DFID's Programme in Bangladesh - International Development Committee Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 1 - 19)

TUESDAY 20 OCTOBER 2009

DR NAOMI HOSSAIN AND PROFESSOR DAVID HULME

  Q1  Chairman: Good morning. Thank you very much for coming in to help us with this first evidence session on our inquiry into Bangladesh, which we are heading off to next week. I wonder, for the record, if you could introduce yourselves.

  Dr Hossain: Good morning, I am Naomi Hossain; I work at the Institute of Development Studies at the University of Sussex. Previously I was working with the Research and Evaluation Division at BRAC in Dhaka as well as doing work for DFID and other donor agencies in Bangladesh on a freelance basis.

  Professor Hulme: I am David Hulme, Director of the Brooks World Poverty Institute at the University of Manchester.

  Q2  Chairman: We have a series of questions for Dr Hossain and a series of questions for Professor Hulme, but it does not stop you coming in if you think you have something to add—do not feel you are left out. Perhaps if I could start with you, Dr Hossain. Obviously, we have had democratic elections in Bangladesh in the past year, but you have given quite a lot of comments on the governance in Bangladesh. Would you bring us up to date as to where you think the country is following the elections and what are the main challenges that it is facing, and perhaps help us with the kind of thing we should be looking out for?

  Dr Hossain: Sure. I am not sure how much background you have on the government situation in Bangladesh. Would it help if I give you a couple of minutes?

  Q3  Chairman: Yes, it would.

  Dr Hossain: Up until 2006 we were experiencing a 15-year period of multi-party democratic rule in Bangladesh, as you are probably aware. It was not a very liberal mode of democratic rule—there were lots of problems; there was a part-partisan penetration of state institutions and institutions of accountability, and the rule of law was tricky. So there were lots of problems with the kind of democracy that we had, and we had 15 years of it. During these 15 years the main parties alternated in power; so it was not that one party was in power the whole time. We had five years of the BNP followed by five years of the Awami League, followed by five years of the BNP. During that time an institution called the Caretaker Government was established—that was in 1996. That was after a somewhat botched attempt to allegedly rig the election in 1996 by the then incoming incumbent. The Caretaker Government is an innovation that uses the senior judiciary for a three-month position to oversee the transition to government, on the assumption that otherwise this will not happen smoothly in a free and fair way. This was constitutionally established in 1996. So that oversaw the 2001 election which had a major change in government, again. In 2006 it became clear that the incumbent government then was likely to want to stay in power and to be attempting to (allegedly) rig the Caretaker Government so that they would oversee an election which they were likely to win. Ultimately, through a long process which nobody really knows the details of, at the end of 2006 a military-supported Caretaker Government was installed but then stayed for two years in power, and attempted a series of governance institutional reforms. This was a non-party government with, I believe, quite a lot of donor support. The UN, at least, is widely believed to have been in support of this government. So these two years were a period of attempts to reform the governance and the political situation—party politics, internal party democracy—efforts to separate the judiciary from the executive. At the end of the two years, there was an election (so this was in December—the election we are talking about) and the Awami League then came to power with a good strong majority. Since then—so it has been about nine or ten months they have been in power—no formal assessment, no kind of regular data collection that I know of has taken place about what has been going on in governance, so far, so I cannot give you a very full and balanced analysis of what has happened so far. However, I have been back twice since then, so I have spent about six weeks in Bangladesh since this government's tenure, and talking to some of the analysts I know, people who have been involved with some of the governance assessment work that goes on regularly in Bangladesh, a couple of things are noted: one is that it does seem to be business as usual, so politics does appear to have returned to business as usual after this two-year period of attempting to clean up governance and politics; so it is not clear to what extent that has been very effective. It is very clear that the rule of law has deteriorated quite rapidly in the last nine or ten months, and some of the efforts at governance reform do seem to have been stalled or, in some cases, reversed. So this is the situation as people who are on the ground have been telling me.

  Chairman: That leads directly to a question that John Battle is going to ask.

  Q4  John Battle: In Bangladesh, as part of the government's reforms that DFID here have been involved with I think they put together a paper called Country Governance Analysis, and I just want to know what you think DFID could do to improve the accountability of state institutions. There is an attempt to get projects government support but that implies that we get good governance. How effective could DFID be and what should it be doing? What specific institutional reforms do you think donors should be pushing for? Should it be the rule of law; insisting that the judiciary operate properly, or policing? What are the things that DFID should be engaged in and, perhaps, are not?

  Dr Hossain: I think, before we get to the specific institutional reforms, there are a couple of things that you may be interested to explore a bit more closely with respect to DFID's work in Bangladesh. In particular, the best rule of thumb, before you go to do anything on governance intervention, or development intervention, is to do no harm. I am not saying DFID did do harm in this case but I think it is worth exploring the extent to which donor support for the Caretaker Government—from the military ranks—non-democratic Caretaker Government over the two-year period, did, in fact, lead to pro-poor outcomes and good governance outcomes. I think that remains to be seen. Sometimes donors do intervene without necessarily understanding the political history, and so on, and I think that is very dangerous. That would be a general point about when to intervene and when to find out, really, how you should be responding. I am not saying there was an easy answer at that time; there was not an easy answer, at that time.

  Q5  John Battle: Can I press you to say: would that view—that people are not being helpful about governance—be the view of the government, or the rulers, or would it be the view of the people? So that, if you like, the donors are seen to be in bed with the governing set and against the people. Would they be seen as on the side of the people and popular with the government?

  Dr Hossain: I am an academic so I cannot say it is going to be that clear-cut, obviously. I do not really know the answer to that. I think a question it would be interesting and important to explore is the extent to which DFID's support (I think DFID gave the appearance of being supportive, anyway, of the Caretaker Government during its two years) contributed to a weakening of the democratic process, and so on, or not. Perhaps it was very supportive. I do not know the answer; we do not know. Not much detail is known of what went on behind the scenes at that time; we are fairly certain the UN was supportive of this military-backed Caretaker Government, and with good intentions.

  Q6  Mr Sharma: What is the role of the opposition at present?

  Dr Hossain: They are very weak and they are very small in numbers; they are very fragmented—the main opposition party, the BNP. A lot of them were in jail and are, again, in jail. The former Prime Minister, Khaleda Zia, is still the leader of the party but they are in quite a lot of disarray. The same could be said to be true of the ruling party, though; they are quite fragmented, at present.

  Q7  Mr Sharma: Are they working in the Parliament or the Assembly?

  Dr Hossain: Yes. They are very small in numbers this time, so it is not clear to what extent they can have much impact.

  Q8  Andrew Stunell: You have obviously got some reservations about whether DFID did it right or not, and in your report you said some quite stringent things about them: "Even committed professional staff" (in DFID this is) "lacked adequate time to engage with the evidence, travel beyond the capital city, or to develop the relationships necessary for a rounded and fully-informed perspective ... " That is, in terms of reports that we get, quite strongly put. Would you like to, perhaps, elaborate that a little bit and say what you think we might be looking for and what assessment we might make?

  Dr Hossain: Actually, for some other purpose I was looking at the 2005 internal DFID evaluation, and there they said very similar things; that it was increasingly difficult for Dhaka-based DFID staff to find out what is going on and to spend time on the ground working out what is going on with poor people. There is a strong emphasis on the sort of upstream policy work, which has continued. I would say, primarily, you have very few numbers of, especially, UK-based staff in the Dhaka office, and that those numbers seem to be dealing with ever larger sums of money. I was living in Bangladesh between 2003 and 2008 and I did interact with quite a lot of different staff professionally and, also, to some extent, socially in that time. My sense was that it was increasingly difficult for them to get a good grasp on what was going on—they just did not have the time. They had all these large sums of money to handle. Not having the people was a real problem for them, and DFID did have, earlier on, in the early-2000s, a very positive reputation in Bangladesh among the other donors and among the NGOs with whom they work of really knowing their territory and really knowing their subject—knowing what is going on on the ground. That reputation has, I think, declined somewhat.

  Professor Hulme: If I can just answer that, I agree with Naomi there; there is a process that has been put in place. DFID staff are being reduced, its spend is being increased, so the spend per staff creates pressure, and governance projects are extremely messy, extremely time-intensive and you do not spend very much money on them. So the way that DFID is being steered overall, as an institution, makes it quite difficult to have staff who know what is happening in the field. One of the things I would encourage you to look at is the turnover rate of DFID staff. My perception is it has gone very high over the last three or four years; when I called into the office I always knew several people, I find nowadays it is a lot of new people. Some stuff you can be briefed on but the governance stuff, in particular, you need someone in the field.

  Q9  John Battle: As well as, in a sense, the autopsy of where we are up to now, we are going to be there soon and I would be interested to know what focus DFID should have now on institutional reform, given that we have to ask for the resources and the funds to do it properly. What would be your priorities now, with the new government, in terms of institutional reform?

  Dr Hossain: I think a lot of work DFID does is on the button, in general. In terms of the sectors they have selected, the public financial management (which is not an area I know a great deal about), that has been a good area and it has had some positive achievements. I think I said in my note to you that I thought human security was an area that desperately needed attention, and I know DFID have been involved with the UNDP police reform programme. Let me just talk to you a little bit about the focus and the kind of approach to that that I think is interesting. DFID's approach to governance is, typically, and for very good reasons, always from the perspective of: "Well, we have these formal institutions of accountability, we have these formal institutions of service delivery, and let's work with those and see how they work." One of the points I tried to make in that note is that when you look at governance you have to take into account that it is an extremely poor country, and there are two reasons why this relationship between governance and poverty are really important. One is—which I think it is always important (I think it really should be the litmus test of good governance in Bangladesh)—how are the poor being affected by governance reforms? The second thing is, actually, you need to think about how governance is affected by poverty. The fact is we are talking about people who are very poor; typically, still 40%, I think, illiterate. People find it very hard to engage with formal procedures of accountability, and so on. So to think of starting your governance reforms at the level of "Well, let's sort out the police" is not necessarily the correct approach. You could approach it very differently, by how are ordinary people already coping? What are poor people already doing to ensure their own human security? I think this would produce an entirely different menu of options for institutional reforms.

  Chairman: Just before bringing in Mark, you have both identified the staffing pressures, which is an issue that concerns us, not just for this report but in doing any report. If either of you feel able to give us a slightly more substantial note about the practical implications of those staff shortages in Bangladesh, I think we would appreciate it. If you could give us a fuller note on that, practically about what the effects are, I think we would find it helpful.

  Q10  Mr Lancaster: Perhaps we can build on that comment, where, effectively, you are saying that some of the formal accountability processes are quite weak—a weak opposition, for example. However, you also make the point in your note that some of the informal processes are very effective. So could you, perhaps, give us some examples of those informal processes and why they are being so successful?

  Dr Hossain: I think the point I was trying to make was not so much that informal accountability pressures are effective but that they are what happens, because formal accountability mechanisms more or less fail. Most of my experience with this is in the area of public service delivery; like David, I work primarily in the kind of poverty governance interface, so I am interested in how poor people access public services. There, all of the formal systems of accountability are, more or less, defunct, and there is almost no question of them working. For example, if your doctor has been rude or is absent, there is almost no way you, as a poor person, can complain about that and get any redress. An example would be that you can, however, get your local patron—your village head-man, or whatever you have—to come along with you and try to exert that level of pressure to get services. We have seen that sort of thing. People use social pressures of all sorts; sometimes the local schoolteacher will be your relative or your neighbour and so you can put pressure on them that way. These sorts of informal pressures are very powerful in a context in which formal mechanisms do not work. It is quite common in Bangladeshi health centres, where patients die, for there to be violent outbreaks of riot or protests, and so on, so that also happens—these sorts of pressures. They are not desirable, but that is not what I am saying; I am saying this is what there is in the absence of effective, formal accountability mechanisms.

  Q11  Mr Lancaster: You would not like to see, for example, DFID or other donors supporting these informal processes; you would rather them try and battle their way through in the formal processes?

  Dr Hossain: As I said, I think in a context in which the majority of the population are poor and illiterate and probably do not really have much experience of engaging with state institutions, it will be really important for you to understand how they do, in fact, engage—how they do, in fact, attempt to get accountability from public service providers. However, using that, I think, it would be quite a useful way of developing performance accountability measures. You could use them in quite a technical way to help develop more effective monitoring systems for public service providers. I think without understanding how those things go on, however, you would never design an effective governance reform.

  Mr Sharma: I do sympathise.

  Q12  Mr Singh: You argue, and so do others, that there is a link between good governance and poverty reduction, yet in Bangladesh there has been some success and some gains in social and human development. How do you account for that in the absence of good governance?

  Professor Hulme: If I may start off with that. You have to watch out for this myth of good governance; yourselves accepted that good governance is something which most countries are aspiring to, still, and, in a way, good enough government is what one is trying to get to, at this stage. It is extraordinary in Bangladesh how imperfect the processes of governance are but those processes have been sufficient to allow the private sector to invest and improve its productivity and create jobs and to allow the voluntary sector to function, and to allow parts of, certainly, local government and parts of the civil service to function. In a way it is how to move towards this "good-enough" governance.

  Q13  Chairman: That rather reinforces the business view that the less government there is the better. So anarchy is fine for business and investment.

  Professor Hulme: Not at all. I am not a macroeconomist but the macroeconomic policies that have been in place in Bangladesh for the last 15 years have allowed the economy to grow, far from what many economists would prescribe as the best set of policies. There has been a degree of stability which has worked there. So, in a way, that element of governance has worked reasonably effectively.

  Q14  Mr Singh: To what extent, in terms of social development and infant mortality rates, etc, is that down to good or very good NGOs and their service delivery?

  Dr Hossain: Part of the explanation is, certainly, the big NGOs are delivering very effective services, but that is definitely, by no means, the full story. Government service delivery is also important for this—there is no doubt about that. You have put your finger on something really important, which is we do not really understand what happened in that period in the 1990s, up until the early/mid-2000s, when Bangladesh had a lot of great achievements in human and social development, while governance was not improving, including at the sectoral level. It is a really interesting question. I think part of the answer lies in these issues that I was talking about with respect to informal accountability. Stuff goes on on the ground that we do not really have a good handle on because our gaze is always at this level of the formal accountability mechanisms, which are just defunct. So if we lower our gaze a little bit and look at what is going on at that sort of frontline level, it does help a bit to understand. The World Bank has some explanation for it; they say—what do they call it, when you have institutional cherry-picking—you have a few pockets of excellence, pockets of success. I do not think that is the full story either. There was also a very strong social demand for, for example, women's education, possibly resulting from, among other things, a demand for garment workers. What that has meant has been that more educated women has, of course, knock-on effects, as we know, for infant mortality and the demand for children's education, and so on. So there have been a number of factors. Nobody knows the full story.

  Professor Hulme: If I could just add, it is as Naomi is saying; being academics we say everything is complicated but these informal processes—it is not that they do not work, but they do not work like the rulebook says they should be working—there are norms in that, and resources are pilfered and not used properly, but there are limits on that, and if people start giving old-aged pensions not to old women but to men who are not of sufficient age then the social sanction comes in, and that will not be allowed and the local government will stop that. People may be able to slip 10% of the food aid programme but if it gets to 20% then, again, some informal processes of governance will kick in; the formal system may not be working but there are boundaries. So it is never anarchy; it is not the way it is supposed to be, but it is not anarchy, and there are social norms which, if people go past them, will kick in. The most concrete example I can think of is an old woman getting a pension where the chairman of the local parish was taking a commission on it. Another member found out and she said: "I'll tell everybody that you're stealing from old women", and so he stopped doing it because he did not want people to know that he was stealing from old women, and so she gets a full pension now. These processes are operating in their own way.

  Dr Hossain: I think these are the sorts of things that, with some exploration and some careful work, could be supported more effectively than they currently are.

  Professor Hulme: Rather than looking at the rulebook and it not working, if DFID staff could spend time trying to work out could more councillors be concerned about pensions.

  Chairman: We may explore that a little bit more in a moment.

  Q15  John Battle: I think the next question is the extent to which the basic delivery of services (you hint at it there) are undermined by the government, in a way, by accountability. For example, in which sectors would you say the provision of parallel services by NGOs, who are trying to provide services, actually undermine what the government should be doing, so we do not get this balance at all and the government starts to provide properly, but they are always on the margins trying to check what everybody else is doing? Is that what you are saying is happening? You gave the example of the pensions—not to go into that example—but to what extent is that delivery of basic services actually undermined by the efforts of NGOs then?

  Dr Hossain: There is, undeniably, that danger. I have not, actually, seen any evidence in Bangladesh that that has happened. I think, especially with the big NGOs and the big programmes of social service delivery—health and education and so on, and microfinance, perhaps, in particular—on the whole, the NGOs appear to me to be supplying services in areas where government is not supplying services, and supplying services that government is not supplying; chiefly, non-formal education in areas that government cannot or will not reach—the groups that government cannot or will not reach—and certain sorts of health services that government cannot. Also, I am thinking, in particular, of BRAC, which is the NGO I know best because I worked for them for five or six years. A lot of the time their health programmes, in particular, were partnerships with government, and so you had quite effective joint working around issues. Also, I think, in some cases, with respect to education, there was some extent to which there was a kind of positive competition which arose around the education of the poor, in particular, where BRAC had reached villages and communities that the government were not reaching. This was something of a spur for government to expand its service delivery, which is primary education, basically. I do not think, in a country like Bangladesh, where there is so much unmet need, that there is much evidence that NGOs have undermined public service delivery.

  Q16  John Battle: If I put it another way: I have never been before to Bangladesh but the impression that I have got—not that there is much to go on—is that some of the popular participation in the best sense is some of the best in the world. If people are not getting resources from the centre they have got to survive, so they have built up some form of informal institutions to deliver. I think, as a politician, as it were—and I am going to take the power back off them—they have got the power, they are doing it now, so I would resent them, in a way, doing that. I know that I cannot cut off their livelihood but, at the same time, I find a tension between what was going on on the ground, yet, at the same time, if I was a slightly more progressive politician, I might say that model of doing things might be the right way to do it and it might be a good model to use elsewhere.

  Professor Hulme: I do not know about using it elsewhere but the NGOs do work very effectively in Bangladesh, and one needs to work with what works, not look at the models—ideal models—of how government should function. So we need to work with the NGOs and keep them on. I used to worry about them displacing the Bangladeshi state but I do not really do that now because there is so much need. They are an incredible resource; they do create new organisational technologies and new products, like microfinance, like low-cost education. The government is not taking that on now but it could take it on in the future. There are hundreds of thousands—maybe a million—of pretty good staff working for them; that is a resource which the government and the private sector does draw on, at times; it pulls them in. So, theoretically, there is that undermining but, in practice, I see the NGOs as part of Bangladeshi's evolution that will be positive.

  Q17  John Battle: If I put the question the other way: which areas of policy or services should the government focus on because the NGOs are delivering in that other area? Do you know what I mean? Is there one area that government should be focusing on because the NGOs are picking up the policy area?

  Professor Hulme: Infrastructure. The NGOs cannot do big infrastructure; it is really important that the government does that well. The other sorts of problems remain: health and education. I think we would look at social protection. While the NGOs are moving into social protection, could they take on social protection on the scale that is required? Infrastructure, health, education and social protection.

  Q18  Mr Sharma: Crime, violence and insecurity are the major issues in Bangladesh. What forms of insecurity are experienced by ordinary people and why are women more frequently the victims of crime and violence?

  Dr Hossain: It was only very recently, in the last few years, that this has really begun to emerge. Bangladesh is not known as a place where there are high levels of crime and violence, apart from political violence. In fact, it is testament to DFID's ability to pinpoint important issues that they did start to do an analysis of human security first, and to support the work of Safer World. Safer World also produced some human security assessments. I was involved with one of those—we did a very large survey of experiences of crime and insecurity and violence, and it is at quite a low level, was what we found; quite low-level but chronic threats of theft and minor forms of violence, and so on. To be honest, domestic violence is, probably, the single greatest human insecurity threat that people in Bangladesh face. The WHO has also done work on this in Bangladesh—women-based violence from their partners is among the highest rates in the world. It seems like such a very simple conclusion to draw but, actually, I think it is probably the greatest source of insecurity. What is interesting about this, and what is important about this (not easy to capture for policy purposes) is the fact that, to some extent, it is not so much the experience of crime and insecurity as the response to the threat of crime and insecurity, or violence, that seems to be quite important; the way people cope, the way women's mobility is curtailed because people are frightened that they will be abused or, you know, beaten or raped; the way people fail to invest in their businesses and their livelihoods—these sorts of things. I think the evidence is only beginning to emerge that that adverse coping is something that is difficult to explore but it seems to be the response that is most troubling.

  Q19  Mr Sharma: What are the informal mechanisms and institutions which can help protect people from violence and crime? How should donor programmes aimed at justice sector reform take these into account?

  Dr Hossain: Again, as I responded to you, I think it is useful in a country like Bangladesh to approach governance from the bottom up, from how people experience these things. A lot of work has already gone on in Bangladesh over the years on the customary dispute resolution—what they call the "Shalish"—the village-based systems for resolving fights and problems. These are typically around land and marital problems—typically, around 80% of them, or something like that. DFID has done quite a lot of work supporting the NGOs who have been working in this area; NGOs have come in to try and make things a bit fairer—things are very traditional and, in some ways, quite biased against women, against poor people and against minorities and so on. So the NGOs have come in in quite a big way. There is another aspect to it which has not been explored much. Again, this work that I was involved with, in looking at crime and insecurity, uncovered what they call Pahara Committees. This is very well known—anyone you speak to will know what a Pahara Committee is; it is just neighbourhood watch, basically—but these seem to be very, very common. We found something like a third of all the respondents in our survey knew of such a thing in their community. When we asked people how they responded to incidents of crime and violence, and so on (I forgot to get the numbers out for you), they were greatly more likely to approach people in their community for help or their neighbourhood watch or their local patron than they were to approach the police for help. These institutions are there, and this is not only in Bangladesh that we are discovering that informal institutions are very powerful; the evidence is emerging that this is the case, I think, with respect to policing.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010
Prepared 4 March 2010