Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of witnesses (Questions 98 - 119)

18 MARCH 1998

ANN PETTIFOR and DAVID WOODWARD

Chairman

  98.  Good morning. Can I welcome both you, Ann Pettifor, and David Woodward to the Committee this morning and thank you straightaway for the very excellent briefing you have given us; some of it, I think, we are going to have to explore the detailed technical language used with you this morning, because I expect that, like some of my colleagues, some of these technical terms are unfamiliar to us and we do need to understand them, I think, to discuss them with you properly. We will ask questions but either one of you can answer the question, or both of you, but preferably not at the same time. I understand you would like to make a brief opening statement, both of you, and so perhaps I could ask you, ladies first, Ann Pettifor?
  (Ms Pettifor)  Thank you very much. I just want to begin by explaining where I am from. My organisation, the Jubilee 2000 Coalition, is an organisation here based on a coalition of really broad forces, mainly the churches but also the trade unions, the women's organisations, the Women's Institute, and black community groups in this country. But we are also an international organisation now and have very rapidly become so. You will know that the churches globalised some time before transnational corporations did, and through the churches we have spread very widely. We are collecting a global petition now in 69 countries and we have similar coalitions in about 40 countries, and we are very pleased that we now have got offices in five out of seven of the G7 countries, with staff; so we are putting pressure on other G7 creditors, as well as the British Government, of course. So it is really quite exciting and extraordinary how the British public have responded to our appeal to look at this issue of unpayable debt, and that was reflected in yesterday's Budget, when we were delighted to hear the Chancellor say that he wanted the millennium, and I quote, "to be remembered for the redemption of debt and the reduction of world poverty" and that was very heartening to us. We have done a quick calculation overnight, just to show how sharp we are, and we note that the Exchequer will provide something like £60 million, over the three years, towards Gift Aid, the charities for the low income, highly indebted countries that the Chancellor is targeting, and we note that it takes something like 18 hours for that money to come back from developing countries in debt service; it is less than what they pay in debt service every day. So that is a rather sharp little analogy. But the point is, while we are trickling down drops of charity to these countries, a flood of debt service is coming back, and it is that imbalance that we want to address in our contribution today. Now we have been told that DFID does, of course, give a great deal more aid than we believe and understand to be coming back to us in the form of debt repayments. One of the questions we would like your Committee to explore is how much of British Government aid is actually used to pay debts, how much of programme aid or balance of support aid is actually used by poor countries to pay debts to the IMF or the World Bank or to other major creditors; in other words, does British taxpayer money go into a country and fly back again to another northern treasury, or does it stay in that developing country as productive investment in that country? We think that is an extremely important issue for your Committee and these are facts that we have not been able to get out of DFID and Government Departments. We want to stress how very unjust, while we welcome the HIPC Initiative and we say that in our report, we would like in this session to show you how very unjust is the approach of northern creditors towards poor debtor countries, compared with their approach to other northern debtor countries. We want to compare the kind of debt relief that Britain was given after the second world war, which was substantial,—we were expected only to spend 4 per cent of revenues from exports to service our debts; Germany, which got massive debt relief only 45 years ago, was expected to spend only 5 per cent of her export revenues servicing debts. But, today, Britain and Germany sit on the Board of the IMF and in the Paris Club and insist that Mozambique spends 20 per cent of the pitiful revenues that she earns from cashew nuts and prawns to service her debts to rich northern creditors; and we want to, in this session, perhaps, draw out that injustice further. Another issue that excites us is the conditionality attached to HIPC, and we would like to draw to your attention a really important speech made very recently by the Chief Economist of the World Bank, in which he actually undermines a great deal of the principles of IMF policies in developing countries, he dismisses it as dogma which is no longer relevant and does not help economic development. These are really important points to be made by the Chief Economist of the World Bank, they have not received much publicity, and we would like to air them here with you today, because we feel that the conditionality attached to HIPC really undermines developing countries. We note, for example, that Rwanda is not even a candidate for debt relief because she does not have a good track record of IMF economic reforms. I visited the IMF, I think it was 18 months ago now, and spoke to the Head of Policy, Mr Jack Boorman, and asked why Rwanda was not on the HIPC list; and, I have to say, he and his officials did not quite burst out laughing but they did suppress a giggle, because, they said, Rwanda did not have an IMF track record and how could she be expected therefore to be eligible for debt relief? Now, pre-conflict, Rwanda had really quite a good economic record, it was not a left-wing regime, she was liberalising her economy, and the World Bank and the Fund were pleased with her track record; post-conflict, she is being penalised for her own civil conflict, and we think that is very unfair. So we would like the Committee to look at conditionality and to question the closeness of the links between these conditionalities and the dispersal of debt relief. Thank you very much.

  99.  Thank you. We are also interested in exactly the same questions as you are asking us, and we hope to get to the bottom of them; one of the purposes of our inquiry is to answer some of the very pertinent questions you have raised. Could you help the Committee immediately by telling us whether or not your Jubilee 2000 campaign is proposing that all debts be wiped out, forgiven, in the year 2000, without any conditions at all?
  (Ms Pettifor)  No; not at all. Our proposal, and our phrase, the phrase that we use, is that we are calling for the backlog of unpayable debts of the poorest countries to be written off by the year 2000; we have chosen the words "backlog of unpayable debts" very carefully, it is a portmanteau term. But, basically, we are saying, that debt, which you, Mr Chairman, know and we know and the Treasury knows and the IMF knows will never be repaid, cannot be repaid, but which is kept on the books because, in our international financial system, it is not possible to draw a line under debts and to write off those debts; they are kept on the books, the countries, if you like, are kept on the economic leash, through these debts, debt is the mechanism which gets the IMF into these countries, and we think that unpayable debt should be written off. So we may be well-meaning, do-gooding types, but we are not careless or irresponsible, we want that portion of debt written off, which everyone knows will not be repaid. And, when it comes to conditionality, we are, of course, concerned about IMF conditions but we are very clear that a very important condition must be that the debt relief must benefit the poorest sections of society; how that is done precisely is a matter still of debate, but we are very clear that that should be a condition of debt relief.

  100.  Yes. Well I think the Committee will want to explore that with you, because what is coming back to us, from our own constituents, is that you are in favour of simply writing off all debt, which is not what you are saying, as I understand it?
  (Ms Pettifor)  Not at all; yes.

  101.  Mr Woodward, would you like to make a short opening statement?
  (Mr Woodward)  Certainly. I should perhaps first clarify my status, to say that I am not an employee or a representative of Jubilee 2000 but rather an adviser to Jubilee 2000, so my views as expressed here, or indeed anywhere else, should not be taken necessarily as representing the views of the organisation, or the Coalition, as such. I would like to say a little about what I think the priorities are, in terms of securing changes to the HIPC Initiative. Initially, as originally formulated, it was a very welcome step forward in the debt strategy, for two main reasons: firstly, that for the first time it allowed a reduction of multilateral debts, including those owed to the IMF and the World Bank; and, secondly, and perhaps more importantly, it moved away from the earlier principle of reducing debts by an amount which was convenient to creditors to a principle of reducing debts to a sustainable level. In practice, as the Initiative has evolved, some very serious shortcomings have become increasingly apparent in it, and I think that some very major changes are needed if it is going to achieve those original objectives. I think there are three broad areas of changes which are needed: firstly, on timing; secondly, on the amounts of debt relief and the rules governing the amounts of debt relief; and, thirdly, on the burden-sharing between multilateral and bilateral creditors. On the question of timing, at present there are very long delays built into the whole process, with countries having to secure a track record of six years of successful structural adjustment; many of them have not started on that process yet. As long as this unpayable debt remains in place, it has a very serious negative impact both in economic terms, on investment, on growth and on development; and in social terms, on poverty, health and education; and deliberately to leave that debt in place for six years, essentially as a means of sustaining conditionality, on IMF and World Bank programmes—and Ann has referred to Mr Stiglitz' comments on that subject—I think that is a questionable policy. So I think the first thing is, there is a major need for acceleration in the process. Secondly, in terms of the amounts involved, in my view the priority on this is the fiscal criterion for debt reduction, primarily in terms of the restrictions which currently apply to its application. Firstly, it is only applicable to countries which have exports of at least 40 per cent of GNP. Now that is a completely artificial restriction, it penalises the poorest countries and the Sub-Saharan African countries disproportionately, and there is no rational basis for it. Even the IMF and the World Bank have accepted that it is essentially there to limit the costs of using this criterion. Secondly, there is a 20 per cent of GDP floor on the revenue which is considered for applying the fiscal criterion, and that has basically the same attributes of being arbitrary and perversely targeting, perversely penalising, the poorest countries. And then, thirdly, there is the question of the 280 per cent threshold for present value to Government revenues, which is arguably set too high. I think that is probably the order of priority for getting changes in those. Secondly, there is the question of the export criterion; again, the 200 to 250 per cent threshold is, essentially, arbitrary. Other liabilities which have a similar effect to debt, for example, the stock of foreign direct investment and private debts to overseas creditors, which are not guaranteed by Governments, are excluded from that calculation; whereas, in terms of the balance of payments, which is what the export criterion is supposed to measure, they have a very similar effect to the public and publicly-guaranteed debt which is included. I think there is also a case for a progressive reduction in those thresholds over time, if we cannot secure this acceleration by the year 2000, to reflect the economic damage which the continued presence of the debt overhang will cause in the interim. The third broad area is burden-sharing. At present, the 80 per cent limit on debt reduction by the Paris Club on eligible debts only, combined with the rules for burden-sharing between bilateral and multilateral creditors, limits the amount of debt reduction which can be given, and therefore in some cases, for example, Mozambique, may well stop even the optimistic sustainability thresholds under the Initiative from being achieved. So I think that needs to be resolved, in one way or another. Finally, if I may take a little more time, there are one or two points which I would like to raise, arising from some of the other submissions to this Committee and the previous evidence. Firstly, there have been arguments for allocating the expenditure which is to be saved by the HIPC Initiative to particular uses, specifically to health and education. I think it is important to note that there will only be money which can be reallocated if the debt is reduced below the level at which it is now being serviced, and that is unlikely to be the case under the HIPC Initiative as it stands. I think there is also a contradiction between that and the ECGD principle, which is that debt relief should be offered so as to maximise the stream of repayments to ECGD, because that necessarily implies an increase in the debt service which is being paid, in which case, by definition, there will not be debt service savings which can be reallocated to other uses. A second point: there was a reference to foreign direct investment as a mechanism for financing, and to ECGD guarantees to promote foreign direct investment. I think there are some fairly serious questions about the appropriateness of much direct investment for low income countries. In foreign exchange terms, it is quite an expensive form of financing: the rates of return, even in developed countries, where the risk is much lower, are in the order of 12 per cent per year; in developing countries where the risk is higher, clearly, multinationals will require a higher rate of return, and that is quite a high price to pay for foreign capital. Now in some cases it may be appropriate, but I think a selective approach and a fairly cautious approach is needed to viewing that as a future financing mechanism for low income countries. The third and final point I wanted to raise is the question of unilateral action by a single Government. I think that is something which, again, needs to be looked at quite cautiously. Given the principle of reducing debt to a specific level, if unilateral action reduces debt before that stage is reached there is a risk that the effect will simply be a saving on the debt reduction which is required from other creditors. So I think that needs to be looked at quite carefully and critically and on a case-by-case basis.

Chairman:  Thank you.

Dr Tonge

  102.  Could you explain that last point to me a bit more carefully, because we heard it from somebody else a few days ago, did we not, that debt relief unilaterally will lead—can you say it again, I am sorry, I have not really quite got, I know my brain has not quite grasped this one?
  (Mr Woodward)  Basically, if you are reducing debt to, say, $100 million, from $200 million, now if the UK reduces, say, wipes off, its debt of $10 million, then because that $100 million level is fixed, when it comes to the final settlement, the final cancellation, the debt will not actually be any lower. So what will happen is that the other creditors will reduce their debts from $190 million to $100 million, instead of from $190 million to $95 million, leaving $5 million for the UK. Does that help? I am sorry, I am not sure that is clear.

  103.  I think I understand.
  (Ms Pettifor)  Mr Chairman, can I just comment on that, because I think that is very technical and I think that it is a problem that exists anyway, under the HIPC Initiative, as it stands. There is a really important political issue, which is that should a Government take the lead internationally in writing off debts, and we think that that, in itself, will begin to put pressure on other Governments, and that pressure, in the end, might result in much greater debt relief. So I think we need to be very careful that we do not get bogged down here in technical calculations and disregard the international framework within which a British Chancellor, say, would take such action, because it would be a startling action and it would be an action of international leadership, and I think it would put enormous pressure on her fellow creditors within the Paris Club and the IMF.

Chairman:  Can I ask Mr Andrew Robathan; he has got an important question to ask you before he has to leave.

Mr Robathan

  104.  Can I apologise for leaving almost immediately after I ask this question, but I am afraid I have double-booked. I think we would all agree with what you say about wishing to see the reduction of world poverty, and, indeed, I cannot think of many people that would not. However, we have just returned, as you may know, from Africa, where we saw a rather different perspective than the one that you have put, in my opinion anyway, other people may have their own perspectives. I would personally think that Rwanda might indeed qualify as being a special case, because of the awful conflict they have had and now the dreadful position they find themselves in, and I think there is no point in trying to get blood out of a stone. However, in Uganda, which, of course, is maybe the first HIPC country to qualify, the central banker said to me, "Well, actually, we wanted to do this, because we want to be creditworthy", and this is a Ugandan speaking, not some import from the IMF, not just for further debt, because, of course, they all want to have further loans and they all want further aid, but also because of private investment, and it is not just wearing a hair-shirt and feeling macho, they understand that, in economic terms, if they are to be taken seriously, we cannot just say, "We'll get rid of the debt and now we'll lend you some more money, and we don't expect that to be repaid either." In Kenya, which I do not think is going for the HIPC Initiative, the central banker said to us, "Don't give us any more money, ask us what we did with the money we've had already" and he was talking about not just Kenya, he was talking about other African countries. Now, I have to say that in your submission, I have read both submissions, neither of you have referred to the responsibilities of the debtor countries, and, I think, Africans said this to us, it is slightly patronising to say, "Well, we'll just write off your debt", they would like it to be written off, of course they would, nobody wants to be saddled with debt repayments, it is slightly patronising to say, "We'll write off your debt, and then we'll treat you separately." I wonder if you would respond to that?
  (Ms Pettifor)  Can I just respond on the two points; the first point about creditworthiness. We often have this argument, especially from World Bank and IMF officials, that actually they cannot write off the debts because that lowers the creditworthiness of those countries. I would like to remind the Committee that this country, the United Kingdom, defaulted on $12.5 billion worth of debt, therefore we still owe the United States something which they calculate to be worth something like $30 billion worth of debt. It is, of course, post-first world war one debt, but we actually went into default; that did not inhibit our ability to attract further loans. In 1953, just 45 years ago, Germany was given massive debt relief; far from inhibiting her attractiveness to investors and to new capital, it was actually the basis of her economic recovery. And the third point is that, a country like Tanzania, Uganda is able to attract some investment, but her debt relief under HIPC will make her more attractive to new lenders; but Tanzania, at the moment, is not creditworthy, Tanzania cannot raise finance in the international capital markets because of her debt. So it would seem rather strange to say let us not give any debt relief to Tanzania because by doing so we would make her less creditworthy.

  105.  I am not saying that, actually, what I am saying is, what are the responsibilities of the debtor countries; now we did not go to Tanzania but I understand that Tanzania is rife with corruption?
  (Ms Pettifor)  Sure, and so are many of these countries; but we would like to point out that there are two sides to the lending coin, there are lenders and there are debtors, there are borrowers, and there is an awful lot of corruption on the other side of the coin, the corruption rests with those who are powerful. I would like to remind you that between 1981 and 1990 the IMF, the World Bank, the British Government and the American Government lent President Mobutu something like $6.8 billion dollars; now that was political lending, it was in pursuance of foreign policy objectives in relation to the Cubans in Angola: so be it. But, today, the ordinary people of the New Democratic Republic of the Congo are repaying that debt. Now Mr Mobutu was not able to raise $6.8 billion from his people. A Member of Parliament pointed out to me that one Kenyan Member of Parliament owns an Australian ranch; it is not possible to buy an Australian ranch with Kenyan shillings, you need US dollars for that. There are two ways of getting US dollars, either by expropriating your country's export revenues or by going to Washington to the IMF annual meeting, hiring a suite in The Sheraton, putting a secretary at the door and waiting for the bankers to queue, offering you loans. Now those loans are often for projects in those countries which are inappropriate for those countries. One of the very good things about Uganda is that loans are now submitted to her Parliament for scrutiny, but in most countries ordinary people do not hear about the loans for building a dam which is going to disrupt their environment and their lives, or of a road which is for the local MP, or the Armed Forces, or whatever, which actually also disrupts their lives, but which benefits the construction company building the project in that country. An awful lot of lending, particularly IMF, World Bank lending, is governed by what construction companies in the OECD countries want to spend their money on in developing countries. Now it is pretty tough for those local people, to blame them for the fact that elites on both sides, if you like, of the coin are colluding in order to incur greater debts in order to incur more lending and in order to raise more money for projects; ordinary people in Kenya find that this is beyond their control. I think people in Britain want to look at the way in which we have given loans, for example, to Indonesia, and I would commend the work of Mrs Clwyd, over the last period, in looking at the way in which we provided loans to Indonesia for arms. Now that President Suharto is turning those arms on his people, it ill behoves us to be critical of his lack of democracy, of his unaccountability, of his corruption, he indeed is corrupt, but he has been corrupted by a lending system, an international financial system, which has serviced him well. I just feel that we ought not to blame ordinary Africans.

  106.  I am not blaming ordinary Africans, I am blaming the Governments and the societies that have spent the money?
  (Ms Pettifor)  And also those who have disbursed it, is what I would suggest, Mr Robathan. We need to remember that there is co-responsibility of both creditors and debtors for this debt.

  107.  So you would back Governments not giving aid or loans to—sorry, you would back international organisations or individual Governments not giving aid to countries where the Government was not up to scratch, in our opinion?
  (Ms Pettifor)  I find that a difficult question.

  108.  Yes, it is, is it not?
  (Ms Pettifor)  Because by doing that we are punishing ordinary people, and personally I think that Africa needs both massive debt relief and a Marshall Plan. Africa has been through the equivalent of the 1930s, through the 1980s, and her people are dying and suffering for that, and the UNDP has said that 21 million children will die before the year 2000, or that their lives could be saved if money spent on debt service was converted into health and education, 21 million children's lives could be saved. Clearly, getting there, that is going to be difficult. But we, as British citizens, and as the British Parliament, need to look at our role in generating that debt before we look at the role of local corrupted elites. I think we just need to be a little more humble about the role that we have played, and the benefits we have accrued from making these loans, they have helped our balance of payments, they have helped protect jobs in export industries like the arms industry.

  109.  We have written off most of our bilateral debt, have we not?
  (Ms Pettifor)  No, we have not.

  110.  That is for certain what we were informed?
  (Ms Pettifor)  We have written off, and this is a very important point, a great deal of DFID debt, ODA debt, and for that the——

  111.  Bilateral debt, yes?
  (Ms Pettifor)  No, no; it is bilateral but it is bilateral aid debt. Ninety-five per cent of the debts owed to Britain are owed to the Export Credit Guarantee Department in the DTI and that has not been written off. That is the great burden of debt. And export credits are, of course, to promote, it is a subsidy, Mr Robathan, for promoting British exports.

Mr Robathan:  I understand that.

Chairman:  I am not certain Ms Pettifor answered your question.

Mr Robathan

  112.  I am not sure you answered the question about debt and responsibility. Do not necessarily think we all disagree with you, but I think you have put forward, if I might say so, a rather one-sided position?
  (Ms Pettifor)  I think the side which just blames the victim is one-sided.

  113.  I am not blaming the victims, I am blaming the people that misuse money?
  (Ms Pettifor)  We are saying that co-responsibility of creditors and debtors for the debt is the way we should look at it, if we are going to be truly fair in this approach.

Mr Robathan:  I think it is fair, too.

Chairman:  Anyway, I think we should end this conversation for a minute.

Mr Robathan:  Thank you; thank you very much for your tolerance.

Chairman

  114.  I do not know whether you have anything to add, Mr Woodward?
  (Mr Woodward)  Yes, I wanted to add just one or two points. Firstly, on the question of creditworthiness, debt cancellation will only affect creditworthiness to the extent that creditors expect it to happen again. Now that is a major part of the rationale behind the Jubilee 2000 campaign, which is to associate the debt reduction explicitly with the millennium, which will not set a precedent, at least for another thousand years, which is beyond most people's time horizons. But I think it is also important to have a more fundamental look at the international financial arrangements which we have at present, both to ensure that financial crises of this nature, or indeed of other possible natures, do not recur, and also to have in place ahead of time effective and clearly understood mechanisms for dealing with them, and for sharing the burden equitably between debtors and creditors, so that those making lending and borrowing decisions in the future will know how exactly the debts are going to be dealt with in the event of a financial crisis. That is something that was severely lacking during the 1970s when much of this debt was originally incurred, and I think the absence of that clear basis for international transactions was a major factor contributing to the debt crises, both in Latin America and in Sub-Saharan Africa. The other question which I would mention, which I also mentioned in my opening statement, with reference to attracting foreign direct investment, is, as I said, I think that this is less of a panacea than it is often seen to be, and that simply attracting in foreign direct investment does create long-term costs to the economy. In much the same way as, again, with the borrowing in the 1970s, one of the major incentives for overborrowing is that the Government in power actually gets the benefits of borrowing, but they bequeath those debts to their successors, and often their opponents. So there is, in that sense, an incentive built into the system to borrow as much as you can get away with. I think there is a risk that that is also happening with some types of foreign direct investment, particularly the sale of existing productive assets, as opposed to new productive capacity built on greenfield sites. On the question of debt and responsibility, certainly I would agree that the debtors have co- responsibility with creditors for the debt. If I did not mention it in my submission, it is perhaps that I take it too much for granted that, generally, one is responding to the view that it is the irresponsibility of the debtors that has caused the problem. It is also the irresponsibility of the creditors, and, in some sense, the creditors have less excuse. As I said, you have this incentive built into the system towards overborrowing; now the only way of controlling that effectively—I cannot see any other way round it—is restraint on the part of lenders, so that they do not lend more than can be repaid in the long term. I think that is the market failure which needs to be dealt with. As regards the use of funds, I think, also, in terms of debt and responsibility, it is important to remember that much of the debt was incurred by past Governments, and often unrepresentative Governments. In some cases their successors are little more representative, but nonetheless the debts were incurred by people who did not have the authority of the population. And, in most cases, most of the debt which has been incurred subsequently, over the last ten or 15 years, has essentially been used to service those past debts. So I think a great deal of the responsibility actually is not with current or recent Governments but with Governments going back perhaps ten, 15, 20 years, who incurred the original debts, which formed the basis for all the interest payments which required new borrowing. As regards corruption and democracy, I think it is important to mention that one of the major factors contributing to corruption and ineffective democracy, or lack of democracy, in many low income countries, is the debt itself: that the financial constraints which are there have led to extremely low Civil Service salaries, in some cases below the poverty line; they have led to poor education systems, low levels of literacy and often weak media. That is by no means the only reason for lack of democracy, but it is a contributing factor and I think quite a significant one, in a number of cases.

Mr Robathan:  I will let my colleagues ask nicer questions.

Chairman:  I think we should ask questions much more about the mechanisms that we are looking at and their appropriateness, rather than the rather emotive, political issues which we have been getting into. But can I ask Mr Dennis Canavan to continue our questioning.

Mr Canavan

  115.  Your submission, Jubilee 2000's submission, that is, to our Committee, argues that it is not possible for creditors to make disinterested and realistic projections on sustainability levels for debtors. If not creditors, who would be best placed to make these projections?
  (Ms Pettifor)  We believe, Mr Canavan, that we need a more independent and fair and transparent process for deciding what is a sustainable level of debt for a poor country. In domestic terms what we have in our legal system are Receivers—people who play an independent role within a legal framework for assessing the viability of the debtor and the viability of the amount of debt that can be repaid. In the international system, there is no-one independent. The IMF is both a creditor itself and also an agent of all creditors, both private creditors and, of course, Government creditors, and the IMF leads the decision about the sustainability of debt. We think that is very unfair because creditors have a very great interest in, of course, not writing off debts. Their business is lending and they do not want to see debts written off. Now there have been proposals as to how this can be done and there are a variety of them. Currently, there are the consultative groups which the World Bank organises, where donors, the UN and creditors sit around the table with the debtor and look at what is viable. Unfortunately, what happens at the moment is that a debtor country will go to the Paris Club, which is only a gathering of creditors, led by the IMF, the donors are not present, the aid departments are not present there, and the debtor is not present when decisions are made within the Paris Club, as Mr Fellgett said in the evidence to your Committee. And it is this dominance of the whole process by creditors which we think is very unfair. There has been another proposal, which is that all you would need is a simple committee of five people, two of them nominated by the debtor, two nominated by the creditor, the chair nominated by all four, whose job it will be to assess sustainability in that country and then decide on the amount of debt service that is viable. We have not come down in favour of any one system, but we want to raise for debate, very broadly, the issue of who decides how much debt relief is viable. We are interested that Mr George Soros just before New Year, made a proposal in the Financial Times for a new international credit insurance institution, because of the very bad lending decisions that were made to South Korea, Indonesia and Thailand. Those lenders, far from being punished by market forces or by the law, have been, in fact, bailed out by an IMF bail-out of $57 billion, in the case of South Korea. Now there is a great deal of unease in the international financial system, and the Financial Times almost every day runs a story about "welfare for bankers" and how we need to look at the international financial system and review it. We share that concern and we would like your Committee and the Treasury and the Government to look at ways—we welcome very much what the Chancellor has said, which is that the debtor should have a stronger voice in debt negotiations—we would welcome more thinking about how the debtor can be represented in those negotiations. So, I am sorry, Mr Canavan, not a very clear answer, but our view is that the system as it is is unfair; we need a great deal more fairness and we want transparency in the process as well. Right now, you know, deciding how much debt Mozambique can pay is a process that is, in effect, decided behind closed doors, and certainly a long way away from the people of Mozambique.

  116.  How much reliability do you attach to the published statistics which are used by debtors and creditors to assess the level of indebtedness and the social and economic development in HIPCs?
  (Ms Pettifor)  We are very worried, in particular, by the creditor debt tables. It is very interesting to us that we have a list of debtor tables but we do not have a list of creditor tables. It is very hard to find out what debts are owed to the British Government and we have had to find that out via Parliamentary Questions. The new Government is being more helpful than the last was, but it is still very difficult to find out how much debt is owed precisely to the British Government and how much debt service is being paid annually. That is almost a state secret, but what is very well documented is how much debt is owed by debtor countries. Now while it may well be well documented it is not accurate, and the IMF itself and the World Bank, sorry, the World Bank, revises almost every year its own figures for previous years, and, if you look at levels of debt for 1985, when you were looking at them in 1985 the level was this, look at the 1989 debt tables and the 1985 figures have changed, look at the 1996 debt tables and the 1985 figures have changed dramatically, and yet decisions are being made—sorry——

Chairman

  117.  But that is bound to be so, because, for one reason, these monies have been lent in foreign exchanges, and therefore the amounts will change according to the changes in foreign exchange?
  (Ms Pettifor)  No.
  (Mr Woodward)  No. I think, when you are looking at stocks of debt, say, for the end of 1985, that the value of a debt in yen, in dollar terms, should be determined by the exchange rate at that point, rather than at the current exchange rates when the data is published.

  118.  What we need to know as a Committee is how they are constructed; are they constructed on that basis?
  (Mr Woodward)  As I understand it, yes.

  119.  As I understand it, they are not, they are actually constructed on the current rate of exchange, but I would like to know which it is?
  (Ms Pettifor)  I think, when the figures are first tabled they are based on that year's rate of exchange; that should not change, because that year's rate of exchange will be fixed at that year's rate of exchange. What does change though, and we cannot explain why, we are not the people to ask this question of, I think, it should be, I think, targeted at the World Bank itself and its data collection agencies, but we are struck by the fact that these numbers change; and why that matters is because a country's level of sustainability is calculated on the basis of this in the present and its ability to service those debts, and so it may be penalised, or it may be expected to pay far more debt than it can afford to, and those figures may not be real figures. So I think these are important issues that need to be addressed. But I am afraid we do not have the answers to that, we are as puzzled as you are.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries

© Parliamentary copyright 1998
Prepared 14 May 1998