Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum from Mr David Woodward, Freelance Development Consultant

1. Historical Background

  From the early 1980s until the middle of the 1990s, international efforts to deal with the debt crisis were seriously inadequate. Initially, this reflected an unrealistic insistence on the part of the major creditor governments (and the IMF) on dealing with the crisis as essentially a liquidity problem, even as it became increasingly apparent that the problem was one of solvency. While solvency-based elements (i.e., debt and debt-service reduction) were introduced in debt restructuring packages from the late 1980s, these proved to be seriously inadequate for low-income countries, for three main reasons.

  —  An arbitrary limit was imposed on the extent of debt reduction by government creditors, based on their own willingness to reduce debts rather than the extent of reduction needed to achieve debt sustainability and renewed growth.

  —  "Opt-out" clauses allowed some creditors (most notably the US and Japan) to avoid debt reduction altogether, by providing extended reschudulings at market interest rates.

  —  No mechanisms were available for the reduction (or even rescheduling) of debts owed to multilateral agencies, which represented an ever-increasing proportion of the debts of many low-income countries, as other financing sources dried up.

  In short, the debt strategy up to the mid-1980s was always too little too late; and the economic damage done to the debtor economies by their continued over-indebtedness (and to the international prices of their exports by their export-promotion efforts) weakened their ability to service their remaining debts, increasing the debt reduction needed still further. Had the Naples Terms been offered on bilateral debts (and the IDA debt-reduction facility been available for commercial debts) in the early 1980s, the debt crisis in the low-income countries could almost certainly have been resolved. For many countries, the enhanced (or even the original) Toronto Terms might well have sufficed.

  When it was first announced, the HIPC Initiative appeared to be a dramatic step forward. As well as offering the possibility of a reduction of multilateral debts for the first time, it moved away from the principle of reducing (bilateral) debts by an amount acceptable to creditors to the principle of reducing total debt to a level regarded as sustainable.

2. The HIPC Initiative: a Promise Unfulfilled

  Sadly, it is becoming increasingly clear that the initial promise of the HIPC Initiative will not be fulfilled, as a number of serious shortcomings have become apparent as the Initiative has unfolded. These are discussed in Attachments B, C and E.[16]

  1. The main indicator of debt sustainability used is the ratio of the net present value (NPV) of public and publicly guaranteed debt to exports of goods and services. This is a reasonable measure of the long-term balance of payments effect of the debt, but it has serious limitations as a measure of sustainability.

  —  It does not take account of other dimensions of debt sustainability (i.e., debt relative to fiscal revenue, production and savings/investment).

  —  It excludes a number of external liabilities which, for a given level of exports, have a similar effect on the balance of payments (notably private non-guaranteed debt and the stock of foreign direct investment and equity investment).

  —  In terms of the debt overhang effect on investment and growth, it appears to be the nominal value of debt rather than its NPV which has the greater effect.

  —  The NPV of debt is heavily dependent on the discount rates used, which fluctuate markedly over time. As a result, the extent of debt reduction (and thus of the "sustainable" level of debt) for each country may depend critically on the timing of the completion point.

  —  It has also been argued that the discount rates currently used are too high, although this has yet to be investigated.

  —  The three-year period over which export figures are averaged is too short to even out price fluctuations. Again, this makes the extent of debt reduction unduly dependent on the timing of the completion point, particularly for countries whose average export prices fluctuate markedly over time.

  2. The level of the NPV/export sustainability threshold is also open to question.

  —  The range currently proposed (200-250 per cent) is essentially arbitrary, and no analytical basis has been provided. The World Bank stated in 1994, on the basis of historical data, that NPV/export ratios in excess of 200 per cent had "generally proven unsustainable over the medium term".[17] This suggests that a figure substantially below 200 per cent would be appropriate in the context of the HIPC Initiative, as private non-guaranteed debt was implicitly included, and the sustainable level of debt is likely to have been reduced further since the pre-1994 period by the adverse effects of the debt overhang, and by increased stocks of foreign direct (and in one or two cases portfolio) investment.

  —  Within the 200-250 per cent range, the level set for each country is based on the application of an essentially arbitrary collection of "vulnerability indicators", apparently in a largely subjective way. Again, no analytical justification has been provided, either for the indicators used, or for the manner of their application. These indicators do not include, for example, direct or portfolio investment, nominal debt indicators, ratios of debt to savings or investment or human development indicators.

  —  The concept of sustainability now used is a very limited one: that a country should not need further reschedulings in the future, although this may be achieved only by continued access to large-scale balance of payments support. This makes no reference either to the effects of the post-HIPC debt on the debtor economy, or to the IMF's traditional concept of balance of payments viability (which also precludes balance of payments support).

  3. While a fiscal criterion (setting a sustainability threshold for NPV/government current revenue of 280 per cent) has, quite appropriately, been introduced, it is subject to very restrictive—and largely arbitrary—conditions.

  —  Only countries with exports of 40 per cent or more of GNP are eligible. Since the ratio of exports to GNP has no effect on the fiscal sustainability of a given level of debt, this rule has no obvious justification. It seriously limits the application of the fiscal criterion, as well as discriminating strongly against the poorest countries: only eight of the 41 HIPCs currently qualify; and only one of these is among the poorest two-thirds of HIPCs.

  —  The revenues used in this calculation are subject to a floor of 20 per cent of GDP. This is arbitrary, and in many cases unrealistic: in Uganda, proclaimed by the World Bank as the model of adjustment in Sub-Saharan Africa over the last decade, revenues remained below half this level in 1995; in Rwanda, local IMF staff saw anything significantly above 10 per cent as unattainable for the foreseeable future in 1996. In all, around three-fifths of HIPCs had revenues below this level in 1995; and once again the poorest are disproportionately affected. Three-quarters of HIPCs with revenues below the floor are among the poorer half of this group. (Neither is this relationship limited to HIPCs: among developing countries as a whole, only four out of 26 countries with GNP per capita at purchasing power parity below $1,200 had revenues in excess of 20 per cent of GDP in 1995.)

  —  The 280 per cent threshold itself is entirely arbitrary, having been set at such a level as to provide significant debt reduction for Côte d'Ivoire (for political reasons), while the restrictions noted above were designed to minimise the eligibility of other countries (for financial reasons). Once again, no analytical justification has been provided for the 280 per cent threshold; and there is no obvious reason to use a different figure from the NPV/export threshold.

  —  As with the export criterion, important liabilities are excluded from the fiscal criterion—in this case, domestic debts of the government. While their direct inclusion would be problematic, some allowance should be made for these liabilities in setting the overall threshold, and possibly in varying it between countries.

  4. Further problems are raised by the issues of timing and conditionality.

  —  No significant debt reduction beyond that available under the Naples Terms Initiative is to be provided until a six-year track record of structural adjustment has been achieved. This represents a deliberate delay in the potential benefits of the HIPC Initiative, as a means of reinforcing the IMF and World Bank's policy conditionality, at the expense of imposing further unnecessary costs on debtor countries through the debt overhang effect.

  —  While some past adjustment is to be counted as part of this track record, this is far less than the periods for which the countries concerned have actually been undertaking IMF and World Bank adjustment programmes. As a result, while many HIPCs had already undergone more than six years of adjustment before the Initiative was even announced, only two (Uganda and Bolivia) and expected to benefit before the year 2000.[18]

  —  The conditionality of debt reduction under the Initiative on structural adjustment raises a serious risk of further delays. Moreover, the appropriateness and effectiveness of structural adjustment as a development strategy for low-income countries remains unproven: at best, it leaves room for improvement.

  —  In both Bolivia and Burkina Faso, the decision point was delayed pending elections, until the new governments had been in office long enough to demonstrate that they were satisfactory to the IMF and World Bank. Apart from raising questions of legitimacy and sovereignty (since both were democratically elected) there is a risk that this will delay the completion point for these countries, and thus the reduction of debt for Bolivia. (Burkina Faso is in any case unlikely to receive debt reducing under the HIPC Initiative.)

  —  These delays leave the debt overhang in place, and will thus further reduce the sustainable level of debt (as well as being an obstacle to effective economic reform); but there is no allowance for any reduction in the sustainability thresholds over time. Significant delays will also mean that the NPV ratios are calculated on the basis of data for later years. If exports (or, for countries benefiting from the fiscal criterion, government revenues) are increasing in nominal terms, this will increase the level of debt deemed sustainable, and thus reduce the debt reduction received by the country concerned.

  5. Apart from questions about the level of the sustainability thresholds, the allocation of the designated debt reduction between different creditor groups is also potentially problematic.

  —  The rules envisaged for burden-sharing between bilateral and multilateral creditors, combined with the current Paris Club restrictions on debt reduction raise serious doubts about whether the debt reduction envisaged by the sustainability rules can be achieved in some cases (e.g., Mozambique, Nicaragua and Guinea-Bissau). There is a risk that this will leave debt at a level which is clearly unsustainable even by the HIPC Initiative's standards. At the very least, in the absence of a definitive solution to this problem, it is likely to cause delays for some countries, while the creditors wrangle over their respective contributions.

  —  There is also a serious question about how debt reduction by non-Paris Club bilateral creditors and the smaller multilateral creditors can be enforced. At present, it is simply assumed that the former will match Paris Club terms, and that the latter will match the terms offered by the IMF and World Bank. However, there is no mechanism available for ensuring their compliance; and there would seem to be a real risk of serious delays (again extending the debt overhang problem), and potentially of a disruption of the whole process.

  6. Experience to date suggests that there has been a substantial amount of political manipulation of the HIPC process.

  —  As noted above, the fiscal criterion was introduced essentially to provide debt reduction to Côte d'Ivoire, for which it would not otherwise have qualified, under strong political pressure from the French government. The rules were designed, and the threshold set, explicitly to provide a politically acceptable level of relief to Côte d'Ivoire, while minimising the additional relief provided to other countries, and thus the additional cost.

  —  The lack of transparency in the application of the vulnerability criteria was exploited to set the NPV/export thresholds for Uganda and Bolivia at exactly the levels below which burden-sharing problems would arise, apparently to avoid a dispute between the multilateral agencies and the Paris Club.

  —  The World Bank allegedly attempted to suppress local opposition to its Country Assistance Strategy for Mozambique by threatening to delay the HIPC process.

3. The Role of the IMF

  The IMF appears to have been motivated primarily by a desire to limit the cost of the HIPC Initiative to itself, and to delay the point at which it incurs such costs. This is largely because of the continuing problems in securing agreement to sales of its gold reserves, which would be necessary to finance a substantial contribution, due to strong German opposition. The delay in gold sales has already reduced the maximum amount which could be raised in this way (net of the compulsory contribution to the Fund's financial reserves) from $33 billion to $24 billion since they were first proposed in mid-1994, as a result of the dramatic fall in the world price. (The possibility of IMF gold sales to finance debt reduction is discussed in Attachment A.)[19]

  This has also led the Fund to "talk down" the potential cost of the Initiative, and to exaggerate the post-HIPC economic prospects of potential beneficiaries, by relaxing its traditional concept of financial viability, and by producing seriously over-optimistic projections for individual countries. (See Attachment C.)[20] These have, in particular:

  —  assumed overall export growth rates, sustained over the long-term, which are far greater than have historically been achieved by most low-income countries;

  —  assumed growth rates of commodity exports (notably Ugandan coffee) which, if replicated in other exporting countries, would appear seriously incompatible with the price assumptions for the same commodities; and

  —  assumed very large inflows of foreign direct investment while making little or no allowance for profit remittances in subsequent years.

  There is also no sign of any allowance having been made for the debt overhang effect on productive investment prior to the completion point.[21]

4. Overall Assessment

  In short, the HIPC Initiative, as originally conceived (or at least presented) had the potential to provide real benefits to the highly-indebted poor countries, by finally allowing the debt reduction available to catch up with what was needed to provide a basis for sustainable economic growth and human development. However, this potential has not been realised, primarily due to the efforts of the creditors to limit their respective shares of the costs, and to delay debt reduction as a means of enforcing conditionality and (in the case of the IMF) to delay the point at which costs are incurred.

  As a result, the debt reduction provided will be inadequate; the economic problems of the poorest countries will be extended unnecessarily into the future, at considerable economic and human costs; and it seems almost inevitable that there will ultimately need to be a new debt initiative to resolve the problem. However, the inadequacies of the HIPC Initiative as it is currently designed are concealed by the slow pace of its implementation, coupled with the IMF's over-optimistic projections.

5. What needs to be done?

  Some major changes in the HIPC Initiative are needed, and needed urgently, if the enormous economic and social costs of the continuing debt crisis of the poorest developing countries are finally to be brought to an end. Possible changes are discussed in Attachment F. 1

  As an immediate priority,

  —  the HIPC process needs to be accelerated considerably (e.g., by increasing the allowance made for past adjustment in assessing track records);

  —  the restrictions on the fiscal criterion (the exports/GNP rule and the revenue floor) need to be removed;[22] and

  —  the burden-sharing rules and restrictions on Paris Club debt reduction need to be revised, to allow debts to be reduced to the levels indicated by the sustainability thresholds.

  A strong case can also be made for

  —  lowering the NPV/exports and NPV/revenue thresholds;

  —  incorporating an automatic lowering of the thresholds over time, to take account of the effects of the debt overhang; and

  —  taking account of currently excluded liabilities (stocks of direct and portfolio investment and private non-guaranteed debt in the case of the NPV/export criterion; and domestic government debt in the case of the fiscal criterion).

  Serious consideration should also be given to

  —  reviewing the interest rates used as discounts rates in NPV calculations;

  —  extending the period over which exports are averaged;

  —  making the application of the vulnerability indicators in the estimation of the NPV/export criterion more systematic and transparent, and including human development indicators and nominal debt indicators;

  —  introducing a similar system for varying the NPV/revenue threshold; and

  —  introducing additional criteria relating to the ratio of the NPV of debt to production, investment and savings.

  If changes are made in the HIPC Initiative to provide additional debt reduction, then resources will need to be found to pay for this, from an accounting, but not necessarily from an economic, point of view.[23] Sales of IMF gold could make a substantial contribution to meeting the economic costs, and could usefully be pursued in parallel with the above changes. Even after the recent fall in gold prices, selling half of the IMF's gold reserves could double the debt reduction available under the HIPC Initiative.

  It will be easier politically to achieve changes in the HIPC Initiative sooner rather than later. It is currently expected that the first country (Uganda) will complete the HIPC process in April 1998, the second (Bolivia) following later in the year. Once these agreements have been completed, major changes in the criteria may require them to be reopened; and there is likely to be some resistance to this.

  This is not an absolute block on further progress: neither of the 1998 deals would need to be revised unless either the NPV/export threshold were lowered (or the period over which exports are averaged were extended); or the export rule and the revenue floor were removed and the fiscal threshold lowered. Nonetheless, the existence of completed agreements will be an increasing complication, both practically and politically, as time progresses; and the process of securing further changes in the HIPC framework will therefore become progressively slower and more difficult.

  At the same time, in the absence of substantial improvements, the inadequacy of the HIPC Initiative will increase, as the sustainable level of debt declines further due to the debt overhang effect and increases in non-debt liabilities. This suggests, firstly, that the extent of the changes needed will increase; and secondly, that growing awareness of the Initiative's inadequacies may make more radical reforms less unthinkable, even as modifications within the existing framework become more problematic. At some point, it may therefore become preferable to shift from seeking to improve the HIPC Initiative to seeking to replace it or to make more fundamental changes in its basic principles. One possible alternative approach to the fiscal criterion is outlined in Attachment G.[24]

6. A Footnote: the HIPC Initiative and Debt Conversion

  On a more minor point, the Committee may wish to be aware that the HIPC Initiative represents a serious complication to the conversion of bilateral debts for development, environmental and humanitarian projects. This is partly because of the principle of reducing debt to a specified level (which implies that converted debts would otherwise be cancelled, except in particular circumstances); and partly because of uncertainty about the extent of debt reduction until the completion point is reached. This is likely to cause a hiatus in debt conversions for HIPCs. (See Attachment D.) 1

Attachments[25]

  A. Woodward, D (1994) "IMF Gold Sales for Debt Relief". Paper for the Debt Crisis Network (UK), September.

  B. Woodward, D (1996) "Debt Sustainability and the Debt Overhang in Heavily-Indebted Poor Countries: some Comments on the IMF's View". In EURODAD, World Credit Tables, 1996: Creditors' Claims on Debtors Exposed. Brussels: European Network on Debt and Development.

  C. Woodward, D (1997) "The HIPC Initiative: Latest Developments". Note for the Jubilee 2000 Coalition, April.

  D. Woodward, D (1997) "Mutually-Beneficial Debt Conversion Using Bilateral Debt: What, Where and When?". Paper for the Royal Society for the Protection of Birds, October.

  E. Woodward, D (1997) "The HIPC Initiative: Presentation to the EURODAD Annual Conference, November 1997".

  F. Woodward, D (1997) "The HIPC Initiative: What Needs to be Done?". Note for the Jubilee 2000 Coalition, December.

  G. Woodward, D (1997) "Fiscal Criteria for Debt Reduction: Human-Development-Based Approaches". Note for the Catholic Fund for Overseas Development, December.

  H. Woodward, D (1997) "The HIPC Initiative: Effects of Changes to the Rules Governing the Fiscal Criterion". Note for the Jubilee 2000 Coalition, December.

David Woodward

Freelance Development Consultant

13 January 1997


16   Not herewith printed. A copy has been deposited in the Library (DR 2). Back

17   World Bank (1994) World Debt Tables, 1994-95: External Finance for Developing Countries. Washington D.C.: World Bank. Volume I, p40. Back

18   Burkina Faso is also expected to be eligible, but is unlikely to qualify for any debt reduction. Back

19   Not herewith printed. A copy has been deposited in the Library. Back

20   Not herewith printed. A copy has been deposited in the Library. Back

21   Until recently, the IMF questioned the existence of the debt overhang effect in low-income countries (IMF (1995) Official Financing for Developing Countries: Washington D.C.: IMF). However, the analytical basis for this view was at best questionable (Attachment B [Not herewith printed. A copy has been deposited in the Library.]); and the Fund has reportedly backed off from this position. A paper in a recent IMF publication has provided strong evidence in support of the debt overhang hypothesis in low-income countries (Elbadawi, I, Ndulu, B and Ndung'u, N (1997) "Debt Overhang and Economic Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa", in Iqbal, Z and Kanbur, R (eds.) External Finance for Low-Income Countries. Washington D.C.: IMF).  Back

22   The potential effects of changes in the rules governing the fiscal criterion are discussed in Attachment H. (Not herewith printed. A copy has been deposited in the Library.) Back

23   To the extent that the debts to be cancelled would not otherwise have been paid (or would have been paid only by the provision of grants, or of new loans which would not ultimately have been paid), there is no economic cost, as the money originally lent has already, in effect, been lost. If servicing the debts would otherwise have required highly concessional new loans, the economic cost of cancelling them would be limited to the NPV of these loans. Back

24   Not herewith printed. A copy has been deposited in the Library. Back

25   Attachments not herewith printed. A copy of each has been placed in the Library. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries

© Parliamentary copyright 1998
Prepared 14 May 1998