith respect to
its online offer for news and current affairs contentto
stimulate consumption of diverse viewpoints from different external
sources.
93. As a separate matter, we also note that licence
fee money is already being allocated, as far as we can tell at
the Government's request, to projects external to the BBC such
as S4C withif not explicittacit approval of the
BBC Trust. It is not out of place, therefore to make the following
recommendation:
94. We recommend that the Charter Review process
makes clear what licence fee funding is for, and that, as long
as it is conceivably available for projects external to the BBC,
it is also made clear what strategic role, if any, this funding
might play in positively promoting external plurality in the wider
UK media.
95. For our part, we urge the Government to
support our view that the licence fee should be for the BBC alone,
though we do not argue that funding to S4C should now be removed.
96. Our sense is that if this principle is not
observed, people can too easily look to the licence fee as a source
of funding for other projects, and the Government of the day can
too easily blur the issue, indeed as it is doing at present. Clarity
and transparency are important and required in this.
No Intervention
WHAT MOTIVATES THE PROPONENTS OF THIS IDEA?
97. In reality, there have been no proponents
of this idea across the evidence submitted to the Committee. Only
one witness, Professor Collins, has appeared to come close:
"In our bolder moments, we do flirt with that idea, my Lord
Chairman."[97]
98. While no one has argued for this approach,
it has, however, arisen a number of times in our evidence sessions.
This is because it has provided witnesses with a way of discussing
the value of having a media plurality policy over having none,
or perhaps more accurately, the value of having a media plurality
policy over allowing decisions on media ownership to be made strictly
on competition grounds or only by competition authorities, as
described in chapter 1.
99. As noted there, those who have made a point
of opposing this idea highlight the differences between competition
policy and plurality policy, underlining that plurality policy
is not secondary to competition policy but that there are good
arguments for considering it to exist in parallel with it.
100. Not disconnected from this, others have
also argued that, institutionally, competition authorities are
not the appropriate bodies to carry out the thinking required
by a media plurality assessment. Professor Picard, for example,
told us that "regulators
are very often very tightly
focused in their competencies to deal with things, or in the methods
that they can use to analyse things, or in the remedies they have.
If [a plurality assessment] gets thrown to a competition authority,
they are going to deal with it as a competition issue."[98]
He added that:
"The Office of Fair Trading, and the Competition
Commission have the ability and skills to undertake appropriate
inquiries in areas involving ownership and mergers/acquisitions,
but their remits do not include continuous monitoring of broader
pluralism issues and the authority and tools to work to proactively
improve media pluralism. They also lack the organisational ethos
and capabilities for positively promoting media pluralism."[99]
THE COMMITTEE'S VIEW
101. As indicated in chapter 1, we believe that
determining clear demarcation lines between plurality and competition
policy is crucial. We will not repeat those arguments here. We
only note that the current overlap between the two seems partly
responsible for the fact that at play in the political discussion
of this subject are a number of matters which in reality run parallel
to media plurality policy.
Caps
102. A cap has been proposed in two contexts:
first, as a stand-alone measure, and second, as a single element
within a package of hybrid measures. The latter will be considered
later under 'hybrids'. For now, a number of questions arise in
relation to a cap as an approach in its own right.
WHAT PROPOSALS HAVE BEEN MADE FOR A CAP AS AN APPROACH
IN ITS OWN RIGHT?
103. Across the evidence the principal witness
to have proposed introducing a cap as a stand-alone measure is
Enders Analysis. Their specific proposal is for a cap of 15% on
the revenues any enterprise can earn across the 'total media market'.
They argue that "the most effective way of ensuring plurality
is to introduce a cap on the share of the revenues of the total
media market controlled by any company
a cap of, say, 15%
would ensure that no one company could completely dominate the
UK media industry"[100]
104. The 'total media market' includes: "national
newspapers; Regional newspapers; Consumer magazines; Video games;
Television advertising; Television subscription fees; Books both
in physical and digital form; Recorded music both in physical
and digital form; Cinema; Video/DVD rental and purchase; Internet
subscriptions; Internet advertising; [and] Radio advertising."[101]
WHAT MOTIVATES PROPONENTS OF THE ENDERS CAP?
105. Proponents of this approach are clearly
motivated by a range of concerns relating to media plurality policy.
Still, given its distinctive features it is probably fair to say
that chief among these is a concern with market powerand
stopping any one entity having too much of it. This was made clear
by Mr Goodall from Enders Analysis in his oral evidence:
"I absolutely believe that if we think plurality and diversity
are important, we have to stop one dog in the industry becoming
too powerful."[102]
He added that:
"Our belief is that most of the malign influence
of extremely high market shares in media arises not necessarily
from the ability to influence the political process, but to influence
the economics of the industry in this large company's favour."[103]
MORE SPECIFICALLY, WHY DO ITS PROPONENTS SET THE
REVENUE CAP AT 15%?
106. There appear to be three main reasons why
the cap's proponents believe it would be an effective measure.
First, as long as the market can sustain them, it provides the
closest thing to a guaranteed 'floor-level' of media players across
the whole media market. As Professor Barnett told us, "The
Enders notion of a 15% cap, which gives you six or seven major
players
The rationale behind it seems to me to be entirely
appropriate."[104]
107. Secondly, it draws a symbolically significant
line in the sand for UK democracy. Again, Professor Barnett
told us that a cap is a "bright white line that says 'thus
far and no further'. At that point it is becoming too uncomfortable
for democracy to allow someone with that much circulation of national
newspapers or that much share of the national television audience
to be in one person's hands or one private company's hands. At
that point we are saying, 'We are going to have to ask you to
divest'. It is important to have that rule and that cap."[105]
108. Thirdly, it gives certainty to the market
and removes discretion from either the regulator or Government
in implementing media plurality policy. It is argued that this
has a number of benefits. It makes the policy more workable from
the perspective of a regulator responsible for it; indeed it is
argued that a policy may be entirely unworkable without removing
discretion from the process. Mr Goodall explained that "we
have gone for a relatively simple, extremely arbitrary ruleand
I use that word carefully because to me that is a good thingbecause
it is then very much easier for regulators to maintain control
and to make sure that the rules are well understood by every participant."[106]
This point was underlined by Dr Craufurd Smith:
"If you are going to start having a cross-media
metric that covers sectors like film, video and games, which is
what she [Enders] is proposing, it may be that revenue is the
only way that you can do that without imposing some enormous burden
on the regulator in order to convert all them."[107]
109. One further reason alleged by some witnesses
to be behind support for setting this cap at 15% is that it would
meet a desire on the part of some to accommodate the BBC's share
of 'revenues' while blocking the growth in revenue-share of Murdoch-owned
media enterprises, if, for example News Corp (as was) were to
have tried once more to acquire the remaining shares in BSkyB.
Mr Elstein claimed that "it is designed for a purpose,
which is to limit the influence of Murdoch or Sky or whatever
I think Claire is very open as to why she is recommending
it
It is just another way of dealing with Murdoch."[108]
WHY DO ITS PROPONENTS SET THE CAP ACROSS THE 'TOTAL
MEDIA MARKET'?
110. To some extent, this point is addressed
in the previous chapter on Scope. A 'total media market' cap appeals
to those in favour of a broader scope for media plurality policy
for the following reason:
"The things that affect us culturally, the
kind of society we are, the kinds of things that matter to us
and the views that we then come to are much more broadly based
than that. That is why I ambringing it back to brass tacksattracted
to the Enders revenue proposal, because it takes into account
that much bigger cultural environment."[109]
111. Separately, the use of a cap across media
markets appears to be driven by an apparent dissatisfaction among
some with the competition authorities in the way they take cross-media
market power into account:
"What we proposed at Enders Analysis was
to address what is the cross-media problem
the regulators
have tended very much to concentrate on market share with individual
media: the press, video games, or whatever. But, in fact, a lot
of the strengths of an operator in these markets can come from
its presence in more than one market."[110]
112. As noted above, our view is that issues
such as this have been unhelpfully blurred with the debate over
media plurality when in fact they are matters running parallel
to it, reflecting perhaps a frustration with the way the competition
authorities have conducted recent assessments of the media market.
WHICH ARGUMENTS ARE USED BY OPPONENTS OF THE ENDERS
PROPOSAL?
113. A range of objections to the Enders approach
have been put to us. Firstly, the breadth of the market to which
the Enders cap would apply is reasonably large and some have argued
that it would, contrary to its own aims, permit alarming concentrations
of power. Taking the 2010 data which Enders cite in their written
evidence, a 15% cross-sector revenue cap would not be crossed
even if a merger were to take place between all of the following:
all Non-News International national newspapers, all of the UK's
regional newspapers, and 50% of radio services. Similarly, taking
the 2015 (projected) data they cite, the cap would not be crossed
if a merger were to take place between all of the following: all
non-News International national newspapers, all regional newspapers
and one of either a) all consumer magazines or b) all radio services).
Concern with this aspect of the Enders proposal was expressed
by a number of witnesses. Dr Craufurd Smith told us that
the Enders approach "is not in itself sufficient, because
you could have one company that completely dominates news and
the newspaper sector and the Enders approach does not pick that
up."[111] Similarly
Dr Hardy of the Campaign for Press and Broadcasting Freedom
told us that a "central concern is that if you include in
the calculation book publishing and video games, the market is
defined so broadly the net impact would be too liberalising."[112]
114. Second, others have argued that the use
of a single metric across the total market assumes equivalence
between genres which is not necessarily reasonable from the perspective
of plurality. It is implicitly the case in the Enders approach
that different genres of media are like for like, such that £1
of revenue from video games is seen as equivalent, for example,
to £1 gained from news and current affairs. This does not
reflect the special nature of news and current affairs in the
context of media plurality policy as explained in the chapter
on Scope. Asked whether the Enders proposal assumes equivalence
between genres in this way, Chris Goodall of Enders told us himself
that: "In terms of ability to dominate a market and act as
the gatekeeper, approximately, yes."[113]
115. Third, others have highlighted potential
problems associated with a cap in general terms, particularly
one that applies to revenues gained beyond NCA:
"It is tempting to seek a simple, single
metric with a 'bright line' threshold for sufficiency. Italy,
for example, sets a maximum share of revenues (across a wide set
of media related industries). However, such tests are too crude.
In particular it unfairly penalises those with interests beyond
news. For instance, why should ITV's ability to acquire other
entities be blocked because it happens to have substantial revenue
from Downton Abbey and other general TV? Clearly these revenues
are quite unrelated to influence over the news agenda or the debates
of the day."[114]
116. Fourth, caps are also argued by some to
be too inflexible:
"
ownership regulation has produced
perverse outcomes where media outlets have been forced to close
rather than to continue under new ownership (albeit more concentrated
ownership): a striking case in point arose following the merger
of EMAP and Scottish Radio Holdings."[115]
117. Fifth, implementing a revenue cap would
also confront practical challenges. Neither determining relevant
revenues (eg. of international companies providing services in
the UK) nor extracting them from those beyond UK jurisdiction
would necessarily be straightforward.
"This would be more difficult to administer
than some other aspects. But let us say you were dealing with
a non-UK, non-EU-based platformcall it Facebook or Googlethat
carries advertising. That advertising is for a product where the
money is paid in Ireland, just as an example. So there are undoubtedly
going to be issues about where that revenue was acquired and whether
it represents media industry revenue in the UK. I believe it is
not beyond the wit of a regulator to get on top of that."[116]
118. Additionally, some have argued that revenues,
technically speaking, are an inappropriate metric for assessing
the diversity of the media market:
"What does revenue have to do with anything?
Then you have to decide which bits of revenue. Why should it matter
that Sky sells hardware to its customers on multi-room subscriptions
or landlines or telephony or broadband? That makes up over a third
of all Sky's revenue. What do we include and what do we exclude?
If you have bundled products, how do you divide them? To say that
15.1% of media revenues gives you complete dominance, blimey,
we could have six organisations with complete dominance of the
media industry according to Enders Analysis. It just does not
make any kind of sense at all."[117]
119. Finally, as noted before, much of the case
put for a conceptual shift towards positive intervention to promote
media diversity is triggered as a reaction against the arguments
used for caps, and therefore against proposals such as that made
by Enders. Professor Richard Collins and Martin Cave, for
example, claimed that "Rather than conceiving of media pluralism
as an objective to be realised by prohibiting mergers, it should
be thought of as pointing towards intervention designed to facilitate
and encourage entry."[118]
THE COMMITTEE'S VIEW
120. Certainly, we have no disagreement with
the motivation to find a simple, user-friendly way accurately
to measure and bring about plurality in our media. We must admit,
however, to remaining somewhat sceptical that the Enders model
would achieve it. In particular, while 166 ways of measuring plurality
(as recommended by the European Commission's report, authored
by Peggy Valcke)[119]
is surely overkill, we are not entirely persuaded that a concept
as complex as plurality can legitimately be reduced down to one.
121. Following on from that, it may be clarifying
to say that it was the Enders proposaland others like itwhich
prompted our arrival at the principle stated at the beginning
of this chapter: that the assessment of plurality should drive
the decision about which remedy or intervention is appropriate,
not the other way around. It is inherent to an approach based
on statutory caps that the decision about which remedy or intervention
is appropriate (for its proponents, a cap) drives the way in which
plurality should be assessed (an arbitrary and potentially misleading
single metric in whose terms the level of the cap has to be set).
Plurality is unfortunately a more complex concept than that; it
cannot be reduced down to a single figure. For example, beyond
a simple numerical assessment of the share of the market accounted
for a media enterprise, a plurality assessment might also consider
the diversity and range of independent news voices; overall reach
and consumption and propensity of consumers actively to multi-source;
barriers to entry and competition to spur innovation; economic
sustainability and so on.
122. In addition, the Enders approach appears
to be motivated by a frustration with the way the competition
authorities do their business when it comes to the mediawhich
may or may not be a legitimate gripebut competition policy
and plurality policy are not the same thing as we have already
explained, and therefore the sorts of arguments put forward do
not form, we think, a sensible basis for constructing a plurality
policy. In a nutshell, the counter-arguments seem to us to outweigh
those in its favour.
Hybrids
123. As noted above, a cap has been proposed
both as a stand-alone measure, as in the Enders model, and as
a single element within a hybrid package of measures. Below are
a number of questions which arise in relation to hybrid approaches
which have been put to the Committee.
WHAT IS A HYBRID APPROACH?
124. A hybrid approach is one which incorporates
structural and behavioural remedies. Structural remedies involve
absolute "bright line" limits, also known as caps; behavioural
remedies oblige media enterprises to introduce certain practices
or controls to their operations.[120]
125. More specifically, the standard hybrid approach
sets two quantitative thresholds in terms of market share: companies
breaching the lower % may be subject to certain behavioural remedies,
while companies breaching the higher % will be subject to structural
remedies.
"the hybrid role would be both structural
and behavioural
this is something that
Harriet Harman
talked about it in her speech at the Charles Wheeler Lecturetwo
bright lines. The first would be a trigger where you would say,
'you have gone above that level, but that is that point at which
you are going to obliged to commit to certain'I do not
know if I would call them behavioural remedies 'certain
obligations'. There is another bright white line that says "thus
far and no further". At that point it is becoming too uncomfortable
for democracy to allow someone with that much circulation of national
newspapers or that much share of the national television audience
to be in one person's hands or one private company's hands. At
that point we are saying, 'We are going to have to ask you to
divest'. It is important to have that rule and that cap."[121]
WHICH HYBRID PROPOSALS HAVE BEEN PUT TO THE COMMITTEE?
126. Three hybrid approaches have been put to
the Committee: one by the Media Reform Coalition (MRC); one by
the Campaign for Press and Broadcasting Freedom (CPBF); and one
by Avaaz. Rt Hon Harriet Harman QC MP has appeared to support
something akin to these approaches in her recent public statements
as well.[122]
127. The three proposals have distinctive features
but share much in common. An important distinction lies in the
percentage at which they set their thresholds. For the MRC they
are set at 15% and 20% of audience share; for the CPBF at 15%
and 30% of market share; and for Avaaz at 20% of either audience
size or revenue. Unlike the Enders proposal whose 'bright line'
limit applies to the 'total media market', the MRC, CPBF and Avaaz
models set their thresholds within specific sectors or 'designated
media markets.' Dr Hardy of CPBF set out that "we favour
an approach that identifies designated markets, such as news and
television services, rather than a total market approach such
as Enders has proposed."[123]
He explained his view that:
"there is real diversity across the cultural
industries. Diversity in terms of content creation: how the economics
of the business work, how goods are sold, what kinds of control
are exercised. We have real concerns about trying to put all of
that together into a single total market calculation"[124]
Similarly the MRC told us that "the key sectors
for news and current affairs include newspapers, television, radio
and online news. Plurality should be measured based on standard
audience share indicators."[125]
Avaaz made a similar point, arguing that "the key sectors
for applying these limits are those through which news and current
events are most commonly consumed: newspapers, online news, television
and radio."[126]
128. However, both the CPBF and MRC proposals
do see merit in the Enders model (or a refinement of it focussing
on the total news market) as a cross-media measure to sit alongside
their hybrid approach which focuses on designated markets. The
MRC explain in written evidence that:
"when it comes to measuring cross-media
power we clearly need a single, one size fits all approach. To
this end, we support proposals put forward by Enders Analysis
to base the measure on a share of total cross-media revenues (Enders
Analysis 2012). This is the simplest and most effective indicator
of overall dominance."[127]
Amending this, Dr Hardy of CPBF told us that
"we would not suggest a total market measure along the lines
Enders has suggested. There is a suggestion floated, for example,
to define a total market in news across all platforms and set
a cap there of 15%. I am much more sympathetic to that approach."[128]
UNDER THESE HYBRID MODELS, WHAT WOULD HAPPEN WHEN
A DESIGNATED MARKET THRESHOLD IS BREACHED?
129. While the MRC, CPBF and Avaaz proposals
place their thresholds at different levelsand indeed the
Avaaz proposal is different in only having one thresholdthey
recommend similar remedies and interventions at the point at which
they are breached.
130. For the CPBF, at a lower threshold,
"the kind of obligations range from what
you could call light to strong. At the light end, we think they
should include compliance with things like codes of conduct agreed
across an industry. They should also include some commitment to
basic working conditions and pay. I think that is an important
issue across the creative industries. A little bit higher up the
scale
agreements at the level of the firm to open up access
to other suppliers, to independent providers and so on. At the
strong end of the market, we think there needs to be divestment
and change of ownership
All of these measures have to trade
off viability with ensuring public interest standards. We think
some flexibility there about what measures are used is the right
approach."[129]
131. Similarly the MRC told us that:
"a first level threshold within sub-markets
should be a 15 percent audience share, triggering behavioural
remedies in the form of public interest obligations. These should
be aimed principally at ensuring journalist and editorial autonomy
within dominant news organisations so that owners and shareholders
cannot exert undue influence over news output."[130]
132. At the higher threshold, both talk about
transfers in ownership. The MRC told us that:
"where a single outlet or group of outlets breach
a given threshold of 20 percent, steps should be undertaken to
ensure that no single entity or individual has a controlling share
of that title or group of titles. The particular advantage of
this approach is that it is aimed specifically at limiting the
influence of powerful interests
shareholder dilution or
equity carve out could genuinely increase internal plurality,
as civil society groups and socially-oriented investors (such
as pension funds) may well take up the opportunity to buy released
shares in order to hold media companies to account."[131]
133. Similarly, Dr Hardy of CPBF told us
that "At the top end, we believe that private operators should
not have greater control than 30% as an absolute maximum. At that
point, firms would need to be reconfigured into public trusts,
co-operative ventures and so on, so that a private entity stayed
within a 30% threshold."[132]
134. With only one threshold, the Avaaz proposal
envisages a slightly different process. In this, "any entity
that already has now or in the future achieved more than 20 per
cent of a sector would undergo a public interest test that could
result in either forced divestment or special regulatory measures
to ensure it operated in ways that promote rather than undermine
democracy."[133]
In other words, there is no lower and upper threshold to trigger
consideration of behavioural and structural remedies separately.
Instead, the single threshold is used to trigger a consideration
of whichever remedieseither behavioural or structuralare
most appropriate in that case. The implication of their evidence,
however, is that the default intervention to be imposed on a media
enterprise breaching the 20% threshold would be a structural divestmentnot
least because they describe their threshold as a market 'cap'and
that in a case of breach, "it is up to media companies to
make a compelling case if they disagree [with blocks on consolidation]."[134]
135. All three groups argue that while the BBC
could breach the designated market thresholds, the mechanisms
through which the BBC and its role are considered should be entirely
separate, as noted previously in the chapter on Scope. For them,
this is because the BBC is already obliged to commit to a significant
degree of public service regulation and the provision of some
level of internal plurality. The thresholds are intended only
to apply to media enterprises not subject to such regulation.
As Dr Hardy of CPBF explained, "we believe that the
mechanism to deal with the BBC's market presence and any problems
that arise from that should be handled elsewhere
So the
market thresholds that should apply to other market actors should
not include the BBC"[135]
136. Similarly the MRC told us that "There
is a need to ensure that dominant media voices which are not subject
to public service regulation are nevertheless committed to maintaining
a degree of internal plurality and accountability."[136]
137. It is also clear that the hybrid approach
is intended to target the national media rather than local or
regional enterprises, where its proponents suggest a different
set of criteria and a different model would be required.
"At the local level, I think the criteria
have to be different, which is, "How do we shore up the kinds
of media enterprises that we want and need?" Not necessarily
just for plurality, but just so that there are some local news
information sources that exist."[137]
WHAT MOTIVATES PROPONENTS OF A HYBRID APPROACH?
138. Proponents of a hybrid model are clearly
motivated by a range of concerns relating to media plurality policy.
Some of these are inevitably shared with those favouring a pure
cap-based model (see above), e.g. to remove discretion from the
Government and regulators when it comes to measuring media plurality
and to draw a symbolically significant line in the sand for UK
democracy. In addition, they believe in the need for flexibility
in the interventions imposed on those with a share of the market
growing between the fixed thresholds, as these should, in their
view, be targeted at demonstrating a principle: that with increasing
share of media markets comes increased public responsibility.
139. First, it is clear that 'hybridists' share
some of the same motivations as proponents of a cap-based model.
As the MRC put to us:
"to shy away from establishing ownership
thresholds is to place unnecessary powers of discretion in the
hands of regulators and ministers. In the absence of clear ownership
thresholds, established in law, the door will always be open to
both commercial capture (politicians may be induced to take certain
decisions under pressure from media groups) and/or politicization
(certain media groups may be unduly favoured or disadvantaged
by political decisions)."[138]
140. In addition, their approach purposefully
builds in a degree of flexibility in order that public interest
obligations can be targeted at ensuring the principle is met:
that with greater media market share comes greater public responsibility.
Dr Hardy of CPBF told us that "the guiding principle
of our approach is that with size and reach comes responsibilities.
Those providing media content or public communication services
are providing services that matter for democracy, for social and
cultural life, for the creative economy."[139]
He added that between the two thresholds "the key point
is the degree of flexibility. All of these measures have to trade
off viability with ensuring public interest standards. We think
some flexibility there about what measures are used is the right
approach."[140]
This flexibility is evident in the Avaaz approach too where they
contemplate that it should be possible for a media enterprise
to breach its 20% threshold as long as it were possible to demonstrate
that a "breach [of] the 20 per cent limit was in the public
interest."[141]
WHICH ARGUMENTS ARE USED BY OPPONENTS OF HYBRID APPROACHES
TO MEDIA PLURALITY POLICY?
141. While the cap envisaged by 'hybridists'
applies only to designated markets rather than to a total media
market, many of the arguments made against a pure cap-based model
apply to the upper "bright line" limit in the hybrid
model. These were rehearsed above. A number of additional challenges
to hybrid approaches have been put to us, arising specifically
from the distinctive features of their proposals.
142. For example, it has been put to us by a
number of witnesses that fixed thresholds are unsuitable for markets
as dynamic as the media. The exit or decline of one company is
inextricably linked to the increasing share of others. Under a
system of fixed thresholds, it seems possible that relatively
arbitrary conclusions could be reached about the plurality concerns
raised by a media enterprise between one day and the next; whether
this were to lead a regulator to intervene or simply to undertake
an investigation, the unpredictable and arbitrary nature of the
trigger would have inevitable consequences for innovation and
investment.
"Intervention in such cases might penalise
success or act as a disincentive to growth and innovation. Given
market volatility, there would be a risk of constant reviews,
which might then have a chilling effect on investment and innovation."[142]
143. Some argued, from a purely practical perspective,
that the implementation of behavioural remedies may be an appealing
idea in principle, softer than the structural options to impose
divestment, but would be extremely hard in practice to agree,
monitor or enforce.
"I think what he [Dr Hardy] has proposed
ends up being too complicated and its regulation extremely difficult
to administer. In a perfect world, it might be the right way to
go. I fear it would impose strains upon any regulator that was
asked to administer it, and it would prove impossible to deal
with."[143]
144. Others have argued that setting a share
of designated markets above which obligations begin to be introduced
struck some as implying that plurality policy would be driven
by a decision on the part of the Government or regulator about
what citizens' and consumers' choices should be rather than leaving
such decisions to citizens and consumers themselves:
"You have to be very careful before you
start bringing in share because you are effectively determining
what number of people is the right number to have freely chosen
what kind of news service they want to consume. We are generally
driven by the view that consumers are free to choose. So long
as they have a range and a sufficient number of choices, that
is up to them."[144]
145. In addition, not all witnesses were persuaded
of the fairness of allowing the BBC to breach such thresholds
while others cannot.
"We are very nervous about the idea that
you can come in and determine what the right share is because
you are effectively calling into question the free choice of the
customers. Of course, if you go down that route, you run into
the issue of the BBC because its share is, by some margin, greater
than anybody else's."[145]
THE COMMITTEE'S VIEW
146. In their favour, the hybrid approaches seem
designed to avoid the undisguised arbitrariness of the Enders
model. We must admit, however, to finding a good number of the
challenges we have heard raised against them difficult to overcome.
In particular, some of the arguments used against a cap-based
approach seem to apply here too: in assessment, the relatively
arbitrary and potentially misleading reduction of the concept
of plurality down to one metric in whose terms the thresholds
must be set. This breaches the principle which we consider to
be important that the assessment of plurality has to be free to
drive the decision about which remedy or intervention is appropriate,
not the other way around. It is inherent to an approach incorporating
statutory caps that the decision about which remedy or intervention
is appropriate drives the way in which plurality has to be assessed.
In our view, only drawing on one single metric to assess plurality
is insufficient. As we noted above, beyond a simple numerical
assessment of the share of the market accounted for a media enterprise,
a plurality assessment might also consider the diversity and range
of independent news voices; overall reach and consumption and
propensity of consumers actively to multi-source; barriers to
entry and competition to spur innovation; economic sustainability
and so on.
147. Moreover, we cannot help but think that
for a framework of plurality interventions to work in the real
world, it will have to find some mechanism for taking the dramatically
different traditions of each medium into account, and unfortunately,
we are unable to see that these approaches would garner very wide
acceptance. We can see the arguments in favour of behavioural
remedies being in the armoury of the regulator when considering
how to intervene in the interests of plurality. However, taking
into account the need to find a way to enforce them and to monitor
their effectiveness, an approach which places them front and centre
is likely to create more problems than it solves.
Ofcom's Proposal
WHAT IS OFCOM'S PROPOSAL?
148. Ofcom's proposal can be found in two documents
submitted in response to specific questions and requests for advice
on the question of media plurality from the Secretary of State.[146]
One of these questions was: "What could trigger a review
of plurality in the absence of a merger?" Ofcom considered
the merits of different triggers and concluded that there was
a good argument for the introduction of a new plurality review
to be conducted on a periodic basisnot triggered by a particular
event but by the regular lapse of time.
149. A point of clarification may be helpful.
Ofcom envisaged "a periodic review of media plurality (undertaken
every four or five years), operating alongside the provisions
of the existing merger-based public interest test."[147]
Having only been asked a limited set of questions about non-transactional
triggers for review, Ofcom did not go so far as to contemplate
any changes to the existing arrangements for the Public Interest
Test.[148] Ofcom recognised,
however, that the establishment of a periodic review would raise
questions about how two different reviews, one periodic and one
transactional (under the current arrangements, the Public Interest
Test), would influence and potentially risk overlapping each other.
As it wrote in its supplementary advice to the Secretary of State,
these considerations would merit further consideration, although
Ofcomrightlyconsiders these to be matters for Parliament
and the Government:
"In our June report, we said that further
consideration was required to determine whether the existing merger
process sits within a new plurality regime or continues in parallel
with it. Either scenario may be desirable, but in any case, the
regulatory framework needs to be consistent and avoid a double
jeopardy outcome such that more than one plurality review is triggered
by the same cause. We believe that these matters are fundamentally
a matter for Parliament and the Government."[149]
150. Accordingly, Ofcom's proposal should not
be taken as a wholesale redesign of media plurality policy where
some other proposals put to this Committee have been. Instead,
it should be seen as the response to some specific questions from
the Secretary of State. The standout features of this response
are the introduction of a new periodic plurality review to be
undertaken every four or five years and beyond this, aspects of
the specification for this review, some of which we consider below.
WHY DOES OFCOM ARGUE FOR THE INTRODUCTION OF PERIODIC
REVIEWS?
151. In response to the Secretary of State's
question noted above, Ofcom analysed four options for triggering
a review:
· a
metric-based trigger, which would require a plurality review to
be carried out if organic growth resulted in a specific metric
being breached;
· a time-based
trigger, which would require a plurality review to be carried
out automatically on a periodic basis;
· an event-based
trigger, which would require a plurality review to be carried
out at the time of a specific event; the current arrangements
for the Public Interest Test fit into this latter category; and
· discretion,
which would require a plurality review to be carried out at discretion
of an appropriate authority.
152. They provide a thorough analysis of the
pros and cons of these options in their advice to the Secretary
of State[150] and ultimately
argue that the most suitable of these is a time-based review.
Their reasoning is two-fold. First, this avoids many pitfalls
of the alternatives which we do not rehearse here; they are articulated
clearly and in some depth in Ofcom's report. Second, a time-based
review also provides a positive mechanism by which the impact
of organic change can be captured while still ensuring that a
measure of certainty, simplicity and transparency can be provided
to all stakeholders. We heard no evidence to dispute these specific
points other than the general countervailing views we address
below.
HOW OFTEN WOULD A PERIODIC REVIEW NEED TO BE UNDERTAKEN?
153. There is at least one risk associated with
a time-based trigger for a plurality review identified by Ofcom
in their advice to the Secretary of State: the capacity of a periodic
review to deal with the impact on plurality of rapid organic change.
"In a market driven by rapid change in technologies
and consumption, it is possible that a review may be required
that would not be triggered by a defined event, and that could
not wait until the next periodic review. While the normal expectation
is that organic change is slow, this is not always the case. For
example, if consumption of news were to switch rapidly from newspapers
to tablets, this could have a significant effect on plurality,
over a short timescale, and without being caught [by the existing
merger-based public interest test]."[151]
154. In light of the potential for rapid organic
change, Ofcom suggests that the key question which follows is
the length of time between periodic reviews.
"Setting it too frequentlyto three
years or lesswould create a cycle of near-perpetual review,
which would be potentially wasteful and a disproportionate burden
on industry. Setting it too infrequentlygreater than five
yearswould risk the trigger not being effective, due to
the pace of change in the market. Neither scenario looks sensible;
we recommend that the timetable for a periodic review be every
four or five years, with the frequency set by Parliament."[152]
155. We did not receive any evidence, suggesting
an alternative time interval.
WHO WOULD BE INCLUDED IN A PERIODIC PLURALITY REVIEW?
156. Ofcom is in agreement with some of the substantial
conclusions we reached in the previous chapter on Scope: that
plurality policy should focus on news and current affairs and
be open to assessing the impact of online media:
"We remain of the view that news and current
affairs play the primary role in delivering the public policy
goals"[153] associated
with media plurality and that "these genres should be considered
across television, radio, the press and online."[154]
HOW WOULD PERIODIC REVIEWS MEASURE PLURALITY?
157. Before an answer to this can be given, a
preliminary question has to be addressed: to what extent should
the measurement framework including the metrics to be used in
a plurality review be prescribed to the body conducting that review?
There are two broad approaches:
· either,
to set down in statute the designated metrics to be used as part
of any plurality review assessment;
· or alternatively,
to set down guidance in statute for which principles and considerations
should be taken into account in determining the metrics to use
for a plurality review, and to instruct the reviewing body, as
part of its reviews, to take this guidance into account alongside
the market context in determining which metrics are most relevant
and useful for the purposes of any individual assessment at the
time.
Box 1
What is a metric?
In the context of this Report, metrics refer to measures
relevant to quantifying a news media market's plurality. In summary,
the range of metrics generally considered fall into three categories:
availability; consumption; and impact.
Availability metrics capture the number of providers
available at the point of Consumption. Consumption metrics capture
the number of people using news media, and the frequency or the
time they spend consuming it. Impact metrics need to capture the
influence of news content consumption on how people's opinions
are formed.
As Dr Craufurd Smith told us, "Ofcom identified
a number of different [metrics]. One is availabilitythe
number of individual sourceswhich is relatively easy to
count, but in itself will not tell you what the share or the potential
power and influence is of each of those particular sources. They
also talked about consumption, which in my view is probably a
rather more helpful metric if you are talking about influence.
That focuses on a number of potential features of a particular
market
and impact is the third one that they mention,"[155]
which, could provide very useful insight but, as Ofcom notes,
is challenging: "Our attempts to measure impact through quantitative
research have revealed complexity in how people's opinions are
formed."[156]
Accordingly, when it comes to impact, Ofcom concludes that "one
needs to assess a range of sources in the round and apply a degree
of judgement."[157]
158. In their advice to the Secretary of State,
Ofcom makes the case for the latter approach: that there are good
reasons for the precise set of metrics to be used in a plurality
review to be open to re-evaluation as part of each review itself,
taking into account their usefulness and relevance at the time.
"Given the dynamic nature of the news market,
the metrics framework itself should be assessed during each review
to ensure its continuing efficacy and relevance."[158]
159. As a result, Ofcom does not specify the
precise nature of the measurement framework for their periodic
review proposal. They suggest that determining this framework
would be an important task at the time of each review and that
this task would be likely to be most onerous at the time of the
first review. We note that in their recent consultation on Media
Ownership and Plurality, the Government mention their intention
to "commission the development of a clear measurement framework,
to be worked up in partnership with industry."[159]
160. Ofcom does, however, identify some characteristics
of the nature and number of metrics to be used. On the number,
Ofcom identifies a clear tension between economy and capturing
complexity. In other words, the choice of the number of metrics
is about finding the right balance between ensuring that they
are manageable and that they sufficiently reflect the complexity
of the state of media plurality. Across the evidence we received,
there appears to be a consensus that the appropriate number falls
somewhere between 5 and 15. Steve Unger, Director of Strategy,
International, Technologists and Economists, Ofcom told us that
"when you get to 100 you are doomed because you can no longer
explain what you have done. I think one or two is too few to capture
the complexity."[160]
Professor Picard gave a similar warning based on his experience:
"One of the strangest things I have ever
done as a researcher was the European Commission's measuring pluralism
report. We came up with about 170 measures. It can be done by
a regulatory agency; why they would want to spend six months doing
it, I do not know, because in the end you can actually do it with
half a dozen measures or so. Essentially, what you want to make
sure is that the viewpoints being represented in the media represent
across society."[161]
161. Similarly, Mr Foster told us that:
"from my experience as both a regulator
and working with media organisations, once you get past five or
six metrics or indicators, there is huge scope for reaching any
answer you would like to reach. The aim should be, notwithstanding
the complexities, to try to focus on a few key metrics and then
have a general discussion around these other issues."[162]
162. On the nature of the metrics to be used,
it is broadly accepted that there are three families of metric
available for the purposes of conducting a plurality review each
suited to measuring separately consumption, availability impact
metrics. For the meaning of metrics, see Box 1 above.
163. In their advice to the Secretary of State,
Ofcom argues that a plurality review will need to draw on a basket
of measures, including some from each of these families. In addition,
Ofcom suggests that limiting a plurality assessment to quantitative
measures would underplay the importance of contextual factors,
and for that reason the measurement framework of a periodic plurality
reviews would, they suggest, include a qualitative assessment
of factors such as "regulation and oversight, the potential
power or editorial control exercised by owners/proprietors within
commercial organisations, governance models, and internal plurality."[163]
HOW WOULD THE PERIODIC REVIEW DETERMINE WHETHER THERE
IS A PLURALITY CONCERN?
164. Ofcom's answer to this is clear: in order
to undertake a periodic review, it would require guidance from
Parliament on the definition of sufficient plurality. There are
two options: first, Parliament can lay down a tight definition
of sufficiency in legislation; or second, Parliament can lay down
general guidance and a narrative description of sufficiency, which
Ofcom can interpret and use as a qualitative benchmark against
which to assess the state of plurality at the time of each review.
165. We have not received a great deal of evidence
arguing strongly either case. However, some witnesses did underline
the basic point that it would be critical to provide some guidance
on the definition of media plurality for Ofcom to use in reaching
its conclusions.
"there would be value in Parliament providing
more guidance to Ofcom in the next Communications Act on what
is meant by "sufficiency" and the criteria to be used
by Ofcom in assessing whether it exists, either in applying public
interest tests or in its periodic reviews. For example, in defining
sufficiency, Parliament might wish to establish some guidelines
or benchmarks for the different market share indicators which
Ofcom could then use to inform its plurality assessments. Alternatively,
Parliament could express sufficiency in the terms suggested by
Ofcom in its recent report, which included a diverse range of
providers, high reach, active multi-sourcing and low barriers
to entry. Reflecting economic realities, there may need to be
different expectations for national and local medialocal
news markets may be unable to sustain the same degree of plurality
as national markets."[164]
166. Were a narrative description considered
most appropriate, Ofcom's own view is that any such description
would need to include a number of different features, including:
"a diverse range of independent news voices; high overall
reach and consumption with consumers actively multi-sourcing;
sufficiently low barriers to entry and competition to spur innovation;
economic sustainability and no single organisation accounting
for too large a share of the market."[165]
WHAT WOULD HAPPEN IF A REVIEW DISCOVERED INSUFFICIENT
PLURALITY?
167. Ofcom suggests that a range of remedies
might be relevant to address plurality concerns identified as
part of a review process.
"They can be grouped into five broad categories:
structural remedies that raise levels of external plurality; behavioural
rules that may help to increase levels of internal plurality;
behavioural rules that impose standards on providers of news;
behavioural remedies that improve access by citizens to providers
of news; and positive interventions to encourage more news provision.
There is unlikely to be a 'one size fits all' approach."[166]
168. However, they are clear that "It is
firstly for Parliament to consider the set of remedies which should
be available in principle within a new framework, and it is then
for the decision-maker tasked with selecting and implementing
remedies to determine which of these is best suited to a specific
set of circumstances" on a case-by-case basis.[167]
An important aspect of these considerations is whether there any
circumstances outside a transaction which could justify intervention.
Further, as noted above, it would remain to be determined how
interventions imposed through the mechanism of a periodic review
would stand in relation to any future transactional review. We
consider both of these points point in chapter 5, Our proposal
for a media plurality policy.
WHO SHOULD CONDUCT A PERIODIC PLURALITY REVIEW?
169. Two options have been suggested to us; plurality
reviews could be conducted either by the competition authorities
or by Ofcom. The Competition Commission itself suggested that:
"it (and in the future, the Competition
and Markets Authority (CMA)) is well placed to consider mergers
raising media plurality issues. It has the appropriate skills,
necessary expertise and economic awareness to investigate media
mergers, to report facts and either give advice to Ministers or
(should Parliament consider it appropriate in future) to determine
issues relating to public interest matters."[168]
170. By contrast, others have argued that, institutionally,
the competition authorities are not the appropriate bodies to
carry out the thinking required by a media plurality policy. Professor Picard
told us that:
"the Office of Fair Trading, and the Competition
Commission have the ability and skills to undertake appropriate
inquiries in areas involving ownership and mergers/acquisitions,
but their remits do not include continuous monitoring of broader
pluralism issues and the authority and tools to work to proactively
improve media pluralism. They also lack the organisational ethos
and capabilities for positively promoting media pluralism."[169]
171. The argument has also been made that: "regulators
while they do have independence, are very often very tightly
focused in their competencies to deal with things, or in the methods
that they can use to analyse things, or in the remedies they have.
If it gets thrown to a competition authority, they are going to
deal with it as a competition issue."[170]
172. On the other hand, others made the argument
that media plurality is a specific concern of media policy and
requires expertise in the communications sector.
"Ofcom was set up as a body with specialisation
in the communications industry, and it has specific statutory
obligations to take into account the interests of citizens and
consumers, as well as business. The competition authority has
competition powers and expertise in that field, but why do you
have a specialised communications regulator if, in a sense, it
cannot be the body that decides issues relating to the media?
This is a policy issue that relates to the media."[171]
WHICH ARGUMENTS ARE USED BY OPPONENTS OF OFCOM'S
PROPOSAL?
173. The opponents of this overall approach tend
to argue that (what they see as) important principles of their
own approach are ignored by it. Ofcom's proposal, for example,
gives a degree of responsibility to the regulator to devise at
each periodic review the details of the process to take. This
would appear to be unappealing to proponents of the Enders approach;
Chris Goodall, for example told us: "Whatever you decide
to propose, I hope you leave no discretion to anybody."[172]
174. Others have suggested that there is a risk
of periodic review being toothless; without clearly specified
thresholds at which intervention is automatic, a regulator may
be unlikely to act; as some have put it: "measuring media
plurality isn't enough."[173]
THE COMMITTEE'S VIEW
175. Our view is that Ofcom's proposal for the
introduction of periodic plurality reviews raises a number of
important questions about how such a system of reviews would interact
and avoid overlap with a system of transactional reviews. As such,
it also prompts the question: what would be the relationship between
periodic plurality reviews and competition processes which are
engaged in the current arrangements for a transactional review,
the Public Interest Test. However, the idea of the periodic review
itself has a number of features in its favour which make it preferable
to the alternatives which have been put to us. One feature in
particular stands out.
176. By placing at its core an assessment of
plurality, able to draw on a measurement framework incorporating
a limited number of different metrics as well as a qualitative
dimension, Ofcom's proposal is unique among the approaches put
to us in this inquiry. It is the only one able to live up to the
principle we set out at the start of this chapter: that the assessment
of plurality should drive the decision about which remedy or intervention
is appropriate, not the other way around. It provides a mechanism
whereby plurality can be assessed unencumbered by an arbitrary
commitment to a specific metric or intervention.
177. As noted above, some argue that this discretion
is its demerit. Our view, however, is that the flexibility required
for an assessment to do justice to the concept of plurality is
a more legitimate concern than a fear of regulatory discretion.
Of course, there may be merit in developing Ofcom's proposal further
to ensure that its discretion is exercised with good judgement
and under appropriate oversight.
178. Indeed, Ofcom's proposal is by no means
a complete one, as noted above. There remain a number of open-ended
questions to be thought through, some of which Ofcom has identified
itself:
· What
should be the relationship between periodic reviews and transactional
reviews?
· What
remedies should be available at the conclusion of a periodic plurality
review?
· What
circumstances outwith the context of a transaction could justify
intervention?
· In all
of this, how should the relationship between competition and plurality
policy be clarified?
- We will set out the way we believe
these questions can be answered in chapter 5, Our proposal on
media plurality policy. In addition, we leave to that chapter
our assessment of other aspects of Ofcom's proposal, including
the role for statutory guidance on the meaning of sufficiency
of plurality and on the design of the measurement framework.
73 A useful summary of the "20/20 rule" is
provided in the DCMS submission to the Leveson inquiry: Narrative
on media ownership. Available online:
http://www.levesoninquiry.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/2012/07/DCMS-submission_Narrative-on-media-ownership.pdf
Back
74
There are 15 regional Channel 3 licensees and one licensee providing
the national breakfast-time service. Back
75
David Elstein. Back
76
Q 94. Back
77
Q 14. Back
78
Ofcom, 5 October 2012, Op. Cit.
Back
79
Q 29. Back
80
Q 33. Back
81
Q 15 (Robin Foster). Back
82
Professor Richard Collins and Professor Martin Cave. Back
83
Q 42 (Professor Collins). Back
84
Q 33 (Professor Collins). Back
85
Q 42 (Professor Collins). Back
86
Q 44 (Professor Collins). Back
87
Q 71. Back
88
Q 49. Back
89
Q 72. Back
90
Q 227 (Mr Heath, BBC). Back
91
Q 249. Back
92
Q 414. Back
93
Q220 (Mr Heath, BBC). Back
94
Q221 (Mr Wilson, BBC). Back
95
Q227 (Mr Heath, BBC). Back
96
Select Committee on Communications, The Future of Investigative
Journalism (3rd Report, Session 2010-12, HL Paper 256). Back
97
Q 53. Back
98
Q 26. Back
99
Professor Picard. Back
100
Enders Analysis. Back
101
Enders Analysis. Back
102
Q 115. Back
103
Q 108. Back
104
Q 78. Back
105
Q 94. Back
106
Q 114. Back
107
Q 7. Back
108
Q 253. Back
109
Q 77 (Professor Barnett). Back
110
Q 108 (Mr Goodall). Back
111
Q 7. Back
112
Q 110. Back
113
Q 114. Back
114
Robert Kenny. Back
115
Professor Richard Collins and Professor Martin Cave. Back
116
Q 125 (Mr Goodall). Back
117
Q 253 (Mr Elstein). Back
118
Professor Richard Collins and Professor Martin Cave. Back
119
Independent Study on Indicators for Media Pluralism in the
Member States-Towards a Risk-Based Approach. Available online:
http://ec.europa.eu/information_society/media_taskforce/doc/pluralism/pfr_report.pdf Back
120
Further detail on the differences between structural and behavioural
remedies and real world examples of these can be found in Ofcom's
advice to the Secretary of State, Annex 2. Ofcom, 6 June 2012,
Op. Cit. Back
121
Q 94 (Professor Barnett). Back
122
Harriet Harman, Charles Wheeler Lecture, University of Westminster,
13 June 2013. Available online: http://www.harrietharman.org/charles-wheeler-lecture-on-media-ownership---130613 Back
123
Q 110. Back
124
Q 111. Back
125
Media Reform Coalition. Back
126
Avaaz. Back
127
Media Reform Coalition. Back
128
Q111. Back
129
Q 114 (Dr Hardy, CPBF). Back
130
Media Reform Coalition. Back
131
Media Reform Coalition. Back
132
Q 122. Back
133
Avaaz. Back
134
Avaaz. Back
135
Q 117. Back
136
Media Reform Coalition. Back
137
Q 71 (Professor Barnett). Back
138
Media Reform Coalition. Back
139
Q 108. Back
140
Q 114. Back
141
Avaaz. Back
142
Robin Foster. Back
143
Q 114 (Mr Goodall). Back
144
Q 191 (Mr Wheeldon, BSkyB). Back
145
Q 191 (Mr Wheeldon, BSkyB). Back
146
The two documents are the following: Ofcom, 6 June 2012, Op.
Cit. and Ofcom, 5 October 2012, Op. Cit. Back
147
Ofcom, 5 October 2012, Op. Cit. Back
148
Further detail on the regulatory context to media plurality can
be found in Appendix 4. Back
149
Ofcom, 5 October 2012, Op. Cit. Back
150
Ofcom, 6 June 2012, Op. Cit. Back
151
Ibid. Back
152
Ibid. Back
153
Ibid. Back
154
Ibid. Back
155
Q 7. Back
156
Ofcom. Back
157
Ofcom, 6 June 2012, Op. Cit. Back
158
Ibid. Back
159
Department for Culture, Media and Sport: Media Ownership and
Plurality Consultation, July 2013. Available online:
https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/225790/Media_Plurality_Consultation_2013.pdf Back
160
Q 397. Back
161
Q 23. Back
162
Q 23. Back
163
Ofcom, 6 June 2012, Op. Cit. Back
164
Robin Foster. Back
165
Ofcom, 6 June 2012, Op. Cit. Back
166
Ofcom. Back
167
Ofcom. Back
168
Competition Commission. Back
169
Professor Picard. Back
170
Q 26 (Professor Picard). Back
171
Q 9 (Dr Craufurd Smith). Back
172
Q 124. Back
173
Freedman, Professor Des (2012) 'Measuring media plurality isn't
enough.' LSE Media Policy Blog, 25 June 2012. Available
online:
http://blogs.lse.ac.uk/mediapolicyproject/2012/06/25/measuring-media-plurality-isnt-enough/ Back
|