THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF MIGRATION
27. Mainstream economic theory suggests
that global economic output would be maximised by abolishing restrictions
on migration. Increasing the mobility of labour would allow resources
to be allocated more efficiently. Labour would be more productively
employed - there are more jobs for people to do in the UK than
in Malawi - and total economic output would increase.[66]
This logic, when it is applied to capital mobility, is the basis
of the Government's enthusiasm for the liberalisation of trade
in goods and services. Given the vast potential gains from liberalising
the movement of workers, the economic case for more migration
is clear.
28. So much for economic theory; the real
world is different. First, as the British Bangladeshi International
Development Group put it: "For inevitable political reasons,
a can of beans has more rights of free movement across the globe
then someone in the developing world, even though in principle
both people living in absolute poverty and the makers of the can
of beans would prosper more if freedom of labour was dealt with
equally."[67] There
is a difference between the free flow of goods and the free movement
of people, and a need to balance the right of sovereign states
to control their borders and pursue their national interests,
with individuals' rights to mobility.[68]
Second, as with trade liberalisation, the benefits of enhanced
migration, and the costs, are distributed unevenly both between
and within countries and social groups, depending on how they
are affected by migration.[69]
29. In host countries, the economic impact
of migration may be felt in terms of tax revenues, welfare spending,
migrants' consumption of public services including health, education
and housing, wage rates, employment levels and overall economic
growth. And the impact of migration may also be felt in other
ways: cultural enrichment, increased diversity and innovation,
or social and ethnic tensions. In the UK there has been much debate
about the economic impact of immigration. The Government - whilst
acknowledging that the data is far from perfect - maintains that
the effects are "small but positive", suggesting the
resultant revenue receipts for the exchequer outweigh extra welfare
payments by £2.5 billion, and that immigration adds a quarter
of one percent to growth in terms of Gross Domestic Product (GDP).[70]
However, whilst immigration may lead to economic growth, it will
not necessarily increase the host society's per capita income.[71]
Whether the balance is positive or negative - overall, or on a
per capita basis - depends on the nature of the migration,
and on whether the migrants are able to prosper in the host country.
30. There are costs and benefits for migrants
themselves. On the plus side, migrants have the opportunity to
accumulate wealth and skills,[72]
working in a context where their labour and skills can be employed
more productively and for greater reward, and where they may feel
more secure. On the minus side migrants may suffer from a lack
of access to health, education and other services,[73]
poor living conditions, and exploitation - by traffickers en
route, and then by employers - no matter whether they have
moved from a village to a town in India, or from Somaliland to
London. Home countries and communities left behind by migrants
are also affected. On the plus side, migration can provide an
outlet for under-employed skills, reducing unemployment and increasing
wages. It can also increase the incentives for people to pursue
higher education,[74]
generate remittances, lead to the return migration of people with
new and improved skills,[75]
expose developing countries to different ideas and values,[76]
and establish links which may be used in future for trading and
business purposes.[77]
But there are significant costs too for home countries and the
communities left behind, including the creaming-off of skilled
and educated people, the loss of their energies and potential
taxes, a reduction in the domestic pressures for economic and
political reform, and the undermining of family and other support
structures.[78] Such
dynamics will further undermine the livelihoods of the chronically
poor.[79]
31. Migration's costs and benefits will
be distributed unevenly. Economic theory suggests strongly that
migration will increase global economic output, giving scope for
win-win outcomes, but many of the developmental gains are likely
to impose costs for some. To take the UK as an example, immigration
may add to the UK's economic output, but depending on the benefits
which migrants claim, the taxes they pay, and the jobs they do,
immigration may benefit high-skilled British workers, but be at
a cost to the low-skilled, and may benefit consumers but cost
tax-payers.[80] We should
not be surprised at this. Economic restructuring distributes its
costs and benefits unevenly.[81]
This of course is where politics comes in, distributing the gains
and losses from migration. At a domestic level this is complex;
when we add an international dimension this complexity is increased.
EVIDENCE-BASED POLICY?
32. There may be some win-wins and cost-free
ways of making migration work for development, but these are likely
to be few. Policy design should therefore be about finding the
most effective and efficient ways to make migration work for development
and poverty reduction. To do this, one would need to identify
which dimensions of migration matter most in terms of their developmental
impact, what the direction of this impact is, and then design
policies which can be used to shape the various dimensions of
migration to influence its overall developmental impact. It is
then the job of governments - which are primarily concerned with
protecting and pursing the interests of their citizens[82]
- to determine how far they want to go in making their migration-related
policies development-friendly. This should involve factoring in
the non-economic costs and benefits of migration, distributional
issues, and other policy objectives (see paragraphs 151167).
Finally, a wise development agency will want to compare the effectiveness
and efficiency of migration as a route to poverty reduction, with
other sorts of development interventions.
33. Unfortunately the evidence-base for
policy on migration and development is very poor.[83]
There seems to be no model of the relationship between the various
dimensions of migration and development. It was noticeable that
several expert witnesses - and this is not to criticise them -
were unable to provide evidence-based answers to what one would
think were basic questions. Asked about the relationship between
international migration and development, Joseph Chamie, the Head
of the UN's Population Division - the man who would know - explained
that because of the lack of good data, "Right now, we are
unable to say precisely what is going on."[84]
In their written evidence, the International Organization for
Migration stated:
"Information and data on migration from
and to developing countries are relatively scant and unreliable.
More and better information is essential for policy-makers to
address migration and development challenges more effectively.
In particular, more and more specific research and data collection
in developing countries is needed if the impact of both migration
and return migration is to be better understood and factored into
programmes to assist countries of origin to develop and retain,
and further improve their national resources, including human
resources."[85]
34. There is also a lack of information
about the numbers of people trafficked[86];
the role migrant communities themselves, smuggling networks and
government policy play in shaping migration flows; the contribution
of migrants to their host countries; migrants' contribution to
their home countries through remittances and other mechanisms;
and, the impacts of return migration. Data on some issues, illegal
migration and unofficial remittances for example, are inherently
difficult to collect. But policy should not be designed on
the basis of hunches and anecdotes. If development policies are
to be well-designed, on the basis of a sound understanding of
the causes and consequences of migration and development, then
the evidence-base urgently needs improving. In particular, better
data on internal migration is needed.
35. We were pleased to hear that DFID acknowledges
the need to improve the evidence-base, and is making efforts -
through its Development Research Centre on Migration, Globalisation
and Poverty at the University of Sussex, and with the World Bank
- to improve the situation. Sharon White, DFID's Head of Policy,
stated that in 18 months' time the information base would be much
better. We shall see. The IOM suggests that the Government
produce a short annual report on migration to the UK from developing
countries. By providing information about who is coming to the
UK, where they come from, what they do in the UK, to what extent
they are remitting, and whether and when they return to their
countries of origin, and by outlining what the Government is doing
to make migration more development-friendly, such a report could
do much to raise awareness about the linkages between migration
and development.[87]
We support this proposal and recommend that the Government takes
it up.
14 For useful overviews of migration and development
see: IOM, The Migration-Development Nexus, 2003; Christina Boswell
and Jeff Crisp, Poverty, International Migration and Asylum, Policy
Brief No.8, United Nations University - World Institute for Development
Economics Research, 2004; Kathleen Newland, Migration as a Factor
in Development and Poverty Reduction, Migration Policy Institute,
1 June 2003; Kimberley Hamilton, Migration and Development: Blind
faith and hard-to-find facts, Migration Policy Institute, 1 Nov
2003; IOM, International Migration and Development: The potential
for a win-win-situation, June 2003; Ronald Skeldon, Migration
and Poverty, Asia-Pacific Journal, Vol. 17(4) pp. 67-82, 2002. Back
15
Q 57 [Professor Ronald Skeldon, Member, University of Sussex Development
Research Centre on Migration, Globalisation and Poverty] Back
16
Some of the increase from 1985 to 2000 is accounted for by the
dissolution of the USSR - new borders and countries have been
established; people who have not moved find themselves classified
as "international migrants". Back
17
Ev 124 [Department for International Development (DFID) memo] Back
18
Ev 249 [Oxfam memo] Back
19
Ev 124 [DFID memo] Back
20
Q 78 [Professor Richard Black, Director, University of Sussex
Development Research Centre on Migration, Globalisation and Poverty] Back
21
Q 4 [Masood Ahmed, DFID] Back
22
Ev 124 [DFID memo]; Ev 228 [New Economics Foundation (NEF)] Back
23
Ev 276 [Unlad Kabayan memo] Back
24
Ev 212 [IOM memo] Back
25
Ev 206 [IIED memo] Back
26
Q 64 [Dr Ben Rogaly, Member, University of Sussex Development
Research Centre on Migration, Globalisation and Poverty] Back
27
Ev 155 [Catholic Institute for Institutional Relations (CIIR)
memo] Back
28
Ev 232 [Overseas Development Institute (ODI) memo]; Ev 206 [IIED
memo]; Ev 125 [DFID memo] Back
29
Ev 210 [IIED memo]; Ev 224 [Joint Council for the Welfare of Immigrations
(JCWI) memo] Back
30
Q 88 [Dr Cecilia Tacoli, Senior Research Associate, IIED]; Ev
226 [JCWI memo] Back
31
Q 88 [Catherine Barber, Economic Policy Adviser, Oxfam] Back
32
Ev 256 [Oxfam memo]; Ev 210 [IIED memo] Back
33
Ev 210 [IIED memo]; Ev 257 [Oxfam memo] Back
34
Ev 226 [JCWI memo]; Q 88 [Cecilia Tacoli, IIED] Back
35
Q 88 [Catherine Barber, Oxfam] Back
36
Ev 124 [DFID memo] Back
37
Ev 260 [Refugee Studies Centre memo] Back
38
Ev 124 [DFID memo]; Q 297 [Dr Heaven Crawley, Director, AMRE Consulting
and formerly Associate Director, IPPR]. See also Stephen Castles,
Heaven Crawley and Sean Loughna, States of Conflict: Causes and
patterns of forced migration to the EU and policy responses, The
Institute for Public Policy Research (IPPR), 2003. Back
39
Ev 272 [UNHCR memo]; Ev 124 [DFID memo]; Q 288 [Anita Bundegaard,
Co-ordinator for Durable Solutions, UNHCR] Back
40
Ev 140 [Anti-Slavery International (ASI) memo]; Ev 128 [DFID memo];
Ev 229 [New Economics Foundation memo]; Ev 193 [The Corner House
memo]; Ev 260 [Refugee Studies Centre memo]; Q 289 [Heaven Crawley,
AMRE Consulting] Back
41
Q 365 [Agnes Kumba Dugba Macauley]; Ev 140 [ASI memo]; Ev 276
[Unlad Kabayan memo] Back
42
Ev 205 [IIED memo];Q 56 [Richard Black, University of Sussex];
Q 205 [Mr Winston Cox, Deputy Secretary-General of the Commonwealth] Back
43
Q 56 [Dr Priya Deshingkar, Research Fellow on the DFID-funded
Livelihoods Options Project, India, Overseas Development Institute
(ODI)] Back
44
Q 54 [Ronald Skeldon, University of Sussex] Back
45
Ev 232 [ODI memo]; Ev 205 [IIED memo]; Ev 125 [DFID memo]. See
also Arjan de Haan, Migrants, Livelihoods and Rights: The relevance
of migration in development policies, DFID Working Paper No. 4,
Feb 2000, p.i. Available at http://62.189.42.51/DFIDstage/Pubs/files/sdd_migwp4.pdf
Back
46
Q 371 [Agnes Kumba Dugba Macauley] Back
47
Q 71 [Priya Deshingkar, ODI] Back
48
Q 118 [Cecilia Tacoli, IIED] Back
49
Ev 234 [ODI memo]; Ev 186 [Childhood Poverty Research Centre memo] Back
50
Ev 273 [UNHCR memo] Back
51
Ev 228 [NEF memo] Back
52
Ev 205 [IIED memo]; Q 56 [Ben Rogaly, University of Sussex] Back
53
Richard Adams and John Page, International Migration, Remittances
and Poverty in Developing Countries, World Bank Policy Research
Working Paper No. 3179, Dec 2003, p.1. See http://econ.worldbank.org/files/31999_wps3179.pdf Back
54
Ev 125 [DFID memo] Back
55
Ev 125 [DFID memo]. The income level at which migration begins
to decrease is not clear. Recent World Bank research - see footnote
53 - gives a threshold of $1630 in 1995 dollars. In their memo,
the Joint Council on the Welfare of Immigrants suggest a threshold
of $4000 in 1985 dollars, but points out that Mexico, with a per
capita income of $7000, is still a migrant-sending country (see
Ev 220). Back
56
Ev 220 [JCWI memo] Back
57
Q 57 [Richard Black, University of Sussex] Back
58
Philip Martin, NAFTA and Mexico-US Migration Policy Options
in 2004, Paper for the IRPP Conference on North American Integration
April 1-2 2004, 8 Feb 2004, p. 10. See http://www.irpp.org/events/archive/apr04/martin.pdf Back
59
Q 82 [Richard Black]; see also Uma Kothari, Migration and Chronic
Poverty, Chronic Poverty Research Centre Working Paper No.
16, Institute for Development Policy and Management, University
of Manchester, March 2002. Available at http://www.chronicpoverty.org/pdfs/MigrationJun-02.pdf Back
60
Q 366 [Councillor Columba Blango, The Worshipful Mayor of Southwark] Back
61
Ev 220 [JCWI memo]; Q 57 [Richard Black, University of Sussex];
Timothy J. Hatton and Jeffrey G. Williamson, Demographic and Economic
Pressure on Emigration out of Africa, Scandinavian Journal
of Economics, Vol. 105 (January 2003), pp. 465-486. Back
62
Sharon Stanton Russell, Migration and Development: Reframing the
international policy agenda, Migration Policy Institute, 1 June
2003, paragraph 3. Available at http://www.migrationinformation.org/Feature/display.cfm?ID=126 Back
63
Richard Adams and John Page, International Migration, Remittances
and Poverty in Developing Countries - see footnote 53. Back
64
Ev 212 [IOM memo] Back
65
Q 252 [Dr Christian Dustmann, University College London]; Ev 172
[COMPAS memo] Back
66
Q 251 [Professor L. Alan Winters, University of Sussex - now at
World Bank] Back
67
Ev 150 [British Bangladeshi International Development Group (BBIDG)
memo] Back
68
Q 332 [Hilary Benn, Secretary of State for International Development] Back
69
Sarah Spencer, The Politics of Migration: Managing opportunity,
conflict and change, Political Quarterly Special Issue, October
2003. Back
70
Q 32 and Q 339 [Sharon White, DFID] Back
71
Ruth Lea, "Large-scale immigration has prompted a flood of
shoddy economic thinking", Daily Telegraph, 19 April 2004. Back
72
Ev 233 [ODI memo] Back
73
Ev 243 [ODI memo] Back
74
Ev 202 [Home Office memo] Back
75
Q 329 [Hilary Benn, Secretary of State for International Development] Back
76
Q 195 [Dr Joseph Chamie, Director, United Nations Population Division] Back
77
Q 250 [Christian Dustmann, University College London] Back
78
Ev 186 [Chronic Poverty Research Centre memo] Back
79
On chronic poverty, see The Chronic Poverty Report 2004-05,
Institute for Development Policy and Management, University of
Manchester - see http://www.chronicpoverty.org/cprcaboutCPR.htm Back
80
In general terms low-skilled immigration into the UK tends to
have more costs and fewer benefits for the poor than it does for
the better off. The case outlined is one of low-skilled immigration. Back
81
Q 270 [Christian Dustmann, University College London] Back
82
Q 255 [Alan Winters, University of Sussex] Back
83
Ev 205 [IIED memo]; Ev 124 [DFID memo] Back
84
Q 181 [Joseph Chamie, United Nations Population Division] Back
85
Ev 217 [IOM memo] Back
86
Q 9 [Masood Ahmed, DFID] Back
87
Q 181 [Mr Frank Laczko, Chief of Research and Publications (Geneva),
IOM]; Ev 218 [IOM memo]; Ev 136 [African Foundation For Development
(AFFORD) memo] Back