Select Committee on Business and Enterprise Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Professor Dieter Helm, Professor of Energy Policy, University of Oxford

  1.  This memorandum addresses possible anti-competitive behaviour in the UK electricity and gas markets, the relevant evidence, and the extent to which the structure of the market distorts competition.

THE VARIOUS CLAIMS MADE BY THE TREASURY, OFGEM AND OTHERS

  2.  Recent large increases in retail electricity and gas prices have given rise to claims that the energy markets are not sufficiently competitive. It has further been claimed by Ofgem that the electricity companies have benefited from a windfall of some £9 billion as a result of the grandfathering of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS) permits for the second phase, 2008-12. Ofgem has recommended that a windfall tax for this amount be levied on the electricity companies and that the revenues be used to cross-subsidise the fuel poor. The Treasury, through a series of "star chamber" meetings with the industry, has conflated these issues further, by arguing that, because of the alleged excess profits (whether from the permit grandfathering or otherwise), the main suppliers should cross-subsidise the fuel poor "voluntarily" against the threat of a windfall tax.

  3.  These claims confuse three separate questions:

    (i)  whether there is anti-competitive behaviour?

    (ii)  whether there is a windfall, and whether this amounts to £9 billion?

    (iii)  whether in a competitive market, cross-subsidies are appropriate from one group of customers to another?

EVIDENCE ON ANTI-COMPETITIVE BEHAVIOUR

  4.  The main claims that have been made about anti-competitive behaviour have not been substantiated by empirical evidence. Ofgem claims that this is because there is no evidence. The industry claims that retail prices have increased because wholesale prices have risen (and by more than retail prices), and that there is customer switching between suppliers.

  5.  In the NETA market structures, which went live from 2000, the evidence is extremely hard to assess from the outside. Unlike the Pool, which NETA replaced, generators and suppliers are free to contract as they choose, whereas the Pool required all significant electricity to be sold into the Pool and anyone could purchase supplies at the Pool price. The Pool was compulsory, transparent and (very) liquid. The introduction of NETA encouraged vertical integration, and pluralised the contracting strategies of the participants. As a result, vertical integration became highly desirable, creating physical hedges for the integrated companies, and leaving generation-only and supplier-only companies at a competitive disadvantage. NETA has proved a major barrier to entry by both merchant generators and supply-only businesses. It is therefore not surprising that there is no significant entry up or downstream since its introduction.

  6.  NETA also made consolidation within the vertically integrated players attractive, and indeed the result has been that a small number of companies now dominate the market.

  7.  It is impossible from the outside to establish whether the result has been consistent with the behaviour of a competitive market. In the absence of entry, the incumbents could be engaged in an intensely competitive battle for market share—and, in the key test for a competitive market, prices could be related to costs.

  8.  The problem for external observers is that the costs upon which prices are based vary, and in a non-transparent way. In particular, it is not sufficient to claim that prices in the wholesale market are tracked by retail prices. The reasons include: the determination of wholesale prices and the influence on those prices of the vertically integrated players; the impact of different fuel mixes on the costs of particular players; and the extent of physical hedges.

  9.  It is therefore not possible for Ofgem to claim that the market is competitive (or not)—as, for example, in response to the Chancellor of the Exchequer's questioning in January 2008 (and it is surprising that Ofgem then announced that, although it believed the market was competitive, nevertheless due to "public pressure" it would conduct its own wide-ranging inquiry). In order to make an informed judgement, there will need to be close scrutiny of the contracts, costs and their relation to prices.

THE WINDFALL CLAIM AND THE EU ETS

  10.  Ofgem claims that the generators have made a windfall profit of some £9 billion from the grandfathering of permits for the EU ETS phase two, and that these ought to be taxed, with the proceeds given to the fuel poor. This is extremely simplistic. Whilst there was a case for an ex ante auction, the arguments for an ex post windfall tax are very different. There are very considerable implications for the market. It is very surprising that Ofgem claims that it knows what the generators would have paid had there been an auction (and the example of the 3G licences for telecoms indicates the possible scale of error in such predictions). It is also very important to bear in mind the impact on balance sheets of such a tax and the particular implications for the smaller generation-only players, whose competitive role would probably be significantly diminished by an ex post windfall tax.

  11.  It is also extremely surprising that Ofgem and the Treasury chose to conflate the windfall tax with the fuel poor, given that there are generators without retail customers, and the climate change problem is distinct from the fuel poverty concerns.

CROSS-SUBSIDIES AND COMPETITIVE MARKETS

  12.  The Treasury's intervention has gone further in its conflation of different issues. The Chancellor's initial concern was with the degree of competition, but then the Treasury used "star chamber" meetings to try to get the main vertically integrated players to cross-subsidise from the bulk of their customers to the fuel poor. Such cross-subsidies are patently inconsistent with competition, so either the Treasury wanted to exploit the claimed (excess) revenues from the claimed anti-competitive behaviour for the benefit of achieving a separate policy goal, or it wanted to handicap the incumbents against entrants.

  13.  Fuel poverty remains a serious issue—which might get worse if incomes fall and/or prices rise further. There are at least three possible permanent solutions: a levy on all suppliers, a levy on distribution, or social security spending. The latter is the least distorting (and the most appropriate). Distribution is a monopoly, and hence distribution customers can be in effect be taxed for this purpose. Supply is supposed to be competitive, and therefore only if a levy is applied across all suppliers on an equal weighting can it be consistent (roughly) with maintaining competition. The (political) trouble with the explicit supply or distribution levy is that they both make transparent that some customers are subsidising others—a redistribution policy that is normally regarded as a function of the tax and social security systems.

TOWARDS A MORE COMPETITIVE MARKET

  14.  The current market design—NETA—lies at the heart of competition problems in the UK energy markets. In the NETA market, the combination of a lack of transparency and the competitive advantages under this market form for vertically integrated large companies tend to limit competition in effect to the main players. This was predicted at the time, and it was not surprising that these large players were enthusiastic advocates of the replacement of the Pool by NETA. Given the close involvement and advocacy of NETA by Ofgem, it is unlikely that it will be willing to take a close enough look at this market design.

  15.  Serious consideration may need to be given as to how to place supplier-only businesses on a level field with vertically integrated players, and NETA needs appropriate reform in this regard.

  16.  NETA also replaced the capacity market. Whilst the Pool-based capacity market was seriously flawed, the elimination of this market has further reduced the scope for merchant entry into generation. A capacity market, with auctioned slots, would provide a more even field for entrants.

CONCLUSIONS

  17.  The main conclusions are:
(i)the voluntary nature of the NETA market makes it impossible to externally establish whether there is evidence of anti-competitive behaviour. This requires detailed scrutiny of the costs of generators, to see whether these are closely related to prices. It is not apparent that Ofgem is in a position to know the answer at this stage;
(ii)the relationship between wholesale and retail prices is not a sufficient test of competition;
(iii)the case for an ex post windfall tax is very weak;
(iv)Ofgem is not in a position to know what generators would have paid ex ante in a permits auction for phase two of the EU ETS;
(v)the relationship between the grandfathering of permits and fuel poverty is at best tenuous—especially given that not all generators are vertically integrated;
(vi)the Treasury's attempt to "persuade" vertically integrated companies to "voluntarily" cross-subsidise the fuel poor has been very unfortunate;
(vii)fuel poverty requires a permanent solution which does not distort competition—cross-subsidies are not consistent with a competitive market;
(viii)NETA is a major cause of market distortions and it acts as a significant barrier to non-vertically integrated entrants; in this regard it is anti-competitive;
(ix)the absence of a capacity market under NETA further reduces the scope for new entry.

31 March 2008





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2008
Prepared 28 July 2008