Memorandum submitted by Professor Philip
Wright and Dr Ian Rutledge
WHY THE RE-INTRODUCTION OF PRICE CONTROL
REGULATION IS THE ONLY REMEDY WHICH WILL WORK FOR DOMESTIC ENERGY
CONSUMERS
SUMMARY POINTS
FROM EVIDENCE
Our first conclusion responds to the Committee's
questions about the competitiveness of the UK's retail energy
markets. We believe that our evidence demonstrates two main points:
(a) that the market structure which has evolved is anti-competitive
and (b) that any amount of switching by retail consumers has and
will fail to change this. In particular, litmus tests for the
anti-competitiveness of the market structure are not only concerned
with market concentration. As we demonstrate in considerable detail,
the companies involved in the market have arranged their affairs
so that they can sustain high and rising profits whatever the
level of their final prices to households and small businesses.
Corroboration of this and of the ineffectiveness of switching
is that companies can be observed to make more money with lesser
number of customershardly a punishment for causing their
customers to switch.
A second conclusion addresses the Committee's
concerns about wholesale markets. Our evidence demonstrates how
UK households are paying higher gas and electricity prices as
a result of the increased uncertainty which liberalised wholesale
gas markets entail and reflect, imposing an insurance premium
on consumers which is highly sensitive to the actual and perceived
risks of shortfalls in supply over winter months. Moreover, policy
has contributed to this problem by failing to ensure that sufficient
gas storage be built in a timely fashion.
Our third conclusion identifies areas of regulatory
oversight. Apart from the anti-competitive structure of the UK's
domestic gas and electricity markets, there is also evidence of
actual anti-competitive behaviour. There is evidence of
both gas prices to households being raised by more than might
be justified by increasing wholesale prices and of electricity
consumers being discriminated against. While this evidence is
from one company, this is only because there is only one company
which discloses sufficient information to consider these issues.
All companies have the ability to vary the mark-up on wholesale,
transportation and supply costs, according to market conditions
and specifically, to discriminate between gas and electricity
customers in order to protect the overall margin; only lack of
company-sourced data prevents us from ascertaining how frequently
other supply companies exercise this option.
Our final conclusion is that it is the domestic
consumer who is most vulnerable to the deployments of companies'
market power which we have identifiedthe domestic consumer
is at the end of the chain and thereby the ultimate recipient
of price risk as it is passed down the chain. However, this does
not also mean that we see a remedy in the break up of the portfolios
which companies have built up in order to manage their risks.
Indeed such a break-up could have serious consequences for prices
if it increased uncertainty and undermined the capacity of supply
companies to contract for eg the large volumes of imported gas
which the country will increasingly require. Instead we would
propose the re-introduction of price control regulation as the
only way of ensuring that households and small businesses are
not exploited. Moreover, it may well be, bearing in mind the large
investments in electricity generation capacity which companies
are being supplicated to undertake, that rate of return regulation
would be a better option than the previously favoured price-cap
form of price control regulation.
WHY THE RE-INTRODUCTION OF PRICE CONTROL
REGULATION IS THE ONLY REMEDY WHICH WILL WORK FOR DOMESTIC ENERGY
CONSUMERS[405]
This evidence directly addresses the first 6
out of the 7 questions posed by the committee. It only addresses
fuel poverty policy by way of the remedy suggested for addressing
market structure and market power.
1. THE SYMPTOMS
OF PROBLEMS
IN THE
UK'S ENERGY
MARKETS
Rising Consumer Expenditure on Gas and Electricity
Between January 2003 and December 2006, the
expenditure by UK households on electricity and gas increased
by 71.7% whereas over the same period the consumption of these
domestic fuels fell by 4.2% (Table 1). Since then, price reductions
during 2007 have been followed by further increases in early 2008
and it therefore seems likely that total expenditure will have
increased further since the publication of the data in Table 1.
Table 1
EXPENDITURE ON AND CONSUMPTION OF ELECTRICITY
AND GAS BY UK HOUSEHOLDS
| Expenditure £m
| | | | Consumption GWh
| |
| Electricity |
Gas | Total | Electricity
| Gas | Total |
2003 | 7,660 | 6,260
| 13,920 | 115,761 | 386,486
| 502,247 |
2004 | 9,120 | 8,285
| 17,405 | 115,526 | 396,411
| 511,937 |
2005 | 10,205 | 9,195
| 19,400 | 116,811 | 384,009
| 500,820 |
2006 | 12,375 | 11,520
| 23,895 | 116,449 | 364,555
| 481,004 |
% Change 2003-06 | 61.6 | 84.0
| 71.7 | 0.6 | -5.7
| -4.2 |
Source: Digest of UK Energy Statistics, Tables 1.1.6, 4.2
and 5.2
The onset of this rapid increase in the burden of household
expenditure on fuel which has pushed an additional 2.5 million
households into "fuel poverty" (Financial Times 2008a)
has broadly coincided with the final removal of all domestic price
regulation (April 2002). In short, full "competition"
has been accompanied by rapidly rising fuel prices. Moreover,
there are strong indications that household expenditure on electricity
and gas is likely to increase further as we move into the next
decade, with even more serious implications for household fuel
povertyan issue we shall return to briefly in the concluding
section of this evidence.
Gas and Electricity Prices Rise Faster than Inflation
Figures 1 and 2 subtract the annual rate of inflation from
the annual increase in gas and electricity prices and the black-shaded
columns therefore show the extent to which gas and electricity
prices have been rising faster than inflation. Since the complete
deregulation of all domestic gas and electricity prices the story
has mainly been of these prices rising faster than inflation (rising
in "real terms"): whereas the previous regulatory regime
generally resulted in consistently falling real prices. Let it
also be said at this stage that any solace which OFGEM and BERR
may take from any one of the possible country rankings (permutations
in euros, purchasing power parity, with or without various taxes,
for particular groups of consumers) of UK domestic gas and electricity
prices in EU league tables is misplaced: in particular, unlike
most other EU states our gas has mainly been supplied from our
own offshore resources not imported by pipeline from Siberia and
by ship from other places more distant than the UKCS. We should
therefore expect to have gas among the cheapest in Europe. As
far as domestic electricity prices (excluding taxes) are concerned
the UK is consistently more expensive than the "unliberalised"
markets of France and Greece, and the latest Eurostat data place
the UK above the EU average.
Figure 1
UK DOMESTIC GAS PRICES AND INFLATION

Figure 2
UK DOMESTIC ELECTRICITY PRICES AND INFLATION

Source for Figures 1 and 2: BERR Quarterly Energy Prices, Table
2.1.1
Note: the gas and electricity prices used in constructing
these Figures are the RPI fuel components exclusive of VAT
Company Profits Increase Despite Flat Demand
While consumers have been experiencing the pain of these
price increases, energy company profits have been growing strongly
(Table 2). Moreover, while some companies possess regulated gas
and electricity transmission and distribution businesses, it is
profits from their non-regulated businesses in the "competitive"
part of the market which have been growing most rapidly (Tables
3 and 4).
Table 2
TOTAL OPERATING PROFITS OF THE DOMESTIC ENERGY SUPPLY
COMPANIES FROM ALL THEIR UK ENERGY BUSINESSES, 2003-2006/07
| 2003 | 2004
| 2005 | 2006 |
2007 |
Centrica plc | 872 | 989
| 1,335 | 1,198 | 1,745
|
EDF Energy plc | 517 | 521
| 587 | 647 | n/a
|
E.ON UK plc | 583 | 642
| 741 | 710 | 778
|
RWE npower | 496 | 411
| 299 | 348 | 496
|
Iberdrola (Scottish Power) | 495
| 597 | 739 | 955
| n/a |
SSE plc | 680 | 790
| 887 | 1,081 | n/a
|
Total | 3,643 |
3,950 | 4,589 | 4,939
| n/a |
Sources for Tables 2, 3, and 4: see Appendix for sources
and methodology
Notes: As with all the succeeding tables containing company-sourced
information, the data have been aligned so that there is maximum
overlap between the different financial years used by the companies:
data from those companies with financial years ending in March
have been aligned with data from those whose financial year ended
the preceding December, eg the year ending March 2007 is aligned
with the year ending December 2006.
Table 3
OPERATING PROFITS OF THE DOMESTIC ENERGY SUPPLY COMPANIES
FROM THEIR REGULATED BUSINESSES, 2003-2006/07
| 2003 | 2004
| 2005 | 2006 |
2007 |
EDF Energy plc | 394 | 392
| 415 | 484 | n/a
|
E.ON UK plc | 155 | 323
| 350 | 334 | 349
|
Iberdrola (Scottish Power) | 394
| 416 | 525 | 524
| n/a |
SSE plc | 318 | 325
| 373 | 349 | n/a
|
Total | 1,260 |
1,456 | 1,662 | 1,691
| n/a |
| | |
| | |
Table 4
OPERATING PROFITS OF THE DOMESTIC ENERGY SUPPLY COMPANIES
FROM THEIR NON-REGULATED BUSINESSES, 2003-2006/07
| 2003 | 2004
| 2005 | 2006 |
2007 |
Centrica plc | 872 | 989
| 1,335 | 1,198 | 1,745
|
EDF Energy plc | 126 | 164
| 151 | 117 | n/a
|
E.ON UK plc | 402 | 499
| 539 | 586 | 522
|
RWE npower | 496 | 411
| 299 | 348 | 496
|
Iberdrola (Scottish Power) | 101
| 181 | 214 | 431
| n/a |
SSE plc | 363 | 466
| 523 | 740 | n/a
|
Total | 2,360 |
2,709 | 3,061 | 3,420
| n/a |
| | |
| | |
Between 2003 and 2006, the total operating profits from UK
energy operations of the 6 domestic energy suppliers increased
by 35.6%. For the three companies for which 2007 data is available
the increase between 2003 and 2007 was 54.7%. Operating profits
from regulated operations (electricity and gas distribution) increased
by 34.2% between 2003 and 2006 while operating profits from non-regulated
operations (gas production, electricity generation, gas storage,
energy trading, energy supply to all customers, energy-related
services), increased by 44.9%.
Relating these substantial increases in operating profit
to the post-tax, post-net interest earnings attributable to the
companies' shareholders is more difficult. Only three of the above
companies provide sufficiently comparable data on this subject.
Moreover data for the year 2007 is currently only available for
one company (Centrica). Since such data relates to all the
companies' operations including foreign and non-energy operations
we can only interpret the figures with considerable caution. With
these caveats in mind, Table 5 displays post-tax "adjusted"
earnings per share ("adjusted"as with the operating
profit data shown abovemeaning before exceptional items
and re-measurements of certain derivatives) and the proportion
of their total operating profits contributed by UK energy operations.
Table 5
ADJUSTED EARNINGS PER SHARE (PENCE) AND PROPORTION OF
TOTAL OPERATING PROFIT ATTRIBUTABLE TO UK ENERGY OPERATIONS, 2003-07
| 2003 |
2004 | 2005 | 2006
| 2007 |
Centrica | 16.80p (80.4)
| 20.00p (80.6) | 18.20p (88.2)
| 19.40p (83.1) | 30.60p (89.5)
|
Scottish Power | 36.40p (43.0)
| 36.20p (89.9) | 44.10p (88.7)
| 47.17p (85.7) | n/a |
SSE | 55.30p (88.2 |
62.80p (88.5) | 72.90p (89.8)
| 92.50p (89.5) | n/a |
Source: Annual Reports and Accounts of Centrica plc, Scottish
Power Ltd, Scottish Power plc and SSE plc
Note: The data in parentheses are the proportions of total
operating profits contributed by UK operations.
From this data we can conclude that aggregate earnings per
share for the three companies in question increased by 46.6% between
2003 and 2006, while Centrica's EPS increased by 82.1% between
2003 and 2007.
2. EXPLANATIONS FROM
OFGEM AND BERR
In response to the substantial real price increases experienced
by UK domestic consumers and in particular the evidence that "Britain's
vaunted competitive energy marketoften held up to other
EU states as a modelis not serving all parts of society".
(Financial Times, 2008b) OFGEM and the Department for BERR
have, in a variety of different documents over the past few years,
advanced the following propositions:
(1) The UK's domestic energy market remains highly competitive
as evidenced by customers switching suppliers (OFGEM, 2006a; 2006b)
and the fact that, measured by a range of additional structural
indicators (regulated third party access to transportation infrastructure,
transparent wholesale markets etc) the UK has the "most competitive"
energy market among the EU and G7 countries (BERR/OXERA, 2007a;
2007b). By implication therefore, the steep rise in domestic
energy prices cannot be attributed to any particular structural
features of that market or the exercise of market power on the
part of the supply companies.
(2) While certain environmental charges have necessarily
been added to the retail price of gas and electricity, the
primary cause of fuel price inflation has been the substantial
increase in wholesale electricity and gas prices with
the rising gas price feeding through to electricity prices via
gas-fired electricity generation (OFGEM, 2006a). We are therefore
invited to infer that the companies which supply gas and electricity
to domestic customers are themselves the "victims" of
these wholesale price increases, a proportion of which they reluctantly
pass-on.
(3) UK wholesale gas prices only increased because
they became linked to "unliberalised" oil-price indexed
prices in mainland Europe as a result of the physical
linkage of markets via new pipelines and the fact that the UK
has recently become a net gas importer (OFGEM, 2006a).
Bearing in mind these explanations we shall now investigate
the issues of concern to the BERR Committee enquiry, starting
with the fundamental question of the nature of competition in
the UK's energy markets. To what extent has the structure of the
UK domestic energy supply industry become intrinsically uncompetitive
and is there evidence that this structure has resulted in actual
uncompetitive behaviour?[406]
3. MARKET STRUCTURE
AND COMPETITION
IN THE
DOMESTIC MARKETS
FOR GAS
AND ELECTRICITY
Initial Expectations
At the time when the UK domestic energy supply industry was
moving from regulation to competition (1996-2002) it was generally
envisaged that the market would become dominated by a large number
of independent "pure" supply companies,[407]
and that prices would continue to fall and generally, remain low
in historical terms. The business would be intrinsically a risky
one for the competing companies, but they would be able to hedge
their purchases and sales in what was expected to be a deep and
liquid futures and forwards (OTC) market. In the event this "deep
and liquid" secondary market failed to materialise, partly
because of the disappearance of the "mega-BTU marketers"
like Enron and TXU who would have constituted the substantial
counter-parties required, had they survived. Nevertheless, competition
in the UK's domestic energy supply business did appear to deliver
decreasing real gas and electricity prices during the years 1997-2002.
However, the extent to which competition per se, was responsible
for these exceptionally low prices has been greatly exaggerated;
these were also years of excess energy supplies worldwide and
the specific characteristics of energy privatisation and liberalisation
in the UK led to a massive over-production of gas during the earlier
part of this period (IEA, 1998) and a massive over-capacity in
electricity generation in the latter part (Rutledge, 2007). The
"asset-sweating" regulation of transmission and distribution
was also responsible for delivering a large part of the reductions
in prices which domestic consumers experienced at this time.
However, this transient success from a consumer perspective
also drove a company response concerned to create an industry
structure which would mitigate the risks associated with the combination
of over capacity, extreme exposure to price risk and very low
(and volatile) wholesale market prices. This new structure "could
not be described as anything other than a vertically-integrated
oligopoly" (Helm 2003, p 311).[408]
As we shall see, this characterisation by Helm has become even
more appropriate since 2003. More important though is how it has
functioned to the detriment of domestic consumers.
The Development of Oligopoly since 2000
Oligopolythe domination of a market by a small group
of companiesdeveloped in the UK energy supply industry
over a relatively short period of time (2001-04). In 2000 there
were 28 gas suppliers licensed to operate in the domestic market
of Great Britain, 16 of which were said to be "active".
Similarly there were 20 licensed electricity supply companies
of which 13 were "active". (OFGEM, 2001a).
Commenting on this relatively happy state of affairs and
having observed that, "the number of competing suppliers
and changes in the number can be a useful indicator of the degree
of competition", OFGEM noted that:
"Since October 2000, the number of licences granted to
. . . suppliers has increased significantly. This can be mainly
attributed to the entrance of new companies into the market, which
will effectively serve to aid the development of competition".
(OFGEM, 2001a, p 61)
However within a mere three years, a dramatic industry concentration
had taken place. According to one industry source, by 2004, just
six supply companies served 95% of the domestic and small business
electricity sector, while the same six companies served 99% of
the domestic (only) gas and electricity sectors. The same source
described the market as "highly concentrated" (EDF,
2004). Today those same six companies dominate the totality of
the domestic gas and electricity markets.
Table 6
NUMBER OF ACTIVE DOMESTIC ENERGY SUPPLIERS IN GREAT BRITAIN
2000-06
| 2000 | 2006
|
Active Gas Supply Companies | 16
| 6 |
Active Electricity Supply Companies | 13
| 6 |
Source: OFGEM (2001a), OFGEM (2006b
Since, as we have noted, OFGEM regards "the number
. . . and changes in the number" (our emphasis) of
supply companies as "a useful indicator of the degree of
competition", it is difficult to see how OFGEM or anyone
else can avoid the logical conclusion that the UK domestic energy
supply business has become much less "competitive" than
it was in eight years ago.
From this we cannot conclude a priori that the six
UK domestic energy supply companies are able to use market power
to raise retail prices above levels which are putatively competitive.
There are four potential constraints on oligopolies exercising
such market power. Firstly, if the market for the particular commodity
being supplied is price-elastic (a percentage increase in price
results in a larger percentage fall in demand) the incumbent companies
would be constrained from raising prices by the expectation of
lower total revenues. Secondly if there are few barriers to entry,
even a small dominant group of companies might fear that raising
pricesand profitswill attract new entrants who would
drive prices back to lower levels. Thirdly, if each company in
the oligopoly has reason to believe that if it unilaterally increases
prices the other companies will refrain from following and it
will consequently be "left out on a limb" losing significant
market share (and profit), this individual company fear
will inhibit the oligopoly collectively from exercising
its potential market power. Finally, a fourth potential constraint
on the exercise of market power by an oligopoly is the government
and its agencies: if the companies have reason to believe they
will be punishedwhether by some kind of "windfall
tax" or price controlif they increase prices above
levels which are generally considered by society to be "reasonable",
they will obviously refrain from doing so.
Unfortunately, in the case of the UK domestic energy supply
industry none of these four constraints apply. Firstly, domestic
consumer demand for gas and electricity is highly inelasticwe
all require a certain minimum level of heating, warmth and light
whatever their prices: there are no substitutes for these "commodities".
Neither can we hedge by switching between the different fuels:
if electricity were to suddenly be offered to us at a much lower
price we cannot switch our gas central heating systems or gas
ovens to electricity except in the very long-term.[409]
Secondly, in today's highly concentrated domestic supply
industry there are formidable barriers to entry: the six incumbent
companies have spent considerable sums investing in the latest
technology to handle millions of customers (Centrica's bill for
this was around £200 million). In order to compete with the
incumbent six companies a new entrant would have to make the same
kind of investment virtually over-night while at the same time
offering retail prices which were substantially below all the
existing suppliers. This kind of scenario can reasonably be discounted.
With respect to the third caveat, on every occasion that
one of the companies has raised its domestic electricity and gas
prices the others have, sooner or later, followed. They may have
raised prices by different amounts and at slightly different times,
but this herd-like behaviour is now so well institutionalised
that none of the companies has any fear that by raising prices
it will become isolated and thereby lose significant market
share.
Fourthly, so far, and based on previous experience, the companies
would appear to have absolutely no reason to fear that the State
will intervene if they raise prices. Such an intervention has
only occurred once (the 1997 Windfall Tax) and this was primarily
a response to the manner in which the energy companies had been
sold off cheaply at privatisation. It should also be noted that
since then, the Government, OFGEM and BERR have repeatedly eulogised
the UK's laissez faire energy industry model. They are
deeply committed to it as an ideological project. Any intervention
in the market by these bodies would therefore be interpreted as
an acknowledgement that the model has failed. This view seems
to be confirmed by the failure to announce any serious attempt
to restrain domestic energy prices in the March 2008 Budget.
Gas Storage
Some final remarks should be added regarding the market structure
of natural gas storage. This sector was originally regulated as
part of British Gas Corporation plc, and subsequently BG plc but
in 2000, gas storage (with the exception of LNG storage) was de-regulated
in the erroneous belief that the sector was potentially competitive.
(It wasn't because the three existing storage facilities had very
different technical profiles such that they can not compete with
one another). In 2000-01 OFGEM required the two largest facilities,
Rough and Hornsea, to auction their storage space and at the time
the prices received at the auctions were exceptionally low. Subsequently
BG plc sold both facilities which by 2002 had passed into the
hands of Centrica and SSE respectively. By the following year,
these two facilities accounted for around 88% of total UK gas
storage space (Wright, 2006, p 31) but in reality, Centrica (Rough)
controlled 100% of long-term (seasonal) storage space while SSE
(Hornsea) controlled 69% of mid-term storage space. In effect
the former was now a monopoly and the latter the dominant player
in a market which contained only two other very small players,
Scottish Power (Hatfield Moor) and EDF (Hole House). Once it became
evident that the UK's own gas supply was rapidly depleting and
the country was becoming dependent on imports, storage prices
more than trebled. In short, this sector remains almost totally
uncompetitive and the consequent rapid rise in storage prices
has contributed to the upward movement of domestic natural gas
prices.
Oligopoly plus Vertical Integration
Responding to the extremely difficult market conditions experienced
by the UK energy industry in the years 1997-2001 as described
above, by 2002 a wave of disposals and acquisitions had largely
taken place which resulted in an industry which was highly integrated
both horizontally and vertically. By 2007 this had produced an
industry structure as illustrated in Figure 3.
Figure 3
UK ENERGY INDUSTRY COMPANY PORTFOLIOS 2007
Companies with Domestic Supply Operations
| | | |
| | | |
|
| Upstream
| Mid-Stream |
| | | | Downstream
|
Company |
Gas
Production
|
Electricity
Generation |
Wholesale
Trading |
Transmission
|
Distribution |
Gas
Storage
| Non-
Domestic
Supply |
Domestic
Supply
|
Centrica (British Gas) | g |
e | g e | |
| g | g e | g e
|
SSE | | e |
g e | e | g | g
| g e | g e |
Iberdrola (Scottish Power) |
| e | g e | e
| e | g (minor) | g e
| g e |
E.ON UK | g (minor) | e
| g e | | e
| g (Minor) | g e | g e
|
RWE npower | | e
| g e | |
| | g e | g e
|
EDF Energy | | e
| g e | | e
| g (minor) | g e | g e
|
Companies without Domestic Supply Operations
| | | |
| | | |
|
| Upstream |
| Mid-Stream |
| | |
| Downstream |
National Grid | |
| | g e | g
| g | | |
British Energy | | e
| e | | |
| e | |
Drax Group | | e
| e(minor) | |
| | e | |
International Power | | e
| e | | |
| e | |
Others | g | e
| g e | | g
| | g e |
|
Source: Author research. "Others" includes major
upstream gas producers, small electricity generators and independent
suppliers to non-domestic customers
Note: g indicates ownership of gas assets; e indicates
ownership of electricity assets
The principal exceptions to this trend were British Energy
plc (nuclear power) and National Grid plc (formed out the merger
of BG Transco (gas transmission) with the National Grid Company
(electricity transmission). National Grid is prevented by its
licence from owning energy supply companies (and visa-versa) and
this has been the only form of vertical integration proscribed
by the Government, OFGEM and BERR. It is argued that such "ownership
unbundling" allows fully effective third party access to
the transmission sector which in turn enables vigorous supply
competition to take place. As we shall see, this confidence in
the creation of a hypothetically competitive industrial structure
for the UK's energy market has been entirely misplaced.
If one wishes to understand the working of the UK domestic
energy market and the prices emanating from that market then the
crucially important form of vertical integration is not that between
transmission and supply but between "upstream" (gas
production and electricity generation) and "downstream"
supply as we shall now demonstrate.[410]
Table 7 shows the extent of "physical" integration
between these two segments for Centrica, the only company which
is a significant gas producer while Table 8 shows the extent of
physical integration between electricity generation and small
customer supply for each of the six domestic electricity suppliers.
Table 7
RATIO OF OWN GAS PRODUCTION TO DOMESTIC GAS SUPPLY VOLUMES
(CENTRICA), 2003-07
| 2003 | 2004
| 2005 | 2006 |
2007 |
Centrica | 0.50 | 0.53
| 0.46 | 0.31 | 0.42
|
Source: Centrica plc, Annual Reports and Accounts
Table 8
RATIO OF OWN ELECTRICITY GENERATED TO DOMESTIC AND SME
ELECTRICITY SUPPLY VOLUMES, 2003-2006/07
| 2003 | 2004
| 2005 | 2006 |
2007 |
Centrica | 0.34 | 0.46
| 0.47 | 0.61 | 0.86
|
EDF Energy | n/a | n/a
| n/a | 1.28 | n/a
|
E.ON UK | n/a | 1.2
| 1.31 | 1.32 | 1.32e
|
Scottish Power | n/a | n/a
| n/a | 0.90 | n/a
|
RWE npower | 1.51 | 1.44
| 1.50 | 1.64 | 1.52
|
SSE | n/a | n/a
| n/a | 1.77 | n/a
|
Sources: see Appendix
Notes: SME = Small & Medium Enterprises
Supply volumes for Centrica: domestic customers only
Supply volumes for EDF: domestic and SME customers
Supply volumes for E.ON: domestic customers only
Supply volumes for Iberdrola: all customers (excluding "exports"
to
England)
Supply volumes for RWE npower: domestic and commercial customers
Supply volumes for SSE: domestic and SME customers
From Table 7 it can be seen that Centrica can supply between
31 and 53% of its "British Gas" domestic gas consumers.
However, there is some indication that Centrica is finding it
harder to satisfy this sector from its own resources and the company
is known to be searching for additional gas reserves through acquisitions.
Table 8 shows the extent to which the companies' own electricity
generation operations can cover the requirements of their domestic
and SME customers. In the case of both Centrica and E..ON UK,
by 2006-07 the in-house generation assets of these two companies
could supply 86% and 132% respectively of the requirements of
their domestic (only) electricity supply customers. With respect
to the remaining four companies, the supply data relate to both
domestic and SME customers but since the percentage of their domestic
and SME customers' requirements covered by the companies equity
generation ranges from 90% to 177% it seems fairly clear that
they can easily serve the needs of their domestic customers alone
from their own generation.
That the companies see this kind of vertical integration
as being very important is evident from remarks taken from company
documents. For example, referring to its UK operations in 2004,
EDF Group states that its strategy was:
"to develop a vertically-integrated operation by acquiring
an electricity generating capacity which would fully cover its
residential clients, seeking to optimise the total margin between
Sales Revenue and Production". (EDF, Document de Base
2004, p 136)
By 2006, it had achieved this objective, stating:
"The output from EDF Energy's generation plants broadly
covers the customer demand from EDF Energy's SME and residential
customers, while demand from large business customers . . . is
covered through wholesale market purchases". (EDF, Document
de Reference, 2006, p 72)
Similarly, although it has clearly not reached the degree
of vertical integration achieved by EDF, Centrica states that:
"Upstream we will continue to pursue the ideal integration
position to support a business with our levels of demand in gas
and electricity". (Centrica, Annual Report & Accounts,
2005)
Indeed, all six of the UK energy supply companies have, on
various occasions, stated that vertical integration is their objective.
Using Vertical Integration to Control Profit Risks
The motivation for this kind of vertical integration is clear:
in the absence of sufficiently deep and liquid financial hedging
markets, the companies have resorted to physical hedging insteadvertical
integration provides that physical hedge as the companies themselves
have stated. Thus for, example, in 2003, having recently acquired
Powergen, E.ON stated:
"Powergen's exposure to low wholesale electricity prices
in the UK is partially hedged by the balance provided by its recently
expanded retail business". (E.ON AG, Annual Report on
Form 20-F, 2003, p 76)
However, two years' later, with market conditions considerably
changed, the company notes that, "E.ON UK's exposure to [rising]
wholesale prices in the UK is partially hedged by its retail business",
while on the same page stating,
"In response to these increases in wholesale prices UK
suppliers including E.ON increased their retail electricity prices
a number of times during 2005". (E.ON AG, Annual Report
on Form 20-F, 2005, p 62).
In similar vein, EDF states that:
"Due to the vertically integrated nature of the Group,
the electricity demand from the retail business provides a natural
hedge for the electricity procured from the generation business.
(EDF Energy plc, Annual Report & Accounts, 2005, p
27)
while in the same report EDF UK states:
"Despite exceptional rises in the energy market prices
in 2005, the Group has managed to limit the rise of its energy
costs to 29% compared to a market rise of 67% in gas and 70% in
electricity on year (price rises based on average day ahead prices
on the spot market between 2004 and 2005). The Group has achieved
this through vertical integration and a hedging strategy implemented
together with EDF Trading, a sister organisation of the Group".
(EDF Energy plc, Annual Report & Accounts, 2005, p
2).
Taking this "textual" evidence together, we can
draw the following conclusions:
(1) When wholesale electricity prices are falling steeply
(as in 2002) vertically integrated companies can increase the
profits of their supply businesses by maintaining retail prices
to domestic customers at existing levels, or perhaps lowering
them only after a considerable lag, or by only a small proportion
of the wholesale price decline. The latter also appears to have
been the case with Centrica and falling wholesale gas prices in
the first part of 2007.
(2) When wholesale prices are rising steeply, companies
can pass on all or part of this burden to their retail domestic
customers who are effectively, "captive" for a period
of time. (And since all or most of the companies are raising their
domestic prices, customers will be uncertain as to whether to
"switch" and which supplier is likely to remain the
most attractive for the foreseeable future.)
(3) While companies may quote public domain wholesale
prices in justifying their retail price increases, they may not
actually be paying these prices (cf the above EDF quotation.).
Indeed, in general, wholesale prices today, this week or this
month do not reflect the cost of gas delivered today, this week
or this month. Suppliers contract for their gas years and months
ahead of the gas delivery day and also use different contracts
for different supplies. This means the cost of the gas delivered
today is the weighted average cost of a contractual portfolio
of gas prices stretching into the pastand this may bear
no relationship at all to current wholesale prices.
However, even where companies appear to be increasing retail
prices to domestic customers less than might be considered "justifiable"
in the light of the wholesale price increaseindeed even
if they may claim quite honestly that their retail businesses
are making a loss, as a consequenceas was recently
claimed by the Chief Executive of E.ON UK plc, (Financial Times,
2008d)vertical integration of the kind described above
may enable the company as a whole to profit from such a situation
as we shall now demonstrate.
Vertical Integration in Action (1): An Example from Electricity
As we have seen, it appears to be the objective of all the
companies supplying the domestic electricity market to be able
to achieve 100% vertical integration with their generation operations:
in other words if their domestic supply market is 25 TWh per year,
they require (and indeed, have mostly achieved) upstream capacity
capable of generating 25 TWh per year. Any excess of electricity
generation over this level can be sold into the considerably more
competitive industrial and wholesale markets where they have less
market power.
Table 9
PROFIT PERFORMANCE OF COMPLETELY VERTICALLY-INTEGRATED
DOMESTIC ELECTRICITY SUPPLIER c 2005
Generation Segment |
| Supply Segment | |
Electricity Generation Sales to Supply Business
| 24,544,320MWh | Electricity Supply Sales to Domestic Customers
| 24,544,320 MWh |
| Millions |
| Millions |
Revenues | £928.6 |
Revenues @ 75.36/MWh | £1,849.7
|
Fuel Cost | £539.5 |
Wholesale Costs | £928.6 |
Other Costs | £180.9 |
Transportation Cost | £493.0
|
Operating Profit | £208.2
| Supply cost + profit | £428.1
|
Margin % | 22.4 |
Supply cost | £400.4 |
| | Total Costs
| £1,822.0 |
| | Operating Profit
| £27.7 |
| | Margin % =
| 1.5 |
Source: Drax Group plc Annual Report & Accounts 2005 (for generation segment data), Centrica plc, Annual Report & Accounts 2005 (for supply segment data).
| | | |
Note: in 2005, the net electricity generation of the Drax Group (23.2 TWh) was broadly similar in magnitude to the electricity volume of Centrica's domestic supply business (25.4 TWh). In the circumstances we have not felt it necessary to make any proportional adjustments to the Drax-based data for revenues, costs and profits as these would be unlikely to make any material difference to the argument.
| | | |
| |
| |
In this theoretical company (but where the figures are based
on industry data) the supply segment purchases all its wholesale
electricity from the Group's generation segment; visa-versa the
generation segment sells all its output to the supply segment.
We believe the profit margins are more or less typical for the
industry at this time22.4% for generation and 1.5% for
Supply. Total Profit is £208.2 million + £27.7 million
= £235.9 million with an overall margin on external revenue
(that of the supply segment) of 12.8%.
We now assume a 30% rise in all wholesale prices. The charge
for electricity by the generation segment to the supply segment
increases to £1,207.2 million while, at the same time, the
fuel costs of the generating segment, rise from £539 million
to £701.4 million (we assume the other costs remain as before).
Since the wholesale electricity cost charged to the supply segment
only originally accounted for 50.2% of the supply segment revenues
(£926/£1849.7), the maximum "justifiable"
increase in the domestic retail price would be 30% x 0.502 = 15.06%.[411]
However, let us also assume that, in the interests of public
relations the company decides that its supply business will raise
retail prices by only 12%. Then the profit performance is as shown
in Table 10.
Table 10
PROFIT PERFORMANCE OF COMPLETELY VERTICALLY-INTEGRATED
DOMESTIC ELECTRICITY SUPPLIER c 2005 AFTER 30% INCREASE IN WHOLESALE
PRICES
Generation Segment |
| Supply Segment | |
Electricity Sales | 24,544,320 MWH
| Electricity Sales | 24,544,320 MWh
|
| Millions |
| Millions |
Revenues | £1,207.2 |
Revenues | £2,071.7 |
Fuel Cost | £701.4 |
Wholesale Costs | £1,207.2
|
Other costs | £180.9 |
Transportation Cost | £493.0
|
Operating Profit | £324.9
| Supply Cost + profit | £371.5
|
Margin % | 26.9 |
Supply Cost | £400.4 |
| | Total Costs
| £2,100.5 |
| | Operating Loss
| -£28.9 |
| | Margin % =
| -1.4 |
| |
| |
Since the prices (and revenue) of the supply segment have
only increased by 12% while the cost of the wholesale electricity
charged to the supply segment has increased by 30% (and assuming
the other costs remain as before), the supply business records
a loss of £28.9 million while the supply segment margin has
fallen from 1.5% to -1.4%. However the total operating profit
of the vertically-integrated operation has actually increased
from £235.9 million to £296.1 million (£324.9-£28.9)
while the total margin on external sales has risen from 12.8%
to 14.3% (£296.1 x 100/£2,071.7).
It must be emphasised that this example is an "ideal
type" used for explanatory purposes; it does not represent
a real company. Nevertheless it demonstrates very clearly how
vertically integrated companies can benefit from the same rising
wholesale prices which they blame for "loss making"
in their downstream business.
Other things being equal, we would expect a company which
has many levels of vertical integration to have more opportunities
to follow this strategy than those which have fewer or no such
vertical structure. Certainly the evidence that non-integrated
energy companies are at a disadvantage in this respect is illustrated
by Drax Group whose operations comprise one very large coal-fired
power station which is totally exposed to the vagaries of the
wholesale markets and in 2007 was caught by falling electricity
prices and rising coal costs such that its operating profit (before
exceptionals and re-measurements fell by 16% (from £548 million
to £462 million), (Drax Group, Preliminary Results,
2007) while the operating profits of the three other companies
which have published 2007 results (Centrica, E.ON UK and RWE npower)
all saw their profits increase.
Vertical Integration in Action (2): Centrica plc
Given the number of vertical integration tiers in Centrica's
portfolio of UK energy businesses (see Figure 3), we should expect
it to have the more possibilities for successfully controlling
its profit risk. This expectation is fulfilled.
Table 11
CENTRICA'S OPERATING PROFITS FROM UK ENERGY OPERATIONS,
BY SEGMENT, 2001-07
Centrica's Profits from its UK Energy Businesses (Operating Profit before Exceptional Items and Remeasurements)
| | | |
| | | |
|
Financial
Years
ending
December
£million
| British Gas
Residential
Gas &
Electricity
| British Gas
Homes
Services
| British Gas
Business | Wholesaling
& Trading
| Gas
Production | Gas Storage
| Total UK
Energy
Operating
Profit
£ million
| % Increase
in Operating
Profit
|
2001 | -46 | n/a
| 44 | 573 | |
n/a | 571 |
|
2002 | 218 | 61
| 65 | 72 | 447
| 1 | 864 | 51.3
|
2003 | 136 | 84
| 51 | 81 | 480
| 40 | 872 | 0.9
|
2004 | 249 | 95
| 64 | -61 | 573
| 69 | 989 | 13.4
|
2005 | 90 | 111
| 77 | -117 | 1,020
| 154 | 1,335 | 35.0
|
2006 | 95 | 102
| 87 | -178 | 864
| 228 | 1,198 | -10.3
|
2007 | 571 | 151
| 120 | 234 | 429
| 240 | 1,745 | 45.7
|
Total Profit
2001-07 | 1,313
| 604 | 508 |
4,417 | | 732
| 7,574 | |
Source: Centrica plc, Annual Reports & Accounts
How Centrica's portfolio works for the company is illustrated
in Table 11, which shows the locus of profits moving between its
different energy businesses. In 2005, for example, a year of high
gas prices, Centrica made very large profits from its gas production
and relatively little from its domestic customers. In 2007, in
contrast, upstream profits were much lower and these were exceeded
by a 500% increase in profits from domestic customers as falling
wholesale prices were not passed on to consumers. In between,
2006 might appear to be an exception, a year in which the upward
surge in profits faltered. However, in 2006 Centrica reduced its
gas production by 37% due to "management decisions to carry
out remedial work on South Morecambe's cooler units during an
extended summer maintenance period and our decisions to switch
off the field in response to low intraday gas prices especially
in the fourth quarter of the year" (Centrica Annual Report
& Accounts 2006, p 15). If production had been maintained
at 2005 levels profits could have been as much as £1,370
million. In addition Centrica has clearly benefited by adding
an increasingly important "midstream" segment to its
businessgas storage. Remarkably, profits from this essentially
monopolistic segment (see our previous remarks) actually made
twice as much money for Centrica in 2007 than the company's energy
sales to businesses.
Nevertheless, although Centrica has more vertical integration
tiers than the other five domestic energy suppliers, we have
also noted that extent of vertical integration between those
tiers is less than the others (See Tables 7 and 8). Indeed,
although it is the only company with a substantial gas production
tier, in 2007 its own gas supplies only provided 42% of the volumes
required by its domestic customers while its own generation volumes,
having increased substantially during the past few years, still
only covered 86% of its domestic customers demand. This suggests
that the company may have more to gain by increasing its final
energy prices and preserving its domestic segment margins than
other companies which are better positioned to take advantage
of the kind of scenario illustrated in Tables 9 and 10. On the
other hand, Centrica also emerges as more of an upstream company
than a gas and electricity supply company: 68% of its accumulated
profits between 2001 and 2007 came from its upstream and midstream
operations.
Switching as Countervailing Power for Domestic Consumers?
It has already been noted that OFGEM and BERR believe that
in spite of the development of oligopoly the gas and electricity
industry which serves domestic customers remains highly competitive
because there is evidence of considerable customer switching between
the six suppliers.
In fact, other things being equal, the UK domestic fuel market
ought to be highly competitive: because although there
are no substitutes for the products sold by the domestic fuel
supply industry as a whole and therefore we would expect
the industry's price elasticity of demand to be very low,
this is not the case for each individual supplier. Here
we see the exact opposite: there are perfect substitutes for each
individual company's product and we should therefore expect the
price elasticity of demand for each company's products to be very
high indeed.
In other wordsand this is the narrative which OFGEM
and BERR would have us believeeach company will raise its
gas and elasticity prices above those of its competitors at its
peril: if it does so it will rapidly lose its customers (because
a perfect substitute is available), sales volumes will fall as
will revenue and profits.
Unfortunately we only have data from two companies, Centrica
and E.ON UK, which are sufficiently detailed and disaggregated
to examine the validity of the OFGEM/BERR narrative. Table 12
provides data on Centrica's domestic gas market revenues, sales
volumes, customers and prices and the annual changes in these
variables between 2001 and 2007.
At first, the data look broadly consistent with the OFGEM/BERR
narrative. In 2002 the gas price increases by 7.6% over the year
compared with the average for 2001, the company loses 4.5% of
its gas customers, sales volumes fall by 12.3% and revenues by
5.6%. The responsiveness of demand for the company's gas to the
change in price (% change in sales volume divided by % change
in price) is moderately elastic: a 1% increase in price results
in a 1.63% fall in sales volume. However, the following year (2003)
the pattern begins to change: an average annual price increase
of 1% only results in a 0.8% fall in sales. Thereafter, until
2007, the pattern is completely inconsistent with the OFGEM/BERR
narrative: the price elasticity of demand falls well below unity
and as low as 0.26 in 2004. In that year the price increases by
11.8%, the company loses 6.5% of its customers; however sales
volume only fall by 3% and revenue actually increases by 11.4%.
The same pattern broadly continues for the succeeding two years.
Indeed, in 2006, Centrica's gas price increases by a massive 28.6%,
but customers and volumes only fall by 7.8 and 7.9% while revenues
increase by a substantial 15.2%. Only in 2007 does the pattern
revert to the Ofgem/BERR narrative: a very small annual increase
in price (part of which is actually a price reduction) is accompanied
by a 2.4% fall in customers while both volumes and revenues fall
by 11.1%. The only problem with this account is that this was
the year in which the company made a record profit of £571
million from its domestic gas and electricity business.
Table 12
CENTRICA, DOMESTIC GAS MARKET DATA AND PRICE ELASTICITY,
2001-07
| 2001 |
2002 | 2003 | 2004
| 2005 | 2006 |
2007 |
Revenue from domestic sales £m | 4,029
| 3,805 | 3,742 | 4,170
| 4,196 | 4,832 | 4,296
|
Domestic gas sales TWh | 260.6
| 228.4 | 226.6 | 219.7
| 194.8 | 179.3 | 159.4
|
Domestic gas customers (000s) | 13,451
| 12,839 | 12,590 | 11,771
| 11,131 | 10,263 | 10,018
|
Weighted average domestic gas price p/therm |
43.80 | 47.12 | 47.57
| 53.16 | 61.16 | 78.66
| 79.26 |
| | |
| | | |
|
Annual change in domestic gas revenue % |
| -5.6 | -1.7 |
11.4 | 0.6 | 15.2 |
-11.1 |
Annual change in domestic gas sales (TWh) % |
| -12.3 | -0.8 |
-3.0 | -11.4 | -7.9
| -11.1 |
change in number of domestic gas customers (000s)
| | -612.0 | -249.0
| -819.0 | -640.0 | -868.0
| -245.0 |
Annual change in domestic gas customers % |
| -4.5 | -1.9 |
-6.5 | -5.4 | -7.8
| -2.4 |
Annual change in domestic gas price % |
| 7.6 | 1.0 | 11.8
| 15.0 | 28.6 | 0.8
|
| | |
| | | |
|
Price Elasticity of Domestic Gas |
| 1.63 | 0.85 | 0.26
| 0.76 | 0.28 | 14.56
|
Sources: Centrica plc, Annual Reports and Accounts 2001-06,
Centrica plc Preliminary Annual Accounts 2007
Notes: The price changes shown are simply changes in the
average annual price disclosed by Centrica: in reality price changes
did not occur at year-end but took place (sometimes more than
once) within the calendar year. The price elasticity of demand
is given as: - (Δq/q x 100) ÷
(Δp/p x 100) where p is the average
annual domestic price, q the quantity of gas sold and Δ the change in price and quantity; the
minus sign is added in the formula because it is conventionally
assumed elasticity should have a positive value whereas it is
also conventionally assumed that an increase in price is associated
with a decrease in quantity sold ( a downward sloping demand curve).
Indeed when we compare the pattern of change in Centrica's
total customer numbers (gas and electricity) with the change in
operating profit from domestic sales throughout the whole period
2001-07 we observe no particular relationship whatsoever (Table
13).
For example, in 2002 Centrica lost 1% of its customers but
its operating profit increased by 1,047%; in 2003 it gained 0.8%
more customers but its operating profit fell by 37.6%; and in
2004, when the company registered its second biggest drop in customers
(5.6%) its profits increased by 83.1%. In other words, as a profitability
"driver" customer numbers (and hence the significance
of "switching") appear to have been almost totally irrelevant
for this company.
Table 13
CENTRICA: CHANGES IN DOMESTIC CUSTOMER NUMBERS AND DOMESTIC
ENERGY SUPPLY OPERATING PROFIT, 2001-07
| 2001 |
2002 | 2003 | 2004
| 2005 | 2006 |
2007 |
Domestic gas customers (000s) | 13,451
| 12,839 | 12,590 | 11,771
| 11,131 | 10,263 | 10,018
|
Domestic electricity customers (000s) | 5,374
| 5,795 | 6,189 | 5,950
| 5,920 | 5,759 | 6,019
|
Total domestic customers | 18,825
| 18,634 | 18,779 | 17,721
| 17.051 | 16,022 | 16,037
|
Annual change in total customers (000s) |
| -191 | 145 |
-1,058 | -670 | -1,029
| 15 |
Annual change in total domestic customers % |
| -1.0 | 0.8 |
-5.6 | -3.8 | -6.0
| 0.1 |
Domestic energy operating profit £m |
19.0 | 218 | 136 |
249 | 90 | 95.0 |
571.0 |
Annual change in domestic operating profit %
| | 1,047.4 | -37.6
| 83.1 | -63.9 | 5.6
| 501.1 |
Source: Centrica plc, Annual Reports & Accounts
Although the disclosure of E.ON UK's market data is considerably
less detailed than that of Centrica, the same pattern of extremely
low price elasticity of demand is also clearly apparent (Table
14).
Table 14
E.ON UK: DOMESTIC GAS AND ELECTRICITY MARKET DATA AND
PRICE ELASTICITY, 2003-06
| 2003 |
2004 | 2005 | 2006
|
Domestic gas sales TWh | 51.2
| 51.5 | 54.1 | 52.4
|
Domestic electricity sales TWh | 30.0
| 29.2 | 28.4 | 26.5
|
Domestic gas customers (000s) | 2,527
| 2,673 | 2,656 | 2,649
|
domestic electricity customers (000s) | 5,397
| 5,380 | 5,148 | 4,956
|
Annual change in domestic gas sales (TWh) %
| | 0.6 | 5.0
| -3.1 |
Annual change in domestic electricity sales (TWh) %
| | -2.7 | -2.7
| -6.7 |
Annual change in gas customers % |
| 5.8 | -0.6 | -0.3
|
annual change in electricity customers % |
| -0.3 | -4.3 |
-3.7 |
Annual change in domestic gas price % |
| 18.5 | 11.9 | 47.0
|
Annual change in domestic electricity price %
| | 16.4 | 7.2
| 30.0 |
| | |
| |
Price elasticity of demand (gas) |
| -0.03 | -0.42 | 0.07
|
Price elasticity of demand (electricity) |
| 0.16 | 0.38 |
0.22 |
Sources: E.ON UK plc, Annual Report & Accounts, E.ON
AG. Strategy & Key Figures, various years.
Note: Where, as in this case, there are two years where
the elasticity value is negative this indicates a situation where
a price increase is associated with an increase in the quantity
sold. For 2003, only the combined sales volumes for Domestic and
SME customers are disclosed by the company. We have assumed that
domestic sales volumes would be the same proportion of the combined
(Domestic + SME) total as in 2004.
In 2004 a substantial increase in the company's gas price
(18.5%) is associated with an increase in both customers and sales
volumes, while in 2005 another gas price increase during the year
(11.9%) results in only a very small fall in customers but quite
a large increase in sales (5%). And in 2006, huge increases in
both gas and electricity prices are accompanied by proportionately
much smaller falls in volumes sold. Throughout the whole period,
the responsiveness of demand to price increases is highly inelastic.
The answer to this apparent conundrum of very low price elasticity
of demand in an industry where the "competitors" are
each selling a perfect substitute is fairly straightforward. Firstly,
during the period in question, all suppliers have been increasing
their prices making it difficult for consumers to understand (using
OFGEM's favourite metaphor) precisely "where to shop".
In any case, when OFGEM urges domestic consumers to "shop
around" for cheaper suppliers, (as though buying domestic
fuel supplies is like purchasing the family's weekly vegetable
requirements) it is using a totally inappropriate metaphor given
that the transaction costs of time, trouble and legitimate fear
of billing problems mean that customers are unlikely to "switch"
more than once per year at most. Therefore, when a consumer commits
to a particular supplier he/she is locking himself/herself into
a an indeterminate price: the customer has no knowledge whether
the price to which he/she has committed will remain constant or
whether it will remain the best bargain. The position is not much
better if the customer chooses to accept a fixed price contract
where, again, the customer is having to gamble on whether the
contract will remain the best one for the foreseeable future.
Furthermore, to complicate matters for the consumer the supply
companies are now beginning to offer additional non-energy price
inducements (typical of oligopolistic "competition"):
for example EDF Energy now offers its customers free "Nectar
Points" for use at Sainsbury's. It is therefore hardly surprising
that consumers are confused and anxious when considering whether
or not to switch supplier and that consequently price changes
have only a limited impact on the volume of switching and sales
volumes. Indeed, according to a recent study by Davies et al.,
so confused were electricity consumers in 2000 that almost a third
of switching consumers moved to a supplier that actually charged
more than the incumbent; and by 2005 matters had barely improved:
in that year only an eighth of consumers who switched to get lower
prices chose the supplier who gave them the best deal (Davies
et al 2007)
4. WHOLESALE GAS
MARKET AND
PRICES TO
CONSUMERS
Turning now to wholesale markets, while we restrict our attention
to wholesale gas markets these are of course also relevant to
the electricity market via the use of gas in the UK's gas-fired
power stations.
A Home-Grown Problem
An oft-repeated contention of Ofgem and BERR is that the
pricing of gas on the UK's wholesale markets is deleteriously
affected by the lack of liberalisation in continental Europe,
in particular via the oil-indexed contracts which have been prevalent
in the contracting for imported gas on the continent. A first
point which may be made with respect to this contention is that
there is a considerable body of research evidence that gas prices
trend upwards with oil prices in liberalised markets without any
linkage to "unliberalised" ones (Barcella, 1999; Serletis
& Herbert, 1999; Asche et al,2006; Panagiotidis &
Rutledge, 2007). These findings confirm the intuitive conclusion
that gas prices are unlikely to spend long periods lagging behind
movements in oil pricesceteris paribus, producers
are likely aspire to achieving prices in a similar range on a
per joule basis and are not therefore likely to sell their gas
at a discount to oil for any length of time.
These points mean that in order to explain the volatility
and high levels of UK gas prices we have to look to more home-grown
causes. Our view, explored at length by one of us in Gas Prices
in the UK (Wright 2006), is that the behaviour of the UK wholesale
gas prices is logically linked to the liberalisation of the UK
market, which has at times delivered prices in excess of both
the oil equivalent price and the price of gas on continental markets.
Why this is the case has four basic ingredients: (a) the gas industry
is frequently afflicted by physical disruptions in supply caused
by breakdowns and other random events (b) in a liberalised market
these everyday disruptions have immediate and dramatic reflection
in wholesale market prices, not just because of the consequent
shortfall in aggregate production, but also because market participants
take positions to profit from the difficulties of the supplier
or suppliers most affected by the disruption (c) because another
aspect of gas market liberalisation has linked an increasing proportion
of UK wholesale gas deliveries to these volatile short-term marketscontracts
are increasingly "gas-indexed"the prices signalled
by the relatively small volumes traded in short-term markets therefore
price much larger volumes of gas being sold into the market (d)
because of the potential cost to individual suppliers of physical
disruptions, particularly if they occur during the winter or just
before the winter as stocks are being built up, futures prices
can soar to dramatically high levels.
This last point, the cost of insuring prices in a liberalised
gas market, is indicated in Figure 4. The figure is stacked with
the blue-shaded area representing the "beach" or "upstream
price" (average unit price received by producers of gas),
while the red-shaded area shows the premium over the beach prices
registered by the most commonly used index price for UK gas deliveries
futures marketthe Month-ahead price.
Figure 4
THE IMPACT OF FUTURES MARKET COSTS ON THE PRICE OF GAS

Source: adapted from Wright (2006, Figure 6.2, p 140)
While a small part of the difference between these two price
series may be explained by entry capacity charges (the Month-ahead
price is for delivery to the UK's notional National Balancing
PointNBPand therefore includes these charges for
transportation), most of the difference reflects the additional
costs imposed on consumers by liberalised gas wholesale markets.
Traders buy and sell the risk of delivering the right amount of
gas at the right time and this is reflected in a risk premium
which increases the price. As well as providing traders with a
source of profit, this premium also clearly escalates in winter
months as both the risks of securing supply, and the costs of
failing to do so, increase.
Another conclusion which may be drawn from Figure 4 is that
at least until the first quarter of 2004, upstream producers were
not responsible for driving the trend in UK gas prices in an upward
directionthis was a function of the wholesale markets.
The fact that Figure 4 does not extend beyond the first quarter
of 2004 is because BERR ceased to provide a quarterly beach/upstream
price figure after that time. Subsequently, there is only an annual
beach price to work with. Using this in Figure 5 it is compared
with (a) the Month-ahead futures price and (b) the weighted average
cost which Centrica states that it pays for gas to supply its
domestic customers. While during the period beyond the beginning
of 2004, the upstream price received by producers was clearly
now playing a role in pushing UK gas prices upwards, the behaviour
of the futures price was adding to this effect to a steadily increasing
extent as the risk premium commanded by wholesale markets increased.
Moreover, Centrica's gas costs, which comprise a portfolio of
contracts with different time profiles, are shown to be similar
to and sometimes exceeding the Month-ahead price.
Figure 5
WHOLESALE PRICES TO SELLERS AND BUYERS COMPARED

Sources: BERR, Quarterly Energy Prices, Table 3.2.1;
Centrica plc, Annual Reports & Accounts; Heren Energy
5. RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN
WHOLESALE AND
RETAIL GAS
PRICES
If the behaviour of wholesale markets already spells difficulties
for consumers, these are compounded by the way the relationship
between wholesale and retail prices may be manipulated.
The relationship between wholesale market prices and retail
prices is frequently discussed under two misconceptions. Firstly,
it is suggested that if wholesale prices rise by x%, then it is
quite reasonable to expect retail prices to rise by the same percentage.
Such an argument is implicit in a graph which appeared on the
front page of the Observer Business section on 24 February
2008 and has also been peddled by OFGEM and recycled by the Financial
Times.[412] In fact
this supposition is entirely fallacious. Because wholesale gas
prices, for example, only constitute around half of the final
price of gas to domestic consumers, a wholesale price rise of
say, 20%, could only be used to try and justify a 10% increase
in retail prices. We say "try and justify" because if
the gas and electricity retail markets were really competitive,
cost pass-throughs to consumers could not be automatic. Secondly,
as noted above, wholesale prices today, this week or this month
do not reflect the cost of gas delivered today, this week or this
month. Suppliers contract for their gas years and months ahead
of the gas delivery day and also use different contracts for different
supplies. This means the cost of the gas delivered today is the
weighted average cost of a contractual portfolio of gas prices
stretching into the pastand this may bear no relationship
at all to current wholesale prices.
In order to be able to understand the relationship between
wholesale prices and the final prices paid by domestic consumers
knowledge of this weighted average cost of gas or electricity
supplies is essential. Fortunately, one company (and only one
of the Big Six) does disclose these costs and other data which
makes it possible to decompose the domestic prices of gas and
electricity into its their three main cost components: the cost
of the gas itself; the cost of transporting it to consumers; and
the cost of marketing and billing for it (the so-called "supply
cost") which also includes the company's profit margin.
From Figure 6 it can first of all be seen that the cost of
transporting gas to households has been very stable since 2001,
coming in at 0.6pence/KWh in every year apart from 2002. On the
other hand, it is clearly the case that changes in the wholesale
cost of Centrica's gas have been a major driver of increases in
prices. However, this is not the whole story: in both 2002 and
2004 it can be seen that changes in the supply cost (including
profit margin) have also played a role. Moreover, such large increases
were not caused by dramatic changes in the actual costs of marketing
and billing, they were caused by increases in downstream profit
margins: as price control were lifted in 2002 the profit margin
on domestic energy sales was raised by Centrica from 0.4% to 4.2%
and then in 2004 it was raised from 2.6% to 4.1% and according
to the company's preliminary 2007 results its profit margin on
domestic energy supply has now risen to 8.8%.
Figure 6
CENTRICA (BRITISH GAS) GAS: BREAK-DOWN INTO COMPONENT
COSTS

Source: Centrica plc, Annual Reports & Accounts
After 2004, in 2005 and 2006 (the data are not yet available
to construct a 2007 breakdown) the gas supply margin was squeezed
as increases in wholesale prices were not fully passed on to domestic
consumers, particularly in 2006. However, this should not be seen
as either an indicator of competitive pressure or a friendly gesture
by Centrica to its customers. From Table 10 it can be seen that
over these two years Centrica made £1,884 million in profits
from its gas production arm, some 74% of its overall profit. Moreover,
as Table 10 also shows that Centrica managed to maintain the profits
from its domestic energy business roughly constant in between
2005 and 2006, a feat achieved at the expense of its electricity
consumers. From Figure 7 it can be seen that the electricity supply
cost margin suddenly leapt upwards in 2006, from 1.8 pence/KWh
to 2.6 pence/KWh.
Figure 7
CENTRICA (BRITISH GAS) ELECTRICITY: BREAK-DOWN INTO COMPONENT
COSTS

Source: Centrica plc, Annual Reports & Accounts
6. REGULATORY OVERSIGHT
This last point also highlights an issue of regulatory oversight
which Figure 8 brings into sharper relief.
While Figures 6 and 7 expressed supply cost margins for domestic
gas and electricity in terms of pence/KWh supplied, Figure 8 converts
these costs to an annual bill based on the average gas and electricity
consumption levels of Centrica's domestic customers. This shows
that the annual supply cost (marketing cost, billing cost and
profit margin) of electricity had been relatively stable compared
with gas supply costs between 2001 and 2006, fluctuating between
about £71 and £79. Then suddenly, just as gas supply
margins were facing a severe squeeze, electricity supply costs
leapt to an average of £108.60 per customer.
Moreover, in this context it should also be noted that in
2001, Ofgem estimated the annual supply cost per electricity customer
(excluding profit) as just £40 and £20 per gas customer
(Ofgem, 2001b). Since 2001 companies have had to invest in new
technology to deal with switching and other supply business demands;
this may have increased the supply cost; on the other hand, the
growth of dual-fuel customer billing will have worked in the opposite
direction. On balance it seems unlikely that Ofgem's 2001 estimate
of supply cost would have changed very much.
In other words not only do Centrica's levels of electricity
and supply costs per customer seem substantially out of line with
Ofgem's own estimates, but the dramatic hike in the electricity
supply cost during 2006 is a levy on electricity customers constituting
prima facie evidence of price discrimination against domestic
electricity consumers.
Figure 8
ANNUAL SUPPLY COSTS FOR BRITISH GAS' RESIDENTIAL CUSTOMERS

Source: Centrica plc, Annual Reports & Accounts
7. UK AND EUROPEAN
MARKETS: MYTH
AND REALITY
To the great irritation of our European Union neighbours,
who have chosen to manage the risks associated with the supply
of gas and electricity to their citizens differently from the
UK, Ofgem and BERR have been wont to hide behind a "blame
it on Europe" smokescreen. They have also trained a small
army of journalists to parrot this line of argument eg "The
problem is not that suppliers are rigging their tariffs, but that
wholesale prices are soaring and consumers here are forced to
pay through the nose for gas imported from the Continent, where
the market is opaque and uncompetitive". (Observer,
2008). Unfortunately, just like the view that the extent of "switching"
reflects the degree of competitiveness in the market, this argument
is also entirely fallacious. It is based on the non-sequitur that
if the rest of Europe had more liberalised gas and electricity
markets the UK's problems would evaporate, particularly because
greater liberalisation would lead to the disappearance of oil-indexed
contracts in the rest of Europe and therefore of the contaminating,
Interconnector-delivered link with oil markets. In fact, it is
highly unlikely that greater liberalisation of European markets
would (a) lead to a reduction in the volume of gas covered by
oil-indexed contracts many of which have only recently been signed
with major producer nations and are not due to expire until the
mid 2030s (Energy Charter Secretariat, 2007), or (b) even if it
did, that the result would be to sever the link between oil and
gas pricesas we have already noted, there is a body of
research which suggests otherwise. Moreover, why would liberalisation
not have similar effects in continental Europe to those which
it had in the UK in 2005/6?
A separate issue affecting the relationship between the UK
and continental gas markets, and which has nothing at all to do
with perceived continental conspiracies to make the UK consumer
suffer, is that the UK has painted itself into a corner by not
building additional storage capacity commensurate with the country
becoming a net importer of gas (see ILEX, 2005). The consequences
of this shortcoming are starkly evident: during summer months
the UK is exporting relatively cheap gas to the continent as other
EU countries seek to establish winter security for their consumers,
but then is being forced to buy it back at a premium when the
country needs to import during the winter. If the UK had built
sufficient storage it would not be exposed in this way: summer
gas could go straight into storage in the UK, obviating the need
to import during periods of potentially premium prices.
8. CONCLUSIONS
Our first conclusion responds to the Committee's questions
about the competitiveness of the UK's retail energy markets. We
believe that our evidence demonstrates two main points: (a) that
the market structure which has evolved is anti-competitive and
(b) that any amount of switching by retail consumers has and will
fail to change this. In particular, litmus tests for the anti-competitiveness
of the market structure are not only concerned with market concentration.
As we have seen, the companies involved in the market have arranged
their affairs so that they can sustain high and rising profits
whatever the level of their final prices to households and
small businesses. Corroboration of this and of the ineffectiveness
of switching is that companies can be observed to make more money
with lesser number of customershardly a punishment for
causing their customers to switch.
Our second conclusion is that UK households are paying higher
gas and electricity prices as a result of the increased uncertainty
which liberalised wholesale gas markets entail and reflect, imposing
an insurance premium on consumers which is highly sensitive to
the actual and perceived risks of shortfalls in supply over winter
months. Moreover, policy has contributed to this problem by failing
to ensure that sufficient gas storage be built in a timely fashion.
Our third conclusion is that, apart from the anti-competitive
structure of the UK's domestic gas and electricity markets,
there is also evidence of actual anti-competitive behaviour.
There is evidence of both gas prices to households being raised
by more than might be justified by increasing wholesale prices
and of electricity consumers being discriminated against. While
this evidence is from one company, this is only because there
is only one company which discloses sufficient information to
consider these issues. All companies have the ability to vary
the mark-up on wholesale, transportation and supply costs, according
to market conditions and specifically, to discriminate between
gas and electricity customers in order to protect the overall
margin; only lack of company-sourced data prevents us from ascertaining
how frequently other supply companies exercise this option.
Our final conclusion is that it is the domestic consumer
who is most vulnerable to the deployments of companies' market
power which we have identifiedthe domestic consumer is
at the end of the chain and thereby the ultimate recipient of
price risk as it is passed down the chain. However, this does
not also mean that we see a remedy in the break up of the portfolios
which companies have built up in order to manage their risks.
Indeed such a break-up could have serious consequences for prices
if it increased uncertainty and undermined the capacity of supply
companies to contract for eg the large volumes of imported gas
which the country will increasingly require. Instead we would
propose the re-introduction of price control regulation as the
only way of ensuring that households and small businesses are
not exploited. Moreover, it may well be, bearing in mind the large
investments in electricity generation capacity which companies
are being supplicated to undertake, that rate of return regulation
would be a better option than the previously favoured price-cap
form of price control regulation.
The urgency of adopting some such measure to protect not
just the fuel-poor but also the mass of low-to-middle income domestic
energy consumers at a time when they are being squeezed by other
inflationary pressures (in particular higher mortgage and food
costs) is underlined by the fact that there is growing evidence
that the supply companies are now anticipating a surge in wholesale
electricity prices over the next five years as a result of an
expected rapid decline in the capacity margin of UK electricity
generation. For example, in 2006 RWE AG stated that, as a result
of the shut-down of around 7 GW of nuclear capacity and 8.2 GW
of coal-fired capacity (as a result of the Large Combustion Plants
Directive) "a sustained increase in wholesale prices"
will commence around 2011 (RWE, 2006, p 116). In 2007 the company
made the same prognostication (albeit more euphemistically), anticipating
that "market fundamentals" in the UK would soon lead
to "a sustained return of value to the generation sector".
(RWE, 2007). It should be added that research commissioned by
BERR itself points in the same direction: According to the Energy
White Paper of 2007:
"In most scenarios examined, we see some decline in the
amount of capacity that is in excess of expected peak demand between
now and the middle of the next decade. As a consequence, we would
expect to see an increase in electricity prices . . ." (DTI,
2007, p132)
However, in spite of the urgent need to address the serious
social and economic problem of rapidly rising domestic fuel bills
by regulatory intervention, we do not underestimate the possibility
that after the years rising profits which they have enjoyed since
regulation was abolished, the big six companies will strongly
oppose any move back towards price control regulation for domestic
consumers.
REFERENCES
Asche et al 2006 | Asche F, Osmunddsen P & Sandssmark M, "The UK Market for Natural Gas, Oil and Electricity: are they Decoupled?" The Energy Journal, Vol 27 No 2
|
Barcella, 1999 | Barcella M L, "The Pricing of Gas", Oxford Energy Forum, Oxford Institute for Energy Studies, May
|
BERR, 2007 | Digest of UK Energy Statistics, National Statistics, London
|
BERR, 2007 | Quarterly Energy Prices, National Statistics, London, December
|
BERR/OXERA, 2007a | Energy Market Competition in the EU and G7, Final 2005 Rankings, OXERA, Oxford, October
|
BERR/OXERA, 2007b | Energy Market Competition in the EU and G7, Preliminary 2006 Rankings, OXERA, Oxford, October
|
Davies et al, 2007 | Davies S, Waddams Price C & Whittaker C, "Competition Policy and the UK Energy Markets", Consumer Policy Review, Vol 17, No 1, January/February
|
DTI, 2007 | "Meeting the Energy Challenge", White Paper, DTI, CM 7124, May
|
EDF, 2004 | Electricite de France, Document de Base 2004, Group EDF, Paris
|
Energy Charter Secretariat, 2007 | Putting a Price on Energy: International Pricing Mechanisms for Oil and Gas, Energy Charter Secretariat, Brussels
|
Financial Times, 2008a | Parker G & Crooks E, Darling to curb big energy profits, Financial Times, 10/3/2008
|
Financial Times, 2008a | Pickard J & Crooks E, "Darling's voluntary energy levy seen as tax grab in disguise", Financial Times, 8/3/2008
|
Financial Times, 2008c | Crooks E, "Scottish & Southern holds prices", Financial Times, 19/1/2008
|
Financial Times, 2008d | Crooks E, "Eon chief hits out at `myths' on profits", Financial Times, 7/3/2008
|
Helm, 2003 | Helm D, Energy, the State and the Market: British Energy Policy since 1979, Oxford University Press, Oxford
|
IEA, 1998 | Gas Pricing in Competitive Markets, International Energy Agency, Paris
|
ILEX, 2005 | Storage, Gas Prices and Security of Supply, ILEX Energy Consulting, October
|
Observer, 2008 | Sutherland R, Observer Business Section, 24 February
|
Odell, 2006 | Odell P R, "Britain's gas market model in radical need of overhaul", Letters, Financial Times 28/2/2006
|
OFGEM, 2001a | Review of Domestic Gas and Electricity Competition and Supply Price Regulation: Evidence and Initial Proposals, OFGEM, London, November
|
OFGEM, 2001b | OFGEM's Analysis of Possible "Headroom" on Domestic Gas and Electricity Retail Supply, OFGEM, London, 20 December
|
OFGEM, 2006a | "Household Energy Bills Explained", Fact Sheet 66, OFGEM, London, August
|
OFGEM, 2006b | Domestic Retail Market Report, OFGEM, London, March
|
Panagiotidis & Rutledge, 2007 | Panagiotidis T & Rutledge E J, "Oil and Gas Markets in the UK: Evidence from a Cointegrating Approach", Energy Economist, Vol 29
|
Rutledge, 2007 | Rutledge I D , New Labour, Energy Policy and "Competitive Markets", Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol 31 No 6 November
|
RWE, 2006 | RWE Facts & Figures 2005, RWE AG
|
RWE, 2007 | RWE Facts & Figures, 2007, RWE AG
|
Sawyer, M C, 1985 | The Economics of Industries and Firms, Routledge, London
|
Serletis & Herbert, 1999 | Serletis A & Herbert J, "The Message in North American Energy Prices", Energy Economist, Vol 21
|
Stern, 2006 | Stern J, "Europe is not to blame for Britain's gas woes", Financial Times, 23/2/2006
|
Wright, 2006 | Wright P W, Gas Prices in the UK: Markets and Insecurity of Supply, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2006
|
| |
APPENDIX
COMPANY-SOURCED FINANCIAL AND OPERATING DATA
In constructing the tables containing company financial and
operating data we have used the following sources:
Centrica plc: Annual Report and Accounts, 2001-2006, available:
http://www.centrica.com/
Centrica plc: Preliminary Results for 2007, available:
http://www.centrica.com/
Drax Group plc, Annual Report and Accounts, 2005-2007,
available:
http://www.draxgroup.plc.uk/
EDF Group, Document de Base 2004, and Document de Reference
2005-2006, available: http://www.edf.fr/92053i/Home-fr/Meta-Plan/EDF-Group.html
EDF Energy plc: Annual Report and Accounts, 2003-2006,
available:
http://www.companieshouse.gov.uk/
E.ON UK plc, Annual Report & Accounts, 2003-2006, available:
http://www.companieshouse.gov.uk/
E.ON AG, Annual Report & Accounts 2003-2007, and Strategy
& Key Figures, 2004-2006, available: http://www.eon.com/
E.ON AG, Annual Report on Form 20-F, 2003-2006, available:
http://www.sec.gov/edgar.shtml
RWE AG, Annual Report and Accounts 2003-2007 and RWE
Facts and Figures, 2004-2007, available:
http://www.rwe.com/generator.aspx/language=en/id=450/home.html
Scottish Power Ltd, Annual Report & Accounts 2006-07,
available:
http://www.companieshouse.gov.uk/
Scottish Power plc, Annual Report & Accounts 2003-04
to 2005-06, available as supplements to 20-F Reports at: http://www.sec.gov/edgar.shtml
SSE plc, Annual Report & Accounts 2004-05 to 2006-07,
available:
http://www.scottish-southern.co.uk/SSEInternet/
The profit data presented in Tables, 2, 3 and 4 are for Operating
Profit (profit before tax and interest payments), for UK-only
energy related operations. The figures are as published at the
date in question, ie we have not used the remeasured figures which
are sometimes displayed where the company presents its prior-year
results for comparative purposes.
As stated in the text, this data (and the operating data
in other tables) have been aligned so that there is the maximum
overlap between the different financial years used by the companies:
data from those companies with financial years ending in March
have been aligned with data from those whose financial year ended
the preceding December. This applies in the cases of Scottish
Power and SSE both of which have financial years ending March.
Consequently financial and operating data from these two companies
derived from (eg) their 2006-07 Annual Reports are placed under
the column headed 2006.
The data were primarily obtained from the "segment information"
notes to the accounts of five of the companies which publish consolidated
accounts for their UK operations (Centrica, EDF Energy plc, E.ON
UK plc, Scottish Power Ltd/plc and SSE plc). The exception is
RWE npower where we have used the segment data of the German parent
company RWE AG where the segment is for RWE npower's operations
and the data is for EBIT (with currency conversion from euro to
sterling at the annual average rate stated by the company). EBIT
is earnings before interest and taxation which means that the
figure may also include some posttax income from any associate
companies or joint venture in which the parent owns less than
50%. We do not believe that the use of EBIT for RWE makes any
material difference to the argument). In addition, since E.ON
UK's annual report for 2007 was not yet available, for E.ON UK's
2007 operating profit figure we have used the EBIT figure for
the company's UK segment from E.ON AG's 2007 Annual Report (which
has been published). However, since our main argument is centred
on the period 2003-06 any slight distortion arising from using
EBIT for 2007 and Operating Profit for the years 2003-06 is minimal.
The choice of the year 2003 as the base line for our analysis
is based on two factors (1) 2003 is the first full year after
the UK domestic energy supply industry was fully de-regulated
(in April 2002); (2) there were no significant acquisitions of
other domestic energy supply businesses by the six companies after
this date. However, both SSE and Centrica made acquisitions of
generating capacity over this period and in 2004 E.ON acquired
Midlands Electricity, a regulated distribution business.
Among the six companies, only Centrica discloses a detailed
segment breakdown of its different business operations. However,
EDF Energy, E.ON UK, Scottish Power and SSE provide separate segment
data for their regulated and non-regulated operations. The RWE
npower data obtained from RWE AG's annual reports provides no
further breakdown, however since we know that RWE npower has no
regulated energy businesses, we have been able to include the
company in both Table's 2 and 4.
In 2005, UK companies were required to begin to use International
Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) in place of UK GAAP. This
has had implications for the profit and loss account in so far
as companies are now required by IAS 32 and IAS 39 to include
their losses and gains on certain derivative contracts in their
income statement by "marking to market" or some other
method of assessing their fair value. (Derivatives which are for
"own use" are exempted, however). The inclusion of these
hugely volatile "paper" gains and losses is widely recognised
as potentially distorting the underlying business performance
of the company and the six companies whose operating profit we
have used in Tables 2, 3 and 4 all provide sufficient information
to either add-back or deduct the value of these volatile re-measurements.
28 March 2008
405
The domestic market for energy supply is variously described as
"retail" (of which it is a part), "household"
or "residential". In our evidence we use "domestic"
to refer to the residential or household sector of the retail
market (the other part of the retail market consists of small
businesses and other organisations paying posted retail tariffs)-except
when quoting company documents where we retain their original
vocabulary. Back
406
In this respect we adopt the traditional "structure-conduct-performance"
paradigm of industrial economics, see Sawyer (1985). Back
407
A "supply" company is one that simply buys energy wholesale
and sells retail without having any other midstream or upstream
energy operations. Sometimes the term "marketing company"
is used as an alternative. Back
408
Although, the originally state-controlled energy monopolies were
broken up (or encouraged to break-up) in the years after privatisation
it was highly predictable, according to "transaction cost"
theory, that such an industry would soon seek new modalities of
concentration and re-integration; see Rutledge (2007). Back
409
We discuss the price elasticity of demand for individual supply
companies below. Back
410
The BERR/OXERA report referred to above which affirms that the
UK has the "most competitive" energy market in the EU/G7
countries virtually ignores the question of vertical integration.
Only a brief reference to the subject suggesting practical difficulties
in obtaining data is included in Section A3.3 of the report (BERR/OXERA,
2007a, p 72). Back
411
The question of what is a "justifiable" pass-through
of wholesale to retail price is discussed further in Section 5
of our evidence. Back
412
see OFGEM's "Factsheet" No 66 (8/11/06), "Household
Bills Explained", later uncritically recycled by the Financial
Times on 5 December 2006. Warwick University academics Waterson,
Giulietti and Grossi also appear to be oblivious to this point
in an article for Power UK (January 2008, p 60). Back
|